Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-18T09:48:50.080Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Assessing the relative influence of party unity on vote choice: evidence from a conjoint experiment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 September 2022

Roni Lehrer*
Affiliation:
University of Mannheim and Goethe University Frankfurt, Frankfurt, Germany
Pirmin Stöckle
Affiliation:
University of Mannheim, Mannheim, Germany
Sebastian Juhl
Affiliation:
University of Mannheim, Mannheim, Germany
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Observational studies and anecdotal evidence suggest that party unity improves a party's electoral performance. Yet, due to a lack of experimental evidence, the causal standing of these findings remains unclear. Moreover, party unity manifests in various ways and we do not know how much different types of party unity affect the vote. Relying on a conjoint experiment implemented in a probability-based survey of the German population, our study unveils the distinct causal effect of different forms of party unity on vote choice. We further establish that appearing united can compensate for substantive policy distances between parties and voters. These findings have important implications for our understanding of how citizens vote and how intra-party politics affects the political representation of citizens in democracies.

Type
Research Note
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the European Political Science Association

What are the electoral consequences of conflict within a party? While ample scholarship on intra-party unity emphasizes its importance for party and electoral behavior (e.g., Ceron, Reference Ceron2015a; Greene and Haber, Reference Greene and Haber2015; Lehrer and Lin, Reference Lehrer and Lin2020), the causal standing of these findings remains elusive as experimental evidence is missing. Furthermore, party unity is frequently simplified to be a unidimensional phenomenon. The various ways in which intra-party dissent manifests itself empirically are neither properly theorized nor well understood. Theoretical arguments on party unity are hardly specific enough to derive precise expectations about the distinct effect of different manifestations of party unity. This theoretical coarseness, the utilization of different measurement approaches, and the lack of causal evidence in general contribute to inconsistent results regarding the effect of party unity on vote choice in published research (Close and Gherghina, Reference Close and Gherghina2019).

Against this background, this research note seeks to improve upon the current state of the literature in three important ways. First, we provide experimental evidence for the effect of party unity on the vote. Second, we compare the effect size of party unity to other important determinants such as the ideological distance between voters and parties. Third, we investigate to what extent conclusions drawn about the consequences of intra-party dissent depend on its operationalization.

Different arguments have been presented in the literature to explain how intra-party conflict depresses a party's vote share (e.g., Greene and Haber, Reference Greene and Haber2015; Jung and Somer-Topcu, Reference Jung and Somer-Topcu2020; Lehrer and Lin, Reference Lehrer and Lin2020). Empirically, however, only observational studies exist that fail to provide causal evidence for the link between party unity and vote choice. We not only causally investigate the electoral consequences of intra-party conflict but also three of its manifestations that empirical research often employs as general measures of party unity: legislative voting behavior, internal critique of the party leadership, and the behavior of delegates at party congresses.Footnote 1

We implement a conjoint experiment in a probability-based survey of the German population. The experimental design not only permits the derivation of causal statements. It also allows us to compare the effect sizes of different forms of party unity to one another as well as to the effect of ideological distance. The results reveal that internal disagreement curtails a party's electoral fortunes. We also find that the electoral consequences of intra-party conflict differ depending on the way the dissent is displayed. While critique from actors within the party has a negligible impact, incohesive voting behavior in parliament and especially publicly displayed conflict at party congresses decrease voters’ likelihood to vote for a party. Finally, party unity is a relevant factor in the calculus of voting that can compensate for some degree of ideological distance.

The intra-party unity dimensions included in the experiment mimic operationalizations that are often used in observational research: Researchers often turn to legislative voting behavior to operationalize intra-party unity. Even though party discipline is usually strong in parliamentary systems, so that parliamentary voting cannot be equated with the sincere expressions of individual preferences (e.g., Carey, Reference Carey2007), diverging voting patterns or more subtle signals such as abstentions are observable indicators divisions within parties (Ceron, Reference Ceron2015a).

Another distinct manifestation of intra-party dissent is openly voiced critique of the party leadership. In principle, different actors – including rank-and-file members, faction leaders, or former party leaders – may openly voice criticism at any time. The availability of social media facilitates the expressions of criticism toward the own party leadership or the parties’ policies without media gatekeeping. Current or former party elites may also utilize traditional forms of public communication such as interviews or press releases to publicly state criticism. Both classical communication strategies and social media statements are used in empirical studies of party unity (Ceron, Reference Ceron2017; Sältzer, Reference Sältzer2020; Somer-Topcu et al., Reference Somer-Topcu, Tavits and Baumann2020).

Finally, party congresses provide an excellent channel to investigate a party's internal cohesiveness. Speeches at party congresses provide a relatively ungated stage for party members to express their concerns with the party leadership and the party's policy platform. Given that national party congresses are among the most important intra-party activities and regularly receive extensive media coverage, the electorate is exposed to information on the proceedings of national party congresses (e.g., Ceron, Reference Ceron2015a; Greene and Haber, Reference Greene and Haber2016; Ceron and Greene, Reference Ceron and Greene2019).

1. Data and research strategy

To causally identify links between (different manifestations of) party unity and vote choice, and to relate their sizes to one another as well as to other determinants of the vote, we conduct a choice-based conjoint experiment (Hainmueller et al., Reference Hainmueller, Hopkins and Yamamoto2014; Ben-Akiva et al., Reference Ben-Akiva, McFadden and Train2019). This design allows us to simultaneously estimate the causal effects of different dimensions of party unity on vote choice. Furthermore, since effect sizes are expressed on a common scale, we can directly compare the influence of different aspects of party unity to one another and to other relevant factors such as ideological distance or different candidate characteristics. The survey experiment was embedded in the November 2019 wave (Blom et al., Reference Blom, Fikel, Friedel, Karem Höhne, Krieger, Rettig and Wenz2020) of the German Internet Panel (GIP), which is based on a probability-based sample of the German population (Blom et al., Reference Blom, Gathmann and Krieger2015). The combination of high-quality survey data and a conjoint experiment enables us to draw conclusions about real-world voter behavior (Hainmueller et al., Reference Hainmueller, Hangartner and Yamamoto2015).

In our experiment, respondents receive randomly varied information about various characteristics of two fictional parties competing against each other in a hypothetical electoral contest. To ease the cognitive burden for respondents, we present the information on the two parties in a table. Respondents are asked to choose one of the parties without an explicit “none”-option (forced-choice design). Yet, they are able to skip the question after an error message asks them to state their choice.Footnote 2 Each respondent consecutively evaluates ten party pairs which is in line with corresponding recommendations for data quality (e.g., Bansak et al., Reference Bansak, Hainmueller, Hopkins and Yamamoto2018).Footnote 3

While we provide information on several features of the hypothetical parties, our primary interest lies in the causal effect of party unity and its manifestations that appear in empirical research. Consequently, we specify three party unity attributes and randomly vary their levels. Table 1 shows all attributes and their respective levels. Specifically, the study separates the following dimensions (with attribute levels in brackets): First, critique toward the party leadership (none, rank-and-file members, former party leader, party faction). This mimics operationalizations that are used in research on party factions, for instance by using social media data (e.g., Ceron, Reference Ceron2012; Sältzer, Reference Sältzer2020). Second, parliamentary voting (united, divided). This kind of approach resembles approaches in legislative studies (e.g., Sieberer, Reference Sieberer2006; Ceron, Reference Ceron2015a). Third, behavior at party congress (united, neither united nor divided, divided) which stems from the literature on party congresses (e.g., Greene and Haber, Reference Greene and Haber2016; Ceron and Greene, Reference Ceron and Greene2019).

Table 1. Attributes and attribute levels

We also randomly vary several additional party features. Foremost, we acknowledge the predominant role of ideological distance for voting (e.g., Franchino and Zucchini, Reference Franchino and Zucchini2015) and assign each fictional party one of five ideological positions (left, center-left, center, center-right, right). Since Lehrer and Lin (Reference Lehrer and Lin2020) report that vote choice is not only affected by party unity on its own, but also jointly with a party's policy ambiguity, we include clarity of reform proposals (high, low). To test for incumbency effects that may be particularly relevant in our experiment in which partisanship is muted (Lim and Jr, Reference Lim and Snyder2015), we manipulate a party's current role (junior coalition party, prime minister's party, opposition party). We also consider the party's top candidate characteristics by varying gender (female, male), age (38, 56, 74 years), and professional experience (activist, employee, retired employee, lawyer, politician, entrepreneur). Finally, to avoid generating unrealistic profiles, we restrict specific combinations of candidate profiles. This refers to scenarios where a 74 years old top candidate still works as an employee, or where a 38 or 56 years old candidate is already retired.Footnote 4

The research design mimics German elections. Similar to Bundestag elections, respondents choose between parties using information on parties’ policy stances, incumbency status, and their Spitzenkandidaten (Debus et al., Reference Debus, Stegmaier and Tosun2014). To facilitate the identification of causal effects, however, the experiment also mutes effects of partisanship, limits choices to two parties and presents information to voters in a way that media usually do not use. Germany serves as an interesting starting point to study party unity since its parties are known to be home to party factions. At the same time, these factions do not dominate party politics as they do elsewhere (Sieberer, Reference Sieberer2006; Ceron, Reference Ceron2015b). Interestingly, the experiment happened to be conducted when Germany's Social Democrats, at the time a junior coalition partner, chose a new party leadership by membership vote. Hence, Germans may have been more sensitive to intra-party division at the time. These aspects somewhat limit the experiment's external validity which we further discuss in the conclusion.

To discern the effect of each attribute, we estimate a conditional logistic regression model (McFadden, Reference McFadden1974) and compute average marginal component effects (AMCE) as well as predicted vote probabilities.Footnote 5 The levels of each attribute are represented by indicator variables. A party's behavior at the party congress, for instance, is modeled as two indicator variables, one for “neither united nor divided” and one for “divided”, while “united” serves as the reference category. Even though the experiment randomizes party ideology, we expect that ideological distance to the respondent's ideal position and not ideology per se matters. To translate party ideology into ideological distance, we rely on respondents’ self-placements on an ideological left-right scale, which was collected two months prior to the experiment in GIP Wave 43 (Blom et al., Reference Blom, Fikel, Friedel, Höhne, Krieger, Rettig and Wenz2021). We use these self-placements to compute the ideological distance between every respondent and the hypothetical party.Footnote 6

Upon list-wise deletion, the sample size totals $3687$ respondents. Because respondents perform multiple choice tasks, our analysis includes $26,761$ choices and standard errors are clustered by respondents to account for this.

2. Results

2.1. The effect of party (dis)unity on the vote

Figure 1 shows the attributes’ AMCEs.Footnote 7 These can be interpreted as the expected change in the probability to choose a given party when an attribute value is compared to the reference category (Hainmueller et al., Reference Hainmueller, Hopkins and Yamamoto2014). In Figure 1, the reference levels are indicated by the black dots at zero.

Figure 1. Average marginal effects of different attributes. Estimates are based on a conditional logistic regression model with clustered standard errors; bars represent $95\percnt$ confidence intervals. The points without horizontal bars represent the reference categories.

Unsurprisingly, by far the strongest predictor of vote choice is ideological distance. A party that has an ideological distance of one unit to the respondent, e.g., a center-right party's distance to a centrist respondent, is on average 10.3 percentage points less likely to be chosen than a party with a zero distance (the 95% confidence interval covers [$8.9$; $11.7$]). When the ideological distance equals two units, e.g., a right party and a centrist voter, its effect already exceeds any other attribute's effect. This result confirms the predominant role of ideological distance for voting.

Regarding the possibility of direct effects of different manifestations of party unity, Figure 1 reveals the existence of heterogeneous causal effects across different dimensions of party unity. Overall, internal critique from party actors has almost no effect on the probability that a respondent chooses the party. In comparison to no internal critique, there is a small negative effect when critique is voiced by internal party factions ($-1.8$percentage points $[\! -\!0.4;\; -\!3.2]$) or former party leaders ($-1.5$ percentage points $[\!-\!0.7;-\!2.9]$). The estimates, however, also suggest that there is no difference between the complete absence of critical comments and critique from rank-and-file members.Footnote 8

In contrast, we find that incohesive voting behavior of a party's parliamentary group harms the party electorally. All else equal, a party failing to ensure united voting patterns by its parliamentary group is on average $5.7$ percentage points $[ 4.6;\; 6.7]$ less likely to be chosen by voters.

Finally, our experiment identifies a party's behavior at its congress as the most decisive dimension of party unity with respect to vote choice. A party that successfully manages to convey a cohesive image at its congress to voters is able to obtain an electoral advantage whereas parties that engage in internal fights will be punished. Open disagreements at party congresses harm parties with a loss in vote probability of $14.7$ percentage points $[ 13.5;\; 15.9]$.

Overall, we find clear support for the expectation that intra-party unity boosts a party's electoral performance. The evidence is particularly strong when party unity becomes visible in party congress behavior and to a lesser degree in parliamentary voting.

Besides these main effects of interest, the experiment further reveals the effects of several additional features. With respect to the top candidate, for example, we corroborate previous findings that voters prefer younger and female candidates with a primary occupation as employees (e.g., Carnes and Lupu, Reference Carnes and Lupu2016). Moreover, our experiment clearly supports observational evidence suggesting that voters punish parties for low reform clarity, i.e. vague policy proposals (Lehrer and Lin, Reference Lehrer and Lin2020).

2.2. How important is party unity for electoral competition?

To compare the effect sizes of the different party unity manifestations to ideological distances and to determine when party unity is pivotal for vote choice, we use the estimates from our conditional logistic regression model to simulate hypothetical electoral contests. Consider a voter who is faced with a choice between two hypothetical parties, Party 1 and Party 2. Both of these parties are identical, except that Party 1 is ideologically somewhat closer to the voter than Party 2. The parties’ full characteristics are given at the top of Figure 2. Following the reasoning of spatial voting, the model predicts a probability of $60.3\% [ 60.1;\; 60.7]$ that the hypothetical voter chooses Party 1 which is ideologically closer (see the top plot in Figure 2).

Figure 2. Hypothetical competition scenarios.

Now imagine that Party 1 competes with Party 3 which manages to present itself as united at its party congress but is otherwise identical to Party 2. In particular, it also positions a unit away from the voter, is divided in parliamentary voting, and its factions voice critique toward the leadership. If only ideological distance mattered to the voter, we would expect Party 1 to prevail because ideological distances did not change. However, because party unity matters, Party 3 is more likely to be chosen. In fact, Party 1 is now chosen by the hypothetical voter with only $45.3\% [ 45.3;\; 45.5]$ probability, which means that we expect the voter to choose Party 3 over Party 1 (center plot in Figure 2).

A similar pattern emerges when Party 1 instead competes with Party 4. This party produces no internal critique, exhibits unified parliamentary voting and neither a divided nor a united behavior at its party congress. Otherwise it is like Party 2. As the bottom plot in Figure 2 shows, in an electoral contest between these parties, Party 1 is roughly as unlikely to be chosen as in its competition against Party 3 (42% [41.8; 42.6]).

These examples present causal evidence that party unity can compensate for greater ideological distance which may, for example, be the ideological difference between center-left and center. They also reveal that while party unity with respect to parliamentary voting and critique of the party leadership may exert rather small effects on voting probabilities, their joint effect is similar in strength to a change in party congress behavior from neither united nor divided to fully united.

3. Additional results: simulate your own electoral competition

Overall, our experimental design gives rise to $21, 600$ distinct party profiles and $466,\; 560,\; 000$ possible party pairings. To facilitate the analysis of interesting hypothetical electoral competitions despite the large number of potential pairings, we provide a free simulation tool that allows researchers to vary all dimensions, and investigate how the predicted election outcome changes when amending one or several distinct attributes. The simulation tool is available online at https://party-unity-conjoint.shinyapps.io/simulation/ and requires no technical or statistical knowledge. Effectively, it operates along the lines demonstrated above: Users specify hypothetical parties with specific attribute configurations, and the tool simulates an electoral contest between them by using the results from the regression analysis.

Suppose we are interested in learning whether perfect party unity can compensate for more than a unit of distance on the five-point scale of policy distance. To do so, we would specify two parties that only differ in their party unity and their ideological distance to the voter. One party is ideologically congruent with the voter, yet, fully divided (internal critique from party factions, divided in parliamentary voting and at the party congress), while the other party is perfectly united (no internal critique, united in parliamentary voting and at the party congress), yet, positions two units away from the voter. We present the corresponding results in online Appendix 6. In particular, we show that even the highest levels of party unity cannot compensate for more than a single unit on a five-point scale of policy distance.

Similarly, we find that in the most extreme scenario, an all united party (no internal critique, united in parliamentary voting and at the party congress) is roughly 2.5 times as likely to be chosen than an all divided party (internal critique from party factions, divided in parliamentary voting and at the party congress).Footnote 9

We strongly encourage researchers to think of novel attributes combinations that are meaningful to their research questions, and to use the simulation tool to gain relevant insights.

4. Conclusion

Using a conjoint experiment, this note establishes a causal relationship between party unity and vote choice. Internal dissent decreases a party's electoral performance. It also reveals that party unity can compensate for ideological distance, however, this effect is limited as spatial considerations clearly dominate vote choice. Finally, we find that the electoral consequences of intra-party conflict differ across distinct dimensions of party unity. While publicly stated critique from party actors has a negligible impact, incohesive voting behavior in parliament and especially publicly displayed conflict at party congresses decrease voters’ likelihood to vote for a party.

The experimental evidence presented here has important implications for political representation in democracies. We find that parties face strong electoral incentives to act in unison and appear united (Greene and Haber, Reference Greene and Haber2015). Viewed from a normative perspective, this points to a trade-off parties need to manage: Parties are supposed to be deliberative institutions in which critical voices are raised and leaders are held accountable (Wolkenstein, Reference Wolkenstein2016). At the same time, our findings suggest that parties have strong electoral incentives to not appear divided in public. Future research will need to study whether and how parties address this challenge.

Further, the results show that the effect of party unity depends on how it is operationalized. This has direct implications for the empirical study of party unity because it has, up until now, often singled out a party unity dimension to measure it (Close and Gherghina, Reference Close and Gherghina2019). Our findings suggest that results may not be robust to the choice of the measurement approach. This also highlights the necessity to improve the theoretical foundation to allow for the derivation of fine-grained expectations regarding the more subtle effects of party unity.

While our experimental design allows us to uncover the causal effect of party unity on vote choice, it abstracts from several important aspects which future research should scrutinize: First, while the experiment establishes a causal relationship, it is not able to reveal the causal mechanisms underlying the link between party unity and vote choice. Second, by prompting respondents with specific levels of party unity as part of the conjoint design, we are unable to uncover any effect perceptions of party unity may have (Plescia et al., Reference Plescia, Kritzinger and Eberl2020). Third, we conducted the experiment within a panel survey in Germany at a time of potentially heightened sensitivity toward party unity. Hence, future research should not only confirm our findings in other electoral contexts but also with respondents who do not regularly answer surveys on political items. Finally, the experiment abstracts from actual German elections in multiple ways, including a choice between two parties, the omission of party labels, and a presentation of information on parties that do not match the actual ballot. We suspect that these aspects limit the experiment's external validity, yet, we do not fully know to what extent. Therefore, we call on scholars to further investigate the relationship between party unity and vote choice to develop a more sophisticated understanding of this important nexus.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2022.45. To obtain replication material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/V294KT

Footnotes

1 In accordance with previous research, we are agnostic whether intra-party conflict stems from policy differences, personal disputes, or both.

2 We present all survey items’ full wording in online Appendix 1.

3 In online Appendix 4, we present evidence from a quality check that suggests that respondents understand and participate in the experiment as expected.

4 Further, in order to avoid a potential bias due to the sequence in which the attributes are displayed, we randomize their order for each respondent (e.g., Hainmueller et al., Reference Hainmueller, Hopkins and Yamamoto2014). We hold the order constant within respondents and across tasks.

5 In online Appendix 3, we demonstrate that results are virtually identical when using the linear implementation as in Hainmueller et al. (Reference Hainmueller, Hopkins and Yamamoto2014).

6 Self-placements were measured on an 11-point scale. We map them to the five categories of the experimental design as follows: Self-placements in categories 1 and 2 are considered equivalent to a left party's ideology, 3 and 4 equivalent to the center-left, 5, 6, and 7 equivalent to the center, 8 and 9 equivalent to the center-right, and 10 and 11 equivalent to the right.

7 The full regression table is available in online Appendix 2.

8 In online Appendix 5, we present evidence that our conclusions are not biased because the Critique on the party leadership dimension may be harder to understand than other party unity dimensions.

9 The other candidate and party characteristics are specified as follows: The candidate is female, 38 years old, and an employee. The party is a junior coalition partner, its reform proposals have high clarity, and it is ideologically congruent to the voter.

References

Bansak, K, Hainmueller, J, Hopkins, DJ and Yamamoto, T (2018) The number of choice tasks and survey satisficing in conjoint experiments. Political Analysis 26, 112119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Akiva, M, McFadden, D and Train, K (2019) Foundations of stated preference elicitation: consumer behavior and choice-based conjoint analysis. Foundations and Trends in Econometrics 10, 1144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blom, AG, Fikel, M, Friedel, S, Karem Höhne, J, Krieger, U, Rettig, T and Wenz, A (2020) SFB 884 ‘Political economy of reforms’, Universität Mannheim, German Internet Panel, Welle 44 (November 2019).Google Scholar
Blom, AG, Fikel, M, Friedel, S, Höhne, JK, Krieger, U, Rettig, T and Wenz, A (2020) SFB 884 ‘Political economy of reforms’, Universität Mannheim, German Internet Panel, Welle 43—Core Study (September 2019).Google Scholar
Blom, AG, Gathmann, C and Krieger, U (2015) Setting up an online panel representative of the general population. Field Methods 27, 391408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, JM (2007) Competing principals, political institutions, and party unity in legislative voting. American Journal of Political Science 51, 92107.Google Scholar
Carnes, N and Lupu, N (2016) Do voters dislike working-class candidates? Voter biases and the descriptive underrepresentation of the working class. The American Political Science Review 110, 832.Google Scholar
Ceron, A (2012) Bounded oligarchy: how and when factions constrain leaders in party position-taking. Electoral Studies 31, 689701.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ceron, A (2015a) Brave rebels stay home. Party Politics 21, 246258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ceron, A (2015b) The politics of fission: an analysis of faction breakaways among Italian parties (1946–2011). British Journal of Political Science 45, 121139.Google Scholar
Ceron, A (2017) Intra-party politics in 140 characters. Party Politics 23, 717.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ceron, A and Greene, Z (2019) Verba volant, scripta manent? Intra-party politics, party conferences, and issue salience in France. Party Politics 25, 701711.Google Scholar
Close, C and Gherghina, S (2019) Rethinking intra-party cohesion: towards a conceptual and analytical framework. Party Politics 25, 652663.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Debus, M, Stegmaier, M and Tosun, J (2014) Economic voting under coalition governments: evidence from Germany. Political Science Research and Methods 2, 4967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franchino, F and Zucchini, F (2015) Voting in a multi-dimensional space: a conjoint analysis employing valence and ideology attributes of candidates. Political Science Research and Methods 3, 221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greene, Z and Haber, M (2015) The consequences of appearing divided: an analysis of party evaluations and vote choice. Electoral Studies 37, 1527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greene, Z and Haber, M (2016) Leadership competition and disagreement at party national congresses. British Journal of Political Science 46, 611632.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hainmueller, J, Hangartner, D and Yamamoto, T (2015) Validating vignette and conjoint survey experiments against real-world behavior. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112, 23952400.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hainmueller, J, Hopkins, DJ and Yamamoto, T (2014) Causal inference in conjoint analysis: understanding multidimensional choices via stated preference experiments. Political Analysis 22, 130.Google Scholar
Jung, J-H and Somer-Topcu, Z (2020) United we stand, divided we fall? The effects of parties’ Brexit rhetoric on voters’ perceptions of party positions. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties 32, 119.Google Scholar
Lehrer, R and Lin, N (2020) Everything to everyone? Not when you are internally divided. Party Politics 26, 783794.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lim, CSH and Snyder, JM Jr (2015) Is more information always better? Party cues and candidate quality in US judicial elections. Journal of public Economics 128, 107123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFadden, D (1974) Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. Vol. Frontiers in econometrics. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Plescia, C, Kritzinger, S and Eberl, J-M (2020) ‘The enemy within’: campaign attention and motivated reasoning in voter perceptions of intra-party conflict. Party Politics 27, 917927.Google Scholar
Sältzer, M (2020) Finding the bird's wings: dimensions of factional conflict on Twitter. Party Politics 28, 6170.Google Scholar
Sieberer, U (2006) Party unity in parliamentary democracies: a comparative analysis. The Journal of Legislative Studies 12, 150178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Somer-Topcu, Z, Tavits, M and Baumann, M (2020) Does party rhetoric affect voter perceptions of party positions?. Electoral Studies 65, 102153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolkenstein, F (2016) A deliberative model of intra-party democracy. Journal of Political Philosophy 24, 297320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Attributes and attribute levels

Figure 1

Figure 1. Average marginal effects of different attributes. Estimates are based on a conditional logistic regression model with clustered standard errors; bars represent $95\percnt$ confidence intervals. The points without horizontal bars represent the reference categories.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Hypothetical competition scenarios.

Supplementary material: File

Lehrer et al. supplementary material
Download undefined(File)
File 3.8 MB
Supplementary material: File

Lehrer_et_al._Dataset

Dataset

Download Lehrer_et_al._Dataset(File)
File