Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T22:32:36.582Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Factors Affecting Sugar-Containing-Product Prices

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 May 2022

Karen L. DeLong*
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN, USA
Carlos O. Trejo-Pech
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

United States (US) sugar policy buffers domestic sugar producers against subsidized and dumped world market sugar resulting in generally higher US sugar prices compared to world prices. A fixed-effects panel regression is used to estimate factors associated with US sugar-containing-product (SCP) retail prices. SCPs are defined by sucrose being a primary ingredient. Explanatory variables in the regression were US sugar prices, SCP characteristics, firm size, firm past financial performance, and macroeconomic variables. Macroeconomic variables, firm past financial performance, and SCP weight were statistically significant in explaining SCP prices. Increases in US sugar prices were not associated with higher SCP prices.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Southern Agricultural Economics Association

Introduction

United States (US) sugar policy utilizes domestic marketing allotments and a tariff-rate quota (TRQ) system to regulate how much sugar is allowed to be marketed in the US (US Department of Agriculture (USDA) Economic Research Service (ERS), 2021a). Domestic marketing allotments establish the amount of sugar domestic producers are allowed to market by company and are split between cane sugar and beet sugar production. Forty countries are granted access to the World Trade Organization TRQ and many also export sugar into the US in amounts specified by various trade agreements. Additionally, Mexico exported an unrestricted amount of sugar into the US due to the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) (now the US–Mexican–Canada Agreement) during 2008–2013. However, there are now constraints to Mexico’s access to the US market due to the suspension agreements negotiated by the US and Mexican governments in 2014 (USDA ERS, 2021a) that suspended severe antidumping and countervailing duties imposed on Mexican sugar imports due to anticompetitive behavior. Additionally, the USDA Secretary of Agriculture can increase the TRQ amount if he or she believes the domestic supply of sugar is “inadequate to meet domestic demand at reasonable prices” (USDA ERS, 2021a).

US sugar prices are generally higher than world sugar prices since the domestic and foreign sugar supply is limited by US sugar policy, whereas the global market has surplus sugar supplies encouraged by production subsidies in most sugar-producing countries (e.g., Elobeid & Beghin, Reference Elobeid and Beghin2006; Hodari, Reference Hodari2018; Hudson, Reference Hudson2019). However, notwithstanding the rationale for US sugar policy, some sugar-using firms claim US sugar policy is harmful to their business since they cannot easily access the discounted subsidized world sugar price. The Sweeteners Users Association (SUA) (2021) claims that “US sugar prices are often double world prices—a cost that typically gets unfairly passed on to consumers.” The SUA recently issued a press release that called the US sugar program “overly restrictive” and committed to “keeping sugar supplies tight and domestic prices high” (SUA, 2021).

While somewhat counter-intuitive, Trejo-Pech et al. (Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020) found that as US sugar prices increase relative to world sugar prices, US sugar-using firm financial performance improves. This may suggest relative (US to world) price increases are passed onto consumers. Further, candy industry reports assert that as sugar prices increase, sugar-using firms can use this as an opportunity to become more profitable by increasing sugar-containing-product (SCP) prices (IBIS World, 2020). If sugar-using firms become more profitable when sugar input costs increase, firms may be increasing SCP prices in an amount that exceeds their input-cost rise.Footnote 1 Consider, for example, the retail price of a Hershey candy bar, which grew 326% from 1983 to 2018, increasing from 35 cents to $1.49 (American Sugar Alliance (ASA), 2021). Meanwhile, the US wholesale refined sugar price rose less than 10 cents per pound, or just 36%, between 1983 and 2018 (USDA ERS, 2021b). Thus, there is evidence that sugar-using firms have, indeed, raised their SCP prices by a greater magnitude than the rise in US sugar price.

It is possible that while prices of some SCPs have increased more than sugar prices over time, SCP prices and sugar prices are not necessarily correlated. This prediction is based on the fact that the share of sugar cost is very low relative to SCP total production cost and SCP price. It is common industry knowledge that sugar costs represent a small fraction of SCP prices despite being a primary ingredient (Triantis, Reference Triantis2016). This is not uncommon; indeed, USDA ERS (2021c) documents the relatively low commodity value contained within most food products in the US. In 2020, the average cost of sugar in highly sweetened SCPs ranged from 1.56% to 10.03% (ASA, 2021). Thus, since sugar cost represents such a minor component of SCP price, it is possible that there is no direct relationship between changes in sugar prices and SCP prices.

The goal of this paper is to determine the factors that affect SCP prices by estimating a hedonic pricing model of SCP prices. Specifically, this study will use a database of SCP prices from 2008 through 2020 to determine the factors influencing SCP prices. SCPs owned by publicly traded firms with observed firm financials are used in the analysis. The hypothesis of whether US sugar prices affect SCP prices is also tested. While research shows that, counterintuitively, sugar-using firms are more profitable when US sugar prices increase relative to world sugar prices (Trejo-Pech et al., Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020), no known research has investigated whether US sugar prices are statistically significant in determining SCP prices. Given sugar prices represent a small fraction of SCP prices (Triantis, Reference Triantis2016; ASA, 2021), it is possible US sugar prices are not associated with SCP prices. This research is the first known study to estimate the determinants of SCP prices. Results will be informative to US sugar policy as well as those interested in sugar-using firm behavior (e.g., SCP determinants). This is important research given SCPs represent a large sector of the agribusiness economy and annually bring in billions of dollars of revenue. For example, SCPs include candy, ice cream, snack foods, baking mixes, and soft drinks which are sectors that in 2020 represented approximately $9.9 billion, $7.8 billion, $41.7 billion, $31.1 billion, and $38.5 billion of revenue, respectively (IBIS World, 2020).

Literature Review

Previous research has analyzed many aspects of the US sugar market such as sugar-sweetened beverage taxes (e.g., Cawley et al., Reference Cawley, Frisvold, Jones and Lensing2021; Lee et al., Reference Lee, Falbe, Schillinger, Basu, McCulloch and Madsen2019; Allcott, Lockwood, and Taubinsky, Reference Allcott, Lockwood and Taubinsky2019), the impact of NAFTA (e.g., Kennedy and Schmitz, Reference Kennedy and Schmitz2009; Knutson, Westhoff, and Sherwell, Reference Knutson, Westhoff and Sherwell2010; Schmitz and Lewis, Reference Schmitz and Lewis2015), the effect of Mexican sugar dumping and countervailing actions on the US sugar market (e.g., Schmitz, Reference Schmitz2018; Lewis and Schmitz, Reference Lewis and Schmitz2015; Zahniser et al., Reference Zahniser, Kennedy, Nigatu and McConnell2016), US genetically modified (GM) sugar beets (e.g., Lewis et al., Reference Lewis, Grebitus and Nayga2016a; Kennedy, Schmitz, and DeLong, Reference Kennedy, Schmitz and DeLong2019; Carter and Schaefer, Reference Carter and Schaefer2019), consumer preferences for sugar (e.g., Lewis, Grebitus, and Nayga, Reference Lewis, Grebitus and Nayga2016a; Lewis, Grebitus, and Nayga, Reference Lewis, Grebitus and Nayga2016b; Lewis, Grebitus, and Nayga, Reference Lewis, Grebitus and Nayga2016c; Lewis and Grebitus, Reference Lewis and Grebitus2016), and how US sugar prices impact sugar-using firm profitability (e.g., Triantis, Reference Triantis2016; Trejo-Pech et al., Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020).

Cawley et al. (Reference Cawley, Frisvold, Jones and Lensing2021) provide a review of the literature concerning the impact of sugar-sweetened beverage taxes. They also analyzed Nielsen Retail Scanner Data along with hand-collected price data on sugar-sweetened beverages to determine the passthrough effect of a sugar-sweetened beverage tax in Boulder, Colorado. They found that the passthrough effect of the tax was slightly less than 75% when analyzing hand-collected store data, but was 50% when using the scanner data. In general, they found consumers paid most of the tax.

Schmitz and Lewis (Reference Schmitz and Lewis2015) found that NAFTA cost US sugar producers $474 million to $1.3 billion annually due to increased Mexican sugar imports into the US. Lewis and Schmitz (Reference Lewis and Schmitz2015) estimated that if the Mexican government no longer owned and operated 20% of their sugar industry, US sugar producers would gain $525 million to $1.6 billion annually. Schmitz (Reference Schmitz2018) observed that the 2014 Mexican–US sugar suspension agreements would have saved US sugar producers $138 million annually if these agreements had been in effect from 2008 through 2014.

Kennedy, Schmitz, and DeLong (Reference Kennedy, Schmitz and DeLong2019) used a partial equilibrium framework to evaluate the possible demand impact of US sugar beets being GM compared to their non-GM sugarcane counterpart. They found that the negative demand impact from sugar beets being GM could outweigh any supply induced gains from GM sugar beets. They concluded that since the National Bioengineered Food Disclosure Standard does not classify beet sugar as bioengineered, this negative welfare result would not be fully realized for sugar beet producers.

Trejo-Pech et al. (Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020) examined the effect of US sugar policy on sugar-using-firm profitability when considering both US and world sugar prices. They examined how the relative US-to-world sugar price ratio impacted US firms’ return on assets (ROAs) and market-to-book (MTB) ratio. Counterintuitively, they found that as US sugar prices increase relative to world sugar prices, US sugar-using firms became more profitable.

While research has examined several aspects of the US sugar market and US policy, no known research has examined factors associated with SCP prices and whether US sugar prices are associated with SCPs. To contribute to the economics of sugar literature, this research analyzes a panel of SCP prices across various sugar-using firms and examines whether US sugar prices are associated with SCP prices.

Conceptual Framework and Hypothesized Results

The goal of this paper is to determine factors influencing SCP prices with a particular interest on understanding the role of input sugar prices. Trejo-Pech et al. (Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020) was the first known research to examine the relationship between US sugar prices and sugar-using firm performance as measured by firms’ ROAs and MTB ratios. It was found that as the ratio of US wholesale refined beet sugar price to the world refined sugar (US-to-world) price increased, firms’ ROAs increased. However, in their second model specification, there was no statistically significant relationship between the US-to-world sugar price ratio and firms’ MTB ratios.

Trejo-Pech et al. (Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020, page 14) concluded their research with a possible explanation of, “US sugar-using firms must pass on higher costs to consumers when relative prices increase or do not pass on discounts to consumers when relative sugar prices decrease.” We examine this outstanding question using a unique data set of SCP prices as a dependent variable, rather than using firm profits (ROA and MTB ratios) as a dependent variable like Trejo-Pech et al. (Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020), and by including sugar prices as an independent variable. Thus, this research will directly estimate whether higher US sugar prices are passed on to consumers while controlling for other relevant possible determinants of food prices.

Previous literature has examined determinants of food prices (e.g., Richards and Hamilton, Reference Richards and Hamilton2015; Volpe, Risch, and Boland, Reference Volpe, Risch and Boland2017; Hamilton, Liaukonyte, and Richards, Reference Hamilton, Liaukonyte and Richards2020; Nakamura, Reference Nakamura2008; Ghazaryan et al., Reference Ghazaryan, Westgren, Parcell and Gedikoglu2018; Nakamura and Zerom, Reference Nakamura and Zerom2010). Factors theorized to affect food prices include input prices (Nakamura and Zerom, Reference Nakamura and Zerom2010; Volpe, Risch, and Boland, Reference Volpe, Risch and Boland2017; Richards and Hamilton, Reference Richards and Hamilton2015; Hamilton, Liaukonyte, and Richards, Reference Hamilton, Liaukonyte and Richards2020), product characteristics such as size and appearance (Ghazaryan et al., Reference Ghazaryan, Westgren, Parcell and Gedikoglu2018), macroeconomic factors (Richards and Hamilton, Reference Richards and Hamilton2015; Volpe, Risch, and Boland, Reference Volpe, Risch and Boland2017), and market power (Hamilton, Liaukonyte, and Richards, Reference Hamilton, Liaukonyte and Richards2020; Richards, Hamilton, and Yonezawa, Reference Richards, Hamilton and Yonezawa2017). Similarly, it is hypothesized that input prices, product characteristics, macroeconomic factors, and firm size will have an impact on SCP prices. While no located research has examined how firm financial performance affects food prices, this research postulates it will affect SCP prices since Trejo-Pech et al. (Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020) found a relationship between firm profitability measures and sugar prices, and because firms’ market power throughout the food supply chain is an important consideration in explaining food prices (Hamilton, Liaukonyte, and Richards, Reference Hamilton, Liaukonyte and Richards2020; Richards, Hamilton, and Yonezawa, Reference Richards, Hamilton and Yonezawa2017). Only SCP prices from publicly traded sugar-using firms were utilized so firm size and financial performance variables could be included as independent variables in the analysis.

The categories of variables hypothesized to affect SCP prices are SCP characteristics—including sugar price and other characteristics—firm size and financial performance, and macroeconomic conditions. A traditional hedonic pricing model is estimated such that for each uniquely identified SCP, i, in a calendar quarter, t, the SCP price per pound (SCPprice i,t ) can be explained as a function of the following factors:

(1) $$SCPpric{e_{i,t}} = f(SC{P_{i,t}},{F_{i,t}},M{E_{i,t}}).$$

where SCP i,t are characteristics relating to the SCP, F i,t are variables relating to the respective SCP firm, and ME i,t controls for macroeconomic conditions over the sample’s time period.Footnote 2

Sugar-Containing-Product Characteristics

Input prices (e.g., Volpe, Risch, and Boland, Reference Volpe, Risch and Boland2017; Richards and Hamilton, Reference Richards and Hamilton2015; Hamilton, Liaukonyte, and Richards, Reference Hamilton, Liaukonyte and Richards2020) and product characteristics (e.g., Ghazaryan et al., Reference Ghazaryan, Westgren, Parcell and Gedikoglu2018) are primary determinants of food prices. It is expected that the SCP characteristics that will impact the SCP price per pound are sugar prices (SugarPrice), the percentage of sugar in the SCP (%Sugar), and SCP weight (Weight).

To test the effect of sugar prices on SCP prices, four specifications of sugar prices are examined across four different models: (1) US wholesale refined beet sugar prices, (2) quarterly lagged US wholesale refined beet sugar prices, (3) US-to-world sugar prices, and (4) US-to-world quarterly lagged sugar prices. With respect to all four specifications, it is hypothesized that the sugar prices will either not be significant in the model or else will be significant and positive (Table 1). If sugar prices are significant and positive, this would be consistent with Trejo-Pech et al. (Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020) and the SUA’s (2021) declaration that higher sugar prices caused by US sugar policy are “unfairly” passed on to consumers. On the other hand, since US sugar prices represent such a small fraction of SCP prices (Triantis, Reference Triantis2016; ASA, 2021), it is also possible that they do not have an impact on SCP prices and are not statistically significant in the model. This argument is also consistent with research documenting a weak transmission of coffee bean prices to consumer prices due to a relatively low share of coffee bean cost relative to the overall cost of manufacturing coffee (Bettendorf and Verboven, Reference Bettendorf and Verboven2000).

Table 1. Variables, definitions, and hypothesized signs

a EPSthresholdt = 1 if EPSt−1/EPSt−2 ≤ 1.01, 0 otherwise.

b Firm market value size, or firm market valuation, is defined as total assets − common equity + market capitalization, where market capitalization equals the stock price multiplied by the number of shares outstanding during the fiscal quarter.

c Prices were adjusted for inflation using the Consumer Price Index.

Notes: NS stands for not significant. NA stands for not applicable.

Table 2. Summary statistics of sugar-containing-product (SCP) prices, SCP characteristics, firm financial performance, and recessions

Notes: Observations = 379.

Similar to Ghazaryan et al. (Reference Ghazaryan, Westgren, Parcell and Gedikoglu2018), food product characteristics are also included in the model. The estimated coefficient on the percentage of the product’s weight that is sugar (%Sugar) will indicate whether products of a higher sugar content are priced higher than products that have a lower sugar content. The %Sugar is also a control variable given there is a diverse panel of SCPs considered in the analysis. It is uncertain whether more highly sweetened products are priced higher or lower (Table 1).

Product weight has been shown to affect pricing decisions of foods (Ghazaryan et al., Reference Ghazaryan, Westgren, Parcell and Gedikoglu2018). To incentivize sales volume, manufacturers may increase a product’s package size, which decreases the SCP price per unit, and in consequence, makes their products economically more attractive. It has also been suggested that sugar-using firms may increase price per unit by repacking candy into smaller bars sold at similar prices (Trejo-Pech et al., Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020), a phenomenon known as “shrinkflation” (National Public Radio, 2021). Decreasing the size of the candy bars without decreasing their price proportionally would have the impact of increasing the SCP price per pound. From a more general standpoint, product Weight is also included as a control variable since the data are a panel of SCPs ranging from candy bars to sucrose-sweetened soft drinks and it is likely SCP prices vary by product types which also have different weights. Given these relationships between SCP weight and price per pound, we expect that as the package size increases (decreases), the SCP price per pound will decrease (increase) (Table 1).

Firm Size and Past Financial Performance

Hedonic pricing modeling improves when in addition to cost and demand considerations (i.e., package size, sugar content, and sugar price), aspects of the brand’s marketing strategy, such as a firm’s competitive positioning, are included as explanatory variables (Rao, Reference Rao1993). Furthermore, the competitive structure and market power of a firm are an important determinant of food prices (Hamilton, Liaukonyte, and Richards, Reference Hamilton, Liaukonyte and Richards2020; Richards, Hamilton, and Yonezawa, Reference Richards, Hamilton and Yonezawa2017). Thus, the firm’s sales growth, past financial performance, and size proxies are considered in this study to control for a firm’s competitive positioning.

Sales growth is one of the most preferred financial ratios used by equity analysts issuing investment recommendations on publicly traded firms’ stocks (Trejo-Pech, Noguera, and White, Reference Trejo-Pech, Noguera and White2015). Firms in the sample would likely consider sales trends when pricing their products. It is hypothesized that one-quarter lagged year-to-year sales growth (SalesGrowth) will positively influence pricing decisions in the current quarter (Table 1). It is plausible that when sales are growing, firms may increase prices to test whether consumers are still willing to pay higher prices (i.e., positive sales growth may signal underpricing). In contrast, when sales are decreasing, firms may decrease prices to incentivize purchasing and avoid further sales growth deterioration.

Publicly traded firms’ profitability is highly scrutinized every quarter by equity analysts and investors because profitability and market equity value are directly related. Consistently, surveyed chief financial officers (CFOs) rank earnings as the single most important financial metric they care about. Further, CFOs have strong incentives to meet or exceed earnings thresholds (Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal, Reference Graham, Harvey and Rajgopal2006). Failure to meet capital market’s earnings thresholds may place firms under financial pressure. Trejo-Pech, Weldon, and Gunderson (Reference Trejo-Pech, Weldon and Gunderson2016), for instance, find that publicly traded agribusinesses failing to meet earnings thresholds tend to manipulate earnings to get back on track, suggesting that earnings thresholds could be as important or more important than the value of reported earnings itself. For empirical research, Gunny (Reference Gunny2010) and Zang (Reference Zang2012) operationalize earning thresholds by comparing firm current and previous period reported earnings ratios, as specified below. It is hypothesized that not meeting earnings thresholds on a given quarter influences the SCP pricing decision in the following quarter. However, it is difficult to predict the direction of price changes firms may create to increase profits because it would depend on margin levels, non-recurrent expenses during the current quarter, or product-price elasticities, among other factors. Following Zang (Reference Zang2012), we build a binary earnings threshold variable with a value of one for firms that reported lower earnings per share (EPS) relative to the previous quarter or barely higher EPS relative to the previous quarter. Specifically, we define EPSthreshold t = 1 if EPSt−1/EPSt−2 ≤ 1.01, 0 otherwise.Footnote 3 This lagged EPS threshold (EPSthreshold) is expected to affect pricing decisions either positively or negatively in the current period (Table 1).

Larger firms might be better positioned than smaller firms for pricing decisions and price negotiations with retailers since they might afford higher advertising expenditures, better trained sales force, higher R&D, and in general, have larger resources. Given the documented effect of firm size on stock returns (Banz, Reference Banz1981; Fama and French, Reference Fama and French1993), firm size is widely used as a control variable in finance-related research. Thus, it is hypothesized that large firms—size measured in terms of market value—will be more likely to exercise their market power and have higher SCP prices than small- and medium-sized firms (Table 1). Therefore, we include a variable regarding the size of the firm relative to other firms in the sample (LargeMarketVal). LargeMarketVal is a binary variable equal to one if a firm ranked in the top 33% of firm market value sizes of all firms in the sample and zero otherwise. Firm market value size is defined as total assets minus common equity plus market capitalization, where market capitalization equals the stock price multiplied by the number of shares outstanding during the fiscal quarter.

Macroeconomic Conditions

Two macroeconomic variables (ME), disposable income (DispIncome) and recessionary periods (Recessions), are used to control for general economic factors that affect the economy on a large scale and could potentially influence SCP prices. DispIncome is per capita disposable income, which is defined as an individual’s personal income minus their taxes (Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2021). As per capita disposable income increases, this indicates that price levels elsewhere may also be rising, such as retail SCP prices. It also may indicate sugar-using firms are motivated to increase their prices since consumers should be able to afford the price increase. The inclusion of this variable is similar to Volpe, Risch, and Boland (Reference Volpe, Risch and Boland2017), who controlled for mean family income in their model of food price changes, and Richards and Hamilton (Reference Richards and Hamilton2015), who included grocery employee average wages in their model examining the passthrough effects of food prices. It is hypothesized that as per capita disposable income (DispIncome) increases, SCP prices will increase as well. The macroeconomic condition of recessions (Recessions) was used to account for trends in gross domestic product (GDP). A recession is defined as two consecutive quarters of decline in real GDP. If the US was in an economic recession according to the National Bureau of Economic Research (2021), Recessions was equal to one (and was zero otherwise). It is hypothesized that SCP prices will be lower in a recession to entice consumers to still purchase SCPs.

Econometric Model

A fixed-effects panel regression was estimated to determine factors influencing SCP prices. The panel consists of a sample of SCPs sold by sugar-using publicly traded firms over time. The dependent variable is SCP price per pound (SCPprice) expressed in 2020 Consumer Price Index (CPI) adjusted dollars (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2021). This was calculated by dividing SCP CPI adjusted prices by the total pounds in each product’s package. Expressing SCP price on a per pound basis standardizes prices across product categories and uses the same units for both output and input prices (i.e., sugar prices are by industry convention expressed in $ per pound). This model specification is similar to Ghazaryan et al. (Reference Ghazaryan, Westgren, Parcell and Gedikoglu2018) who estimated a hedonic pricing model with produce prices as the dependent variable and included independent variables related to produce characteristics.

SCP price is modeled as a function of SCP characteristics, firm size, firm past financial performance, and macroeconomic conditions. Equation(2) shows the model:

(2) $$\eqalign{\ln (SCPprice)_{i,t}^{SCP} = {\beta _0} + {\beta _1}\cdot\ln (Weight)_{i,t}^{SCP} + {\beta _2}\cdot\ln (\% Sugar)_{i,t}^{SCP} \cr \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\, + {\beta _3}\cdot\ln (SugarPrice)_{i,t}^{SCP} + {\beta _4}\cdot SalesGrowth_{i,t - 1}^F + {\beta _5}\cdot EPSthreashold_{i,t - 1}^F \cr \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\, + {\beta _6}\cdot LargeMarketVal_{i,t}^F + {\beta _7}\cdot\ln (DispIncome)_{i,t}^{ME} + {\beta _7}\cdot R_{i,t}^{ME} + {a_i} + {e_{i,t}} \cr} $$

where subscript i represents the uniquely identified SCP, t is a calendar quarter, and superscripts represent characteristics associated with the SCP (SCP), SCP firm (F), and macroeconomic conditions (ME). SCP characteristics include SCP weight (Weight), the percentage of sugar in the SCP (%Sugar), and the four considered sugar prices (SugarPrice) which were adjusted for inflation using the CPI. To facilitate the interpretation of results (i.e., have parameters estimated as elasticities), the natural log (ln) of the SCP characteristic variables and disposable income was used in equation(2).

SCP firm size and financial performance variables include sales growth (SalesGrowth), the EPS threshold proxy (EPSthreshold), and the variable regarding the size of the firm relative to other firms in the sample (LargeMarketVal). The macroeconomic variables of per capita disposable income (DispIncome) and recessions (Recessions) were also included. DispIncome was adjusted for inflation using the CPI and the natural log of DispIncome was used in the model. Complete variable descriptions appear in Table 1. a i in equation(2) captures product-specific fixed effects.

From equation(2), the null hypothesis of whether sugar prices affect retail SCP prices $({\beta _3} = 0)$ can be tested. If the null is failed to be rejected, then sugar prices do not have a relationship with SCP prices. Meanwhile, if the null hypothesis is rejected $({\beta _3} \ne 0)$ , then sugar prices do affect SCP prices. Equation(2) is estimated under four specifications of SugarPrice to test the null hypothesis. In the first specification, SugarPrice is the quarterly sugar price, and in the second specification, SugarPrice is the one-quarter lagged sugar price, relative to the time-period SCP prices were collected. This was done to determine whether SCP prices are based on current sugar prices or previous (lagged) sugar prices. If sugar prices do affect SCP prices, it is likely they do not instantly change.Footnote 4 Thus, it is suspected that any relationship between sugar prices and SCP prices would be lagged by one-quarter. To keep the notation simple, equation(2) shows only the current price specification.

In the third sugar price model specification, SugarPrice is the US-to-world sugar price ratio and in the fourth specification it is the quarterly lagged US-to-world price ratio. This follows a similar approach to Trejo-Pech et al. (Reference Trejo-Pech, DeLong, Lambert and Siokos2020). The sugar relative price coefficient, β 3, is expected to be either positive or non-significant. A positive coefficient will imply that US sugar-using firms will increase prices whenever they find themselves in a competitive disadvantage relative to firms that can obtain sugar at world prices. This may occur in the following instances on which the US-to-world price ratios increase: when both US and world sugar prices increase but the US sugar price increases at a higher rate, when both US and world sugar prices decrease with US sugar prices decreasing at a lower rate, and in general when any combination of US and world sugar price changes increase the US to world sugar price ratio. Alternatively, the US-to-world sugar price coefficient will be zero if US sugar prices represent such a small percentage of SCP prices that US sugar firms do not make SCP pricing decisions based on sugar input price changes, regardless the relationship between US and sugar world prices.

To estimate the panel fixed-effects regression in equation(2), the xtreg command in Stata with the fe specification was used (StataCorp, 2017). The regression was estimated accounting for heteroscedasticity and contemporaneous correlation of the error terms through the vce(robust) command in Stata. This specification was used since the results of the xttest3 command (Baum, Reference Baum2001) provided a rejection of the test’s null hypothesis which means the error terms exhibited groupwise heteroscedasticity. The vce(robust) command results in the Huber/White/sandwich variance–covariance estimation (vce) estimator to be calculated for the regression coefficients (StataCorp, 2021). The coldiag2 command in Stata was used to determine if multicollinearity was an issue. If the estimated condition indexes for the variables are less than 30, the regression is considered free of collinearity issues (Belsley, Reference Belsley1991).

Data

Starting in 2008, the ASA created an annual database of SCPs. To qualify as a SCP, the product had to contain sugar (sucrose) as a primary ingredient (be at least the fifth listed ingredient on the product’s label) and the product had to contain at least 10% sugar by product weight. Sugar in this analysis is limited to sucrose; for example, soft drinks in this data set include only those made with real sugar (sucrose) and do not include those sweetened with high fructose corn syrup (HFCS). Annually (typically in June), the ASA collects data from grocery stores in the metropolitan Washington, D.C. area on a variety of SCPs. They collect the SCP prices as well as information from the respective products such as the product’s net weight and information from the nutritional facts panel such as serving size, servings per container, and grams of sugar per serving. Previous research has also used hand-collected data to estimate the passthrough effects of taxes on sugar-sweetened beverages (Cawley et al., Reference Cawley, Frisvold, Jones and Lensing2021).

For this analysis, only publicly traded companies with available financial accounting and stock price data in the Wharton Research Data Services (WRDS) database were analyzed since firm financial performance was controlled for in the analysis. Firm financial data were obtained specifically from WRDS’s Compustat Capital IQ Fundamentals Quarterly module, with the following items used to calculate financial variables in the model: total assets, total revenue, total equity, stock price, number of shares outstanding, and EPS. Thus, there is a panel of data by firm and SCP type ranging from 2008 through 2020 with the exception of 2011 when the ASA did not collect data.

The complete list of SCPs in the analysis, by firm and by year, appears in Appendix A. The firms in the analysis, and examples of their SCPs in the panel, are the following: Tootsie Roll (Junior Mints), The Hershey Company (e.g., Milk Duds, Hershey Bar, Hershey Bar with Almonds), Unilever (e.g., Klondike bars, Ben and Jerrys ice cream), The J.M. Smucker Company (e.g., Pillsbury cake and frostings), Pinnacle Foods and Conagra (e.g., Duncan Hines frosting and cake mixes), PepsiCo, Inc. (e.g., Pepsi Throwback, Quaker corn bread), Mondelez (e.g., Oreos), Kraft (Jello-O), and General Mills (e.g., Betty Crocker cake mixes and frostings). Appendix A also shows summary statistics by SCP firm (Table A1).

Summary statistics for the variables used in equation(2) appear in Table 2. There are a total of 379 observations in the sample. SCP prices were collected directly from the SCPs appearing in the grocery stores and, for this study, were adjusted for inflation using the CPI series published by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (2021) with August 2020 as the base year (i.e., the last month SCP prices were collected in the database). SCP price was then standardized by dividing it by the SCP’s net weight (in pounds). This is the dependent variable in the analysis, SCPprice. The average SCP price per pound (SCPprice) was $6.22/pound with a minimum price of $0.55/pound (Pepsi Throwback and Mountain Dew Throwback) and a maximum price of $17.95/pound (Hershey York Peppermint Pattie) (Table 2).

Sugar-Containing-Product Characteristics

The model was estimated using four SugarPrice specifications as shown in Table 1. The US wholesale refined beet sugar prices were considered for analysis, and they were adjusted for inflation using the CPI.Footnote 5 The US wholesale refined beet sugar price was utilized since this is the industry conventional benchmark for wholesale refined sugar dating back to 1960 (USDA ERS, 2021b). To construct the US-to-world sugar price ratio, the US wholesale refined beet sugar price was divided by the world wholesale refined sugar price.Footnote 6 Both prices were adjusted for inflation using the CPI.

Equation(2) was estimated using four SugarPrice specifications (i.e., US contemporaneous and lagged sugar prices, and US-to-world contemporaneous and lagged price ratios). Both wholesale refined beet sugar prices averaged around 33 cents/pound and ranged from around 23 cents/pound to 44 cents/pound. Both US-to-world sugar price ratios averaged around 1.8 with the lowest being 1.2 and the highest being 2.7. Figure 1 shows the annual relationship of wholesale refined beet sugar prices per pound and SCP prices per pound as well as the percentage of sugar in each product. As shown by Figure 1, sugar prices represent a small percentage of the SCP price.

Figure 1. Annual SCP prices, sugar prices, and sugar share of SCP weight.

The percentage of sugar (%Sugar) in each SCP was calculated from the weight of sugar in the product provided on the nutritional facts panel (in pounds) divided by the SCP weight provided on the package label (in pounds). The average percentage of sugar in SCPs was 48%, the minimum was 12% (Pepsi Throwback), and the maximum was 99% (Tootsie Roll Junior Mints). The SCP weight (Weight) is equal to the net weight of the SCP, which is found on the package of the SCP. The average weight was 1.17 pounds with the minimum SCP weight being 0.086 pounds (General Mills Betty Crocker muffin and quick bread mix-cinnamon streusel) and the maximum SCP weight being 9 pounds (Pepsi Throwback and Mountain Dew Throwback).

Sugar costs in the package per pound (SugarCostPackage) were also computed by multiplying %Sugar by the quarterly SugarPrice. Footnote 7 The average cost of sugar across all SCPs was 15.9 cents/pound, with a maximum of 44 cents/pound (Tootsie Roll Junior Mints) and a minimum of 2.7 cents/pound (Pepsi Throwback) (Table 2). Meanwhile, the average SCP price is $6.22/pound. Thus, the percentage of the cost of sugar across SCPs is only 2.56% of the total SCP price despite the fact that sugar consists of 48% of the SCP’s weight. Figure 2 shows this relationship from 2008 to 2020.

Figure 2. Cost of sugar in the sugar-containing-product (SCP) versus the SCP price.

Firm Size and Past Financial Performance

Sales growth (SalesGrowth) was calculated by first accumulating last-trailing-twelve-months (LTTM) revenues per quarter and then applying the formula (LTTM revenuest−1/LTTM revenuest−5)−1. The average one-quarter lagged annual sales growth for the firms in the sample was 3.1%. The lowest sales growth was −13.1% (Mondelez) and the maximum sales growth was 114% (Kraft).

EPS threshold (EPSthreshold) was calculated as in Zang (Reference Zang2012), EPSthreshold t is equal to one if EPSt−1/EPSt−2 ≤ 1.01, and zero otherwise, with the 12-months-moving-average basic EPS excluding extraordinary items, reported by Standard and Poor’s in the WRDS database. The average EPS threshold was 39% with the minimum being zero for several companies and the maximum being one for several companies. The LargeMarketVal was equal to 35%. The average firm market valuation was $5.5 billion with the smallest being $1.5 billion (Tootsie Roll Industries) and the largest being $270 billion (PespiCo Inc.) (Table 2).

Macroeconomic Conditions

Per capita disposable income (DispIncome) was adjusted for inflation using the CPI. On average, DispIncome was $39,334 with the lowest being $29,440 and the highest being $53,261. The US was marked as being in an economic recession from the fourth quarter of 2007 through the second quarter of 2009 and in 2020. On average, 17% of the SCP sample was collected during a recession (Table 2).

Results and Discussion

Table 3 shows the results of estimating equation(2) using the four different SugarPrice specifications using all SCPs. Since ice cream and soft drinks were heavier (Weight), equation(2) was also estimated excluding ice cream and soft drinks (Table 4). Multicollinearity was not an issue in any of the model specifications as the Condition Indexes for all the variables were less than 24 and anything under 30 is considered free of collinearity issues (Belsley, Reference Belsley1991). All models had high R 2 values of 0.85 in Table 3 and above 0.80 in Table 4. Since the results in Table 4 are very similar to Table 3, we primarily discuss only the results in Table 3.

Table 3. Panel fixed-effects regression results using quarterly lagged and quarterly sugar prices

* p < 0.05.

** p < 0.01.

*** p < 0.001.

Notes: The dependent variable is the natural log (ln) of SCPprice. SE is the variance–covariance estimation (VCE) robust standard error. SCP is the sugar-containing-product.

Table 4. Panel fixed-effects regression results using quarterly lagged and quarterly sugar prices and excluding ice cream and soft drinks

* p < 0.05.

** p < 0.01.

*** p < 0.001.

Notes: The dependent variable is the natural log (ln) of SCPprice. SE is the variance–covariance estimation (VCE) robust standard error. SCP is the sugar-containing-product.

Sugar-Containing-Product Characteristics

The coefficient on SugarPrice when considering quarterly lagged wholesale refined sugar prices, quarterly lagged US-to-world sugar prices, and US-to-world sugar prices is not significant.Footnote 8 Thus, there is no evidence that sugar prices are associated with SCP prices, and we fail to reject the null hypothesis that β 3 = 0 and conclude that sugar prices do not affect SCP prices. A possible explanation of why there is no statistically significant relationship between US sugar prices and US SCP prices is that US sugar costs represent a small percentage of US SCP prices (i.e., only 2.56% in this sample) despite being a large portion of the SCP’s weight (48% in this sample). However, when considering quarterly wholesale refined sugar prices, there is a negative and statistically significant relationship (p < 0.05) between sugar prices and SCP prices. This is the opposite of expectations and would indicate that as sugar prices increase, SCP prices actually decrease, ceteris paribus.Footnote 9 To investigate this further, we look to the results when we exclude soft drinks and ice cream from the analysis (estimating the model with more similar SCPs by weight). Under that model, this relationship no longer exists (Table 4).

Together, these results indicate that higher US sugar prices and higher relative sugar prices (compared to world sugar prices) do not result in increased SCP prices. This means there is no evidence to suggest that higher sugar prices are passed onto consumers through higher SCP prices when other factors are accounted for. The lack of a positive relationship refutes the SUA (2021) claims that US sugar policy causes sugar-using firms to pass on high costs of US sugar to consumers.

The percentage of sugar in the SCP (%Sugar) also did not have a statistically significant relationship with SCP prices. This is further evidence that characteristics related to the cost of sugar in the SCP have no effect on SCP prices. Despite critics of US sugar policy claiming high US sugar prices negatively impact consumers (SUA, 2021), it is hard to justify this allegation when sugar costs represent such a small fraction of SCP prices despite being a primary ingredient (Triantis, Reference Triantis2016; ASA, 2021). Similar to previous studies (Triantis, Reference Triantis2016; ASA, 2021), this study found that the cost of sugar in SCPs was only 2.56%. This is likely a rationale for why there was no statistically significant association between SCP prices and sugar prices (SugarPrices) or the percentage of sugar in the SCP (%Sugar).

Consistently across all model specifications, Weight was negative and significant (p < 0.001) (Table 3). As predicted, as the weight of the package increased, the SCP price per pound decreased. Across both sugar price specifications, if SCP weight increased by 10%, SCP price per pound decreased by 4.8%. It was hypothesized that this result could either be due to “shrinkflation” or simply because heavier products are cheaper per pound. By evaluating Table A1 in the appendix and micro-analyzing the raw data, it is apparent that within this data set, the results are likely driven by larger products (e.g., Pepsi Throwback, Oreos, Ice Cream) being cheaper per pound and weighing more than candy (e.g., Tootsie Roll, Hershey candy). From analyzing the raw data, it also appears that within this SCP data set products did not “shrink” over time. However, future research could find data where this phenomenon took place and investigate this issue further.

Firm Size and Past Financial Performance

For all model specifications, as expected, an increase (decrease) in lagged sales growth (SalesGrowth) increases (decreases) current SCP prices. Across all sugar price specifications in Table 3, a 10% increase in sales growth increases SCP prices by about 2% (p < 0.01). It is possible that firms make SCP pricing decisions based on recent sales growth performance. That is, firms increase SCP prices when sales positively grow, to test whether consumers are still willing to pay higher prices, and decrease prices when sales decline, to incentivize purchasing and avoid further sales growth deterioration. SCP firms ranked at the top 33% of firm market value size (LargeMarketVal) did not price SCPs differently. This indicates that market power does not affect pricing strategies.

Across all sugar price specifications, SCP prices increase following a quarter when firms do not meet their EPS thresholds (ESPthreshold) (i.e., when lagged EPS is lower or barely higher relative to the previous quarter’s EPS) (p < 0.001). This is expected as EPS in publicly traded firms is highly scrutinized by equity analysists and EPS growth is rewarded by investors. Indeed, financial managers recognize that earnings are the single most important financial metric they care about. This result suggests that not meeting the EPS threshold might put firms into temporarily financial distress causing them to increase SCP prices to increase profits.

Macroeconomic Conditions

As expected, as disposable income increases, SCP prices also increase (p < 0.001). As disposable income increases by 10%, SCP prices increase by around 7–8%. Results also suggest that SCP prices tend to be lower during economic recessions (Recessions), as expected. This indicates that sugar-using firms consider the demand for SCPs as somewhat elastic since both macroeconomic variables affect SCP prices (e.g., when in a recession SCPs are lower and when disposable income rises, they increase).

Conclusions and Policy Implications

US sugar policy regulates the amount of sugar domestic producers are allowed to market and the amount of sugar foreign countries are allowed to export to the US. This is done to buffer domestic producers against subsidized foreign sugar that depresses the world market price to levels well below world average sugar production costs (LMC International, 2021). This results in US sugar prices generally being higher than world sugar prices, opening the possibility that sugar-using firms pass these higher sugar costs onto consumers. Therefore, this research estimated a traditional hedonic pricing model using a unique data set to determine if US sugar prices are associated with SCP prices. This is the first known research to estimate the factors that influence SCP prices, which is important given SCPs represent a multibillion-dollar sector of the economy.

Results found that firm sales growth, firm historical EPS, SCP weight, and macroeconomic conditions were all statistically significant in determining SCP prices. However, it was not found that higher sugar prices or higher relative sugar prices (to the world) were associated with increased SCP prices. A possible explanation of why US sugar prices are not related to SCP prices is that among the SCPs in this sample, the average cost of sugar was only 2.56% of its total product price despite sugar representing nearly half of the SCP’s weight. The discovery that the commodity (sugar) value of the SCP is insignificant is consistent across other food groups (USDA, 2021c). For example, in 2019 it was estimated that farmers received only 14.3 cents from a typical dollar of food purchased (USDA, 2021c). In comparison, a sugar farmer receives even less than this amount from a typical dollar of a SCP purchased.

In terms of policies surrounding the sugar market, it is fascinating that on one end of the spectrum, critics contend US sugar prices are too low, which encourages overconsumption of SCPs and in turn contributes to the obesity epidemic (New York University, 2019). Those researchers suggest SCPs should be taxed to increase SCP prices and discourage SCP consumption (New York University, 2019). The literature on SCP taxes is vast and examines the passthrough effect of taxes on SCPs and the questionable effectiveness of taxes on decreasing consumption of SCPs (e.g., Cawley et al., Reference Cawley, Frisvold, Jones and Lensing2021; Lee et al., Reference Lee, Falbe, Schillinger, Basu, McCulloch and Madsen2019; Allcott, Lockwood, and Taubinsky, Reference Allcott, Lockwood and Taubinsky2019). On the other end of the spectrum, other critics contend US sugar prices are unfairly high and US companies should have better access to the world sugar market (SUA, 2021). Those companies argue that higher sugar prices are “unfairly” passed on to consumers (SUA, 2021).

We examine that declaration by being the first known research to estimate a hedonic pricing model of SCP prices. It was found that while several factors contribute to SCP prices, the percentage of sugar in the SCP and sugar prices (whether lagged, contemporaneous, or relative to world prices) did not have a positive and statistically significant impact on SCPs. Thus, sugar-using firms are not sensitive to US sugar price variation when pricing SCPs. Instead, those firms consider other SCP characteristics, their firm financial position, and macroeconomic conditions when pricing their products. This study ultimately concludes that US sugar policy does not negatively affect sugar-using firms.

Future research should further investigate the commodity value of the food dollar across various commodities and the transmission of commodity prices to food prices. It is important for farmers, policy makers, and consumers to understand what percentage of retail prices are attributable back to the farm, since this message likely resonates with the public. Furthermore, some agribusiness firms are characterized as having market power. Thus, future research should continue to consider firm size and financial performance in their analysis of food prices similar to this study. The results of this study are beneficial to sugar beet and sugarcane farmers as they begin their campaign to support current US sugar policy in the upcoming Farm Bill since this study shows that while sugar is an important, and many times the majority component of SCPs, it represents, on average, less than 3% of the SCP price. Furthermore, findings show that sugar’s price changes, whether higher or lower, have no effect on prices retail consumers pay for SCPs, from cake mixes to soft drinks to candy bars.

Data availability statement

The sugar-containing-product database was collected by the American Sugar Alliance (ASA) through grocery store observation. The remaining variable database was collected by the authors through publicly available USDA data and from financial data subscriptions. Publicly available data and codes are available upon request to authors.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the editor, three anonymous reviewers, and audience members at the Southern Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting for their helpful comments and discussion of this paper.

Author contributions

K.L.D. and C.O.T.P. conceptualization, data curation, formal analysis, funding acquisition, investigation, methodology, project administration, resources, software, supervision, validation, visualization, writing—original draft, and writing—review and editing.

Financial support

This work was supported by the ASA.

Competing interests

Funding for this project was supported by the ASA.

Appendix A: Sugar-Using Firms in the Data set

Below is the listing of the US publicly traded firms in the data set used to estimate equation(2). Also included is information on the brands/products included in the SCP data set by firm, the category of these products, and the years these SCPs by firm appear in the data set. Table A1 provides a breakdown of the descriptive statistics of the variables used to estimate equation(2) by firm.

US publicly traded firms in the data set and ingredient list following product (note that ingredients comprising less than 2% of the product are not listed):

Conagra (CAG)

Years in data set: 2019, 2020

N = 2

Notes: Acquired Duncan Hines brand from Pinnacle Foods in October 2018.

Brand/Products:

  • Duncan Hines Creamy Homestyle Frosting Chocolate (sugar, water, palm oil, cocoa powder processed with alkali, corn syrup, canola oil)

General Mills (GIS)

Years in data set: 2008, 2009, 2010, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020

N = 22

Brand/Products:

  • Betty Crocker Cream Cheese Frosting (sugar, palm oil, water, corn syrup, corn starch)

  • Betty Crocker Vanilla Cake Mix (sugar, palm oil, water, corn syrup, corn starch)

  • Betty Crocker Blueberry Muffin Mix (enriched flour bleached, sugar, artificially flavored blueberry bits, palm oil, corn syrup, dextrose, leavening, DATEM, soy lecithin, whey, sodium stearoyl lactylate, sodium caseinate, xanthan gum, cellulose gum, artificial flavor)

  • Betty Crocker muffin and quick bread mix (enriched flour bleached, sugar, vegetable oil, corn syrup, brown sugar, modified corn starch, leavening, cinnamon, salt, corn starch, monoglycerides, xanthan gum, cellulose gum, soy lecithin, color added)

Hershey Company (HSY)

Years in data set: 2008, 2009, 2010, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020

N = 212

Company notes: Kit Kat is only sold by Hershey in the US Nestle holds rights to Kit Kat globally. However, Nestle’s candy was sold to Froneri in March 2018 but Hershey still remains able to sell Kit Kat in the US.

HSY Brand/Products in data set:

  • Almond Joy (corn syrup, milk chocolate (sugar, cocoa butter, chocolate, milk, lactose, milkfat, nonfat milk, lecithin, PGPR, coconut, sugar, almonds))

  • Bag of Hugs (milk chocolate (sugar, milk chocolate, cocoa butter, milk fat, lecithin, natural flavor), sugar, vegetable oil, nonfat milk, corn syrup solids, lactose)

  • Bag of Kisses (milk chocolate (sugar, milk, chocolate, cocoa butter, milk fat, lecithin, natural flavor))

  • Bag of Minatare Hershey Bars (milk chocolate (sugar, milk, chocolate, cocoa butter, milk fat, lecithin (soy), PGPR, natural flavor))

  • Chocolate syrup (high fructose corn syrup, corn syrup, water, cocoa, sugar)

  • Hershey Bar Milk Chocolate (sugar, milk, chocolate, cocoa butter, milk fat, lecithin, natural flavor)

  • Hershey Bar with Almonds (milk chocolate (sugar, milk, chocolate, cocoa butter, milk fat, lecithin, natural flavor), almonds, sunflower oil)

  • Hershey Cookies and Cream Bar (sugar, vegetable oil, nonfat milk, corn syrup solids, enriched wheat flour, lactose)

  • Jolly Ranchers (corn syrup, sugar)

  • Kit Kat (sugar, wheat flour, nonfat milk, cocoa butter, chocolate, palm kernel oil, milk fat, lactose (milk))

  • Milk Duds (corn syrup, sugar, vegetable oil, dextrose, nonfat milk, reduced protein whey, chocolate)

  • Good & Plenty (sugar, corn syrup, enriched wheat flour)

  • Mounds (corn syrup, semi-sweet chocolate (chocolate, sugar, cocoa, milk fat, cocoa butter, soy lecithin, PGPR, emulsifier, vanillin, artificial flavor, milk), coconut, sugar)

  • Payday (peanuts, sugar, corn syrup, skim milk, vegetable oil)

  • Reese’s Cups (milk chocolate (sugar, cocoa butter, chocolate, skim milk, milk fat, lactose, lecithin, PGPR), peanuts, sugar, dextrose, salt, TBHQ, citric acid).

  • Rolo (sugar, corn syrup, high fructose corn syrup, skim milk, vegetable oil, hydrogenated vegetable oil, chocolate)

  • Twizzlers (corn syrup, enriched wheat flour, sugar)

  • York Patty (sugar, corn syrup, semi-sweet chocolate (chocolate, sugar cocoa, ilk fat, lecithin, cocoa butter, PGPR emulsifier, natural flavor, milk), invert sugar, egg whites, oil of peppermint)

  • Whoppers (sugar, corn syrup, hydrogenated palm kernel oil, whey, cocoa, malted milk, confectioner’s glaze, lecithin, salt, natural flavor, artificial flavor, calcium carbonate, tapioca dextrin)

J.M. Smucker Company (SJM)

Years in data: 2008, 2009, 2010, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018

N = 20

Company notes: The SJM products in our list are all Pillsbury. Brynwood Partners (private) bought Pillsbury baking mixes from SJM in July 2018. Thus, we only use the data on Pillsbury mixes through 2018 since SJM sold it off.

Brand/Products:

  • Pillsbury Yellow Cake (enriched bleached flour, sugar, leavening)

  • Pillsbury Supreme Frosting (sugar, palm oil, water, corn syrup, corn starch, canola oil)

Kraft (KHC)

Years in data set: 2009, 2010, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020

N = 12

Brand/Product:

  • Strawberry Jello (sugar, gelatin, adipic acid)

  • Cherry Jello (sugar, gelatin, adipic acid)

Mondelez (MDLZ)

Years in data set: 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020

N = 34

Company notes: MDLZ is a spinoff of Kraft in 2001.

Brand/Products:

  • Oreos (sugar, unbleached enriched flour, riboflavin, palm and/or canola oil, cocoa, high fructose corn syrup, leavening, salt, soy lecithin, chocolate, artificial flavor)

PepsiCo, Inc. (PEP)

Years in data set: 2009, 2010, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020

N = 22

Notes: Pepsi throwback uses real sugar so only those drinks were used in our analysis.

Brand/Products:

  • Pepsi Throwbacks (carbonated water, sugar, caramel color, phosphoric acid, caffeine, natural flavor)

  • Mountain Dew Throwback (carbonated water, sugar, orange juice concentrate, citric acid, natural flavor, sodium benzoate, caffeine, sodium citrate, gum Arabic, erythorbic acid, calcium disodium EDTA, brominated vegetable oil, yellow 5)

  • Quaker corn bread (wheat flour, degerminated yellow corn meal, sugar, animal shortening)

Pinnacle Foods (PF)

Years in data set: 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018

N = 10

Company notes: Pinnacle Foods was privately held until it went public in 2013. Thus, we only use data starting in 2013. Also, in 2018 Conagra acquired the Duncan Hines brand from Pinnacle Foods. Thus, Conagra (CAG) is the owner of Duncan Hines in 2019, 2020 in our data set.

Brand/Products:

  • Duncan Hines Creamy Homestyle Frosting Chocolate (sugar, water, palm oil, cocoa powder processed with alkali, corn syrup, canola oil)

Tootsie Roll Industries (TR)

Years in data set: 2009, 2010, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020

N = 10

Brand/Products:

  • Junior Mints (sugar, semi-sweet chocolate (sugar, chocolate processed with alkali, cocoa butter, soy lecithin-an emulsifier, vanillin-an artificial flavor), corn syrup, confectioner’s glaze, food starch-modified, peppermint oil, invertase (an enzyme))

Unilever (UL)

Years in data set: 2008, 2009, 2010, 2017, 2018

N = 35

Brands/Products:

  • Good Humor (Breyers) Ice Cream (milk, cream, sugar, egg yolks, corn syrup, whey, vegetable gums, mono and diglycerides, natural flavors, annatto, salt)

  • Klondike Bar (nonfat milk, sugar, coconut oil, cream, corn syrup, whew, chocolate liquor processed with alkali)

Table A1. Descriptive statistics by firm

Appendix B

Table B1. Panel fixed-effects regression results using quarterly lagged and quarterly sugar and HFCS prices

* p < 0.05.

** p < 0.01.

*** p < 0.001.

Notes: The dependent variable is the natural log (ln) of SCPprice. SE is the variance–covariance estimation (VCE) robust standard error. SCP is sugar-containing-product. HFCSPrice is the quarterly HFCS wholesale spot price for HFCS-42 (USDA ERS, 2021b) and has been adjusted by the Consumer Price Index similar to other price variables.

Footnotes

1 Holding other things constant, when the percent increase in cost equals the percent increase in price, profitability increases due to profit margins (i.e., the dollar value increase of revenues is higher than the dollar value increase in cost).

2 As will be explained later in this document, some variables are lagged with respect to SCP prices. To facilitate the exposition in this section, equation(1) shows a contemporaneous relationship between the dependent variable and all explanatory variables.

3 We modified Zang’s (Reference Zang2012) definition, who uses EPSthreshold t−1 = 1 if EPSt−1 − EPSt−2 ≤ $0.02, 0 otherwise. Instead of using the minuscule threshold level amount proposed by Zang (i.e., 2 cents per share), we use a minuscule percentage (i.e., 1%), to consider the fact that EPS may vary significantly across firms with different earnings scales or shares outstanding. The 1% threshold we use is consistent with the 1% used by Gunny (Reference Gunny2010) for return on assets thresholds.

4 The literature on passthrough prices argues that food prices are "sticky," implying that sometimes it takes some time for prices to be passed from a supply level (e.g., wholesale price changes) to the next (e.g., retail price changes). Vavra and Goodwin (Reference Vavra and Goodwin2005) provide a summary of this literature and argue that empirical results in this regard are mixed, that is, prices are sticky for some products and may change rapidly for others.

5 US wholesale refined beet sugar prices are in the Table 5 tab of the “World, US, and Mexican sugar and corn sweetener prices” dataset.

6 World refined sugar prices are in the Table 2 tab of the “World, US, and Mexican sugar and corn sweetener prices” dataset.

7 Note that SugarCostPackage is not included in the regression since %Sugar and SugarPrice are included instead.

8 Additionally, upon advice from a reviewer, we also considered a specification of equation(2) where HFCS prices are considered as an additional independent variable in case any firms consider sucrose and HFCS ingredient substitutes depending on relative prices. The results of this model appear in Appendix B. HFCS and sugar prices in this model were also not significant.

9 This result could be explained by the notion of “sticky” prices (Vavra and Goodwin, Reference Vavra and Goodwin2005) and since this model considers contemporaneous sugar prices rather than lagged sugar prices, any price transmission has not had time to occur.

* p < 0.05.

** p < 0.01.

*** p < 0.001.

References

Allcott, H., Lockwood, B.B., and Taubinsky, D.Regressive Sin Taxes, with an Application to the Optimal Soda Tax.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 134,3(2019):15571626.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
American Sugar Alliance. Charts and Graphs, 2021. Internet site: https://sugaralliance.org/wp-content/uploads/2021/04/Charts-for-the-website.pdf Google Scholar
Banz, R.The Relationship Between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks.” Journal of Financial Economics 9,1(1981):318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baum, C.F.Residual Diagnostics for Cross-Section Time Series Regression Models.” The Stata Journal 1,1(2001):101–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belsley, D.A.A Guide to Using the Collinearity Diagnostics.” Computer Science in Economics and Management 4,1(1991):3350.Google Scholar
Bettendorf, L., and Verboven, F.Incomplete Transmission of Coffee Bean Prices in the Netherlands.” European Review of Agricultural Economics 27,1(2000):116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bureau of Economic Analysis. National Accounts, Section 2: Personal Income and Outlays, 2021. Internet site: https://apps.bea.gov/histdata/fileStructDisplay.cfm?HMI=7&DY=2021&DQ=Q2&DV=Third&dNRD=October-1-2021 Google Scholar
Carter, C.A., and Schaefer, K.A.Impacts of Mandatory GE Food Labeling: A Quasi-Natural Experiment.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 101,1(2019):5873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cawley, J., Frisvold, D., Jones, D., and Lensing, C.The Pass-Through of a Tax on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages in Boulder, Colorado.” Colorado American Journal of Agricultural Economics 103,3(2021):9871005 DOI 10.1111/ajae.12191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elobeid, A., and Beghin, J.Multilateral Trade and Agricultural Policy Reforms in Sugar Markets.” Journal of Agricultural Economics 57,1(2006):2348 DOI 10.1111/j.1477-9552.2006.00030.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, E.F., and French, K.R.Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds.” Journal of Financial Economics 33,1(1993):356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghazaryan, A., Westgren, R., Parcell, J., and Gedikoglu, H.Factors Affecting Farmers Market Produce Prices in Missouri.” Journal of Food Products Marketing 24,8(2018):927–45 DOI 10.1080/10454446.2017.1422843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, J., Harvey, C., and Rajgopal, S.Value Destruction and Financial Reporting Decisions.” Financial Analysts Journal 62,6(2006):2739.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gunny, K.The Relation Between Earnings Management Using Real Activities Manipulation and Future Performance: Evidence from Meeting Earnings Benchmarks.” Contemporary Accounting Research 27,3(2010):855–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, S.F., Liaukonyte, J., and Richards, T.Pricing Strategies of Food Retailers.” Annual Review of Resource Economics 12,1(2020):87119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodari, D.Sugar Low: Commodity Plummets on Surplus.” The Wall Street Journal, May 1, 2018, 2018. Internet site: https://blogs.wsj.com/moneybeat/2018/05/01/sugar-low-commodity-plummets-on-surplus/ Google Scholar
Hudson, D. An Examination of Foreign Subsidies and Trade Policies for Sugar. Texas Tech University, 2019, pp. 132.Google Scholar
IBIS World . Candy, Soda, Baking Mix, Snack Food, and Ice Cream Production in the US, 2020. Internet site: https://www.ibisworld.com/ Google Scholar
Kennedy, P., and Schmitz, A.Production Response to Increased Imports: The Case of U.S. Sugar.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 41,3(2009):777–89 DOI 10.1017/S1074070800003217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, P.L., Schmitz, A., and DeLong, K.L.Biotechnology and Demand Concerns: The Case of Genetically Modified Sugar Beets.” AgBioForum 22,1(2019):113. http://www.agbioforum.org/v22n1/v22n1-kennedy.htm Google Scholar
Knutson, R., Westhoff, P., and Sherwell, P.Trade Liberalizing Impacts of NAFTA in Sugar: Global Implications.” International Food and Agribusiness Management Review 13,4(2010):116.Google Scholar
Lee, M.M., Falbe, J., Schillinger, D., Basu, S., McCulloch, C.E., and Madsen, K.A.Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Consumption Three Years after the Berkeley, California, Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax.” American Journal of Public Health 109,4(2019):637–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, K.E., and Grebitus, C.Why U.S. Consumers Support Country of Origin Labeling: Examining the Impact of Ethnocentrism and Food Safety.” Journal of International Food & Agribusiness Marketing 28,3(2016):254–70 DOI 10.1080/08974438.2015.1110548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, K.E., Grebitus, C., and Nayga, R. Jr.U.S. Consumer Preferences for Imported and Genetically Modified Sugar: Examining Policy Consequentiality in a Choice Experiment.” Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics 65,3(2016a):18 DOI 10.1016/j.socec.2016.10.001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, K.E., Grebitus, C., and Nayga, R. JrThe Impact of Brand and Attention on Consumers’ Willingness to Pay: Evidence from an Eye Tracking Experiment.” Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 64,4(2016b):753–77 DOI 10.1111/cjag.12118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, K.E., Grebitus, C., and Nayga, R. JrThe Importance of Taste in Experimental Auctions: Consumers’ Valuation of Calorie and Sweetener Labeling of Soft Drinks.” Agricultural Economics 47,1(2016c):4757 DOI 10.1111/agec.12208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, K., and Schmitz, T.The Impact of Partial Mexican Government Sugar Industry Ownership on U.S. and Mexican Sugar Trade.” Journal of Agribusiness 33,1(2015):1738.Google Scholar
LMC International. World Sugar Prices vs Costs of Production. Oxford: LMC International, 2021.Google Scholar
Nakamura, E.Pass-Through in Retail and Wholesale.” American Economic Review 98,2(2008):430–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nakamura, E., and Zerom, D.Accounting for Incomplete Pass-Through.” The Review of Economic Studies 77,3(2010):1192–230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
National Bureau of Economic Research.US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions National Bureau of Economic Research., 2021. Internet site: https://www.nber.org/research/data/us-business-cycle-expansions-and-contractions Google Scholar
National Public Radio. Beware of ‘Shrinkflation,’ Inflation’s Devious Cousin, 2021. Internet site: https://www.npr.org/sections/money/2021/07/06/1012409112/beware-of-shrinkflation-inflations-devious-cousin Google Scholar
New York University. Taxing Sweetened Drinks by the Amount of Sugar Could Cut Obesity and Boost Economic Gains, 2019. Internet site: https://www.nyu.edu/about/news-publications/news/2019/september/taxing-sweetened-drinks-by-the-amount-of-sugar-could-cut-obesity.html Google Scholar
Rao, V.Chapter 11: Pricing Models in Marketing.” Marketing. Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science, Vol. 5. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1993, pp. 517–52. 10.1016/S0927-0507(05)80034-9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richards, T.J., and Hamilton, S.F.Variety Pass-through: An Examination of the Ready-to-Eat Breakfast Cereal Market.” Review of Economics and Statistics 97,1(2015):166–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richards, T.J., Hamilton, S.F., and Yonezawa, K.Variety and the Cost of Search in Supermarket Retailing.” Review of Industrial Organization 50,3(2017):263–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitz, T.Impact of the 2014 Suspension Agreement on sugar between the United States and Mexico.” Agricultural Economics 49,1(2018):5569 DOI 10.1111/agec.12395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitz, T., and Lewis, K.Impact of NAFTA on U.S. and Mexican Sugar Markets.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 40,3(2015):387404.Google Scholar
StataCorp. Stata Statistical Software. 15th ed. College Station, TX: StataCorp, 2017.Google Scholar
StataCorp. Manual for xtreg, 2021. Internet site: https://www.stata.com/manuals13/xtxtreg.pdf Google Scholar
Sweetener Users Association. SUA Applauds USDA for Allowing Additional Raw Sugar Imports, 2021. Internet site: https://sweetenerusers.org/2020/09/09/sua-applauds-usda-for-allowing-additional-raw-sugar-imports/ Google Scholar
Trejo-Pech, C., Noguera, M., and White, S.Financial Ratios Used by Equity Analysts in Mexico and Stock Returns.” Contaduría y Administración 60,3(2015):578–92 DOI 10.1016/j.cya.2015.02.001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trejo-Pech, C., DeLong, K.L., Lambert, D., and Siokos, V.The Impact of US Sugar Prices on the Financial Performance of US Sugar-Using Firms.” Agricultural and Food Economics 8,1(2020):16 DOI 10.1186/s40100-020-00161-5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trejo-Pech, C., Weldon, R., and Gunderson, M.Earnings Management through Specific Accruals and Discretionary Expenses: Evidence from U.S. Agribusiness Firms.” Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d’agroeconomie 64,1(2016):89118 DOI 10.1111/cjag.12063.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Triantis, A. Economic Effects of The U.S. Sugar Policy. American Sugar Alliance, 2016. https://sugaralliance.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/10/Triantis-Sugar-Policy-Study.pdf Google Scholar
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Price Index, 2021. Internet site: https://www.bls.gov/cpi/ Google Scholar
USDA ERS. Sugar and Sweeteners Policy, 2021a. Internet site: https://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/crops/sugar-sweeteners/policy/ Google Scholar
USDA ERS. Sugar and Sweeteners Yearbook Tables, 2021b. Internet site: https://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/sugar-and-sweeteners-yearbook-tables/ Google Scholar
USDA ERS. Food Dollar Appreciation, 2021c. Internet site: =https://data.ers.usda.gov/reports.aspx?ID=17885 Google Scholar
Vavra, P., and Goodwin, B.. Analysis of Price Transmission Along the Food Chain, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 3. Paris: OECD Publishing, 2005. https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/752335872456 Google Scholar
Volpe, R., Risch, C., and Boland, M.The Determinants of Price Adjustments in Retail Supermarkets.” Managerial and Decision Economics 38,1(2017):3752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zahniser, S., Kennedy, L., Nigatu, G., and McConnell, M. A New Outlook for the U.S.-Mexico Sugar and Sweetener Market (No. SSSM-335-01; p. 53), 2016. Internet site: =https://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/pub-details/?pubid=74634 Google Scholar
Zang, A.Evidence on the Trade-Off between Real Activities Manipulation and Accrual-Based Earnings Management.” The Accounting Review 87,2(2012):675703 DOI 10.2308/accr-10196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Variables, definitions, and hypothesized signs

Figure 1

Table 2. Summary statistics of sugar-containing-product (SCP) prices, SCP characteristics, firm financial performance, and recessions

Figure 2

Figure 1. Annual SCP prices, sugar prices, and sugar share of SCP weight.

Figure 3

Figure 2. Cost of sugar in the sugar-containing-product (SCP) versus the SCP price.

Figure 4

Table 3. Panel fixed-effects regression results using quarterly lagged and quarterly sugar prices

Figure 5

Table 4. Panel fixed-effects regression results using quarterly lagged and quarterly sugar prices and excluding ice cream and soft drinks

Figure 6

Table A1. Descriptive statistics by firm

Figure 7

Table B1. Panel fixed-effects regression results using quarterly lagged and quarterly sugar and HFCS prices