Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T21:23:36.831Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Love of novelty: a source of innovation-based growth… or underdevelopment traps?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 May 2023

Yuichi Furukawa*
Affiliation:
Chuo University, Hachioji, Japan RIETI, Tokyo, Japan
Tat-kei Lai
Affiliation:
IESEG School of Management, Univ. Lille, CNRS, UMR 9221 - LEM - Lille Economie Management, F-59000 Lille, France
Kenji Sato
Affiliation:
Osaka Metropolitan University, Osaka, Japan
*
Corresponding author: Y. Furukawa; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This study develops a new dynamic general equilibrium model to explore the role of people’s love of novelty as a cultural preference in innovation and innovation-based growth. The model considers (a) an infinitely lived representative consumer who has standard love-of-variety preferences for differentiated products and additional love-of-novelty preferences for new products and (b) technological progress driven by two costly and time-consuming innovation activities, new product development and existing product development. We demonstrate that consumers’ love of novelty is a source of innovation-based growth, wherein economies with a moderate love of novelty can achieve innovation and long-run growth through endogenous cycles between periods in which new product development is active and those in which existing product development is active. However, if love of novelty preference is too weak or too strong, the economy is caught in an underdevelopment trap with less innovation and no long-run growth. We also provide some suggestive empirical evidence that supports our theoretical predictions.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

It is a commonplace assertion in economics that culture—like institutions and geography—is a fundamental cause of cross-country differences in macroeconomic performance (Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2005)). However, as Mokyr (Reference Mokyr2005) argues, from both theoretical and empirical perspectives, it is still unclear how and to what extent culture explains such differences. A large body of literature has examined this question, considering such dimensions as preferences, entrepreneurial traits, religion, and family ties.Footnote 1 This study provides a new approach to this growing research agenda by clarifying the importance of the desire for new ideas (or “love of novelty”) as an individual cultural preference.

Love of novelty is widely considered important for innovation. For example, Fagerberg (Reference Fagerberg and Fagerberg2004, Reference Fagerberg2013) argues that “‘openness’ to new ideas, solutions, etc. is essential for innovation” because innovation requires people and firms to “search widely for new ideas, inputs and sources of inspiration.” Given that innovation is considered a major driver of long-run growth in macroeconomics (Romer, (Reference Romer1990), Grossman and Helpman (Reference Grossman and Helpman1991), Aghion and Howitt (Reference Aghion and Howitt1992)), a relevant research question is to identify the role of people’s love of novelty as a cultural preference in terms of macroeconomic performance such as innovation and growth.

To motivate our theoretical analysis, we first show in Figure 1 some country-level relationships between love of novelty (using data from the World Values Survey) and innovation (using data from World Intellectual Property Organization and other databases). This figure shows an inverted-U relationship between love of novelty and innovations and a positive relationship between love of novelty and original innovations, suggesting that the relationship between love of novelty and innovation can be non-trivial.Footnote 2

Figure 1. Scatter plots. Note: This figure shows various scatter plots between love of novelty (measured by Question E046 of the world values survey) and measures of innovation. Further details about the data sources and the variables are in the Appendix.

Our theoretical analysis extends Matsuyama (Reference Matsuyama1999, Reference Matsuyama2001) by incorporating the following new features.Footnote 3 First, we assume that an infinitely lived representative consumer has preferences for both differentiated products (“love of variety”) and new products (“love of novelty”). Second, we incorporate the well-accepted view that each single innovation involves a combination of new and existing product development (OECD 2018).Footnote 4 Specifically, in our model, new ideas are first invented as original products, and they are transformed and developed into “old” products through existing product development.

Our core finding is that, depending on its level, love of novelty can play different roles in innovation and growth: (a) When love of novelty preference is weak, firms invent fewer original products, even though they are the source of existing product development. Since each innovation requires new and existing product development, the aggregate level of innovation is too small for the economy to achieve long-run growth, resulting in an underdevelopment trap. (b) When love of novelty is moderate, both types of innovation perpetually occur along an equilibrium path, however cyclically. Along the equilibrium path, periods in which new product development occurs and periods in which existing product development alternate,Footnote 5 whereby the economy achieves long-run growth through innovation cycles. (c) In the case of strong love of novelty, firms eventually invest exclusively in inventing new products; thus, no improvements to old products occur in the long-run equilibrium. In this case, the economy is trapped in a situation where new goods are invented constantly, but they rarely survive in the absence of existing product development. As in the case of weak love of novelty, the economy loses the balance between the two types of innovation; the aggregate level of innovation is too low to achieve long-run growth, further resulting in an underdevelopment trap. Therefore, the overall effect of love of novelty is ambiguous: moderate love of novelty is a fundamental source of innovation-based growth (consistent with what is generally believed), but weak or strong love of novelty can cause an underdevelopment trap. We also calibrate the model to US data to simulate the transition dynamics of the economy switching between the two different innovation processes.

The theoretical findings above support the widely accepted view that culture is a fundamental cause of cross-country differences in macroeconomic performance, by considering an important aspect of national culture—the public’s love of novelty. Since different people or regions typically have different attitudes toward novel things overall (e.g., Rogers (Reference Rogers1962), Tellis et al. (Reference Tellis, Yin and Bell2009)), love of novelty as a national characteristic may be a core determinant of economic growth and development. Specifically, our finding implies that the lack or excess of the public’s love of novelty is a fundamental cause of underdevelopment. This supports the view of Mokyr (Reference Mokyr2000), who asserts that cultural preference for new ideas is “highly relevant to the experience of underdeveloped countries whose failure to adopt best-practice technologies is often regarded as an integral part of underdevelopment.”

This paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 discusses our contributions relative to the existing literature. Section 3 presents the basic model, and Section 4 characterizes the equilibrium dynamics of the model. Section 5 identifies the critical role of the love of novelty in innovation and growth in the long run. Section 6 provides a quantitative analysis. Finally, Section 7 offers some concluding remarks.

2. Related literature

Our study contributes to the literature on innovation-based growth (Romer (Reference Romer1990), Grossman and Helpman (Reference Grossman and Helpman1991), Aghion and Howitt (Reference Aghion and Howitt1992)). While, as we first mentioned, the importance of culture as an essential source of growth is widely perceived in economics, few studies explore the role of cultural aspects of people’s preferences in innovation-based growth. Chu (Reference Chu2007), for example, notably argues that entrepreneurial overconfidence can cause different economic growth rates across countries, using a standard innovation-based growth model.Footnote 6 More recently, Pan et al. (Reference Pan, Zhang and Zou2018), Hof and Prettner (Reference Hof and Prettner2019), and Chu et al. (Reference Chu, Cozzi, Pan and Zhang2020) have examined status-seeking preferences in the innovation-based growth model. Our study contributes to this literature by examining the role of consumer love of novelty as a cultural source of innovation-based growth.

Broadly interpreting the meaning of culture or cultural preferences, our study also relates to Galor and Michalopoulos (Reference Galor and Michalopoulos2012) and Doepke and Zilibotti (Reference Doepke and Zilibotti2014). They identify the critical role of entrepreneurial traits in innovation and economic growth by considering the endogenous evolution of a fraction of people who exhibit entrepreneurial spirit (in terms of risk tolerance). Given that entrepreneurial traits should be partially attributable to culture, their studies and ours contribute to the literature on culture, innovation, and growth by examining different cultural factors.Footnote 7

More broadly, several studies examine the role of culture in other classes of the endogenous growth model. For example, Cozzi (Reference Cozzi1998) considers a cultural asset unproductive at the individual level, traded between different generations, yet has positive external effects on productivity growth. He further shows that culture can be a bubble that causes dynamic indeterminacy and self-fulfilling stagnation. Thus, the role of culture in his model is ambiguous in that it can encourage or discourage economic growth. Galor and Moav (Reference Galor and Moav2002) show that individual preferences for offspring quality contribute to population growth and human capital formation. Subsequent studies by Ashraf and Galor (Reference Ashraf and Galor2007, Reference Ashraf and Galor2013a, Reference Ashraf and Galor2013b, Reference Ashraf and Galor2018) explore cultural/genetic diversity and regional development at different stages and places.Footnote 8 Several studies in this line of research have identified the ambiguous role of some cultural factors, as in our study. For example, Ashraf and Galor (Reference Ashraf and Galor2013a) show an inverted U-shaped relationship between genetic diversity within a country and regional economic development.

We also contribute to the theoretical literature on innovation cycles by identifying the love of novelty as a novel factor for cyclical innovation (Judd (Reference Judd1985), Shleifer (Reference Shleifer1986), Deneckere and Judd (Reference Deneckere, Judd, Deneckere and Judd1992), Gale (Reference Gale1996), Francois and Shi (Reference Francois and Shi1999), Matsuyama (Reference Matsuyama1999, Reference Matsuyama2001), Furukawa (Reference Furukawa2015), Sunaga (Reference Sunaga2017), and Yano and Furukawa (Reference Yano and Furukawa2023)). In the main analysis, following this theoretical literature, we assume that the innovator can enjoy only a single-period monopoly, and we demonstrate that when the love of novelty is moderate, innovation is cyclical on an equilibrium path. On this cyclical path, the two types of innovations, new and existing product development, perpetually alternate on an equilibrium path. As explained above, it is reasonably justifiable because the duration of patent protection, or, more generally, monopoly power, can persist for only a finite period in reality. Allowing for a multiperiod monopoly, from a more general perspective, Iwaisako and Futagami (Reference Iwaisako and Futagami2007) identify an essential role of the temporary nature of monopoly in growth cycles in an innovation-based growth model with a finite patent length.Footnote 9 Our study extends these by developing a new model of innovation and growth cycles and characterizing the role of consumer love of novelty as a source of innovation cycles.

Lastly, our study is related to the literature on two-stage innovation models. Most models in this literature have distinguished basic and applied research (see, e.g., Aghion and Howitt (Reference Aghion and Howitt1996), Michelacci (Reference Michelacci2003), Akiyama(Reference Akiyama2009), Cozzi and Galli (Reference Cozzi and Galli2009, Reference Cozzi and Galli2013, Reference Cozzi and Galli2014), Acs and Sanders (Reference Acs and Sanders2012), Chu et al. (Reference Chu, Cozzi and Galli2012), Chu and Furukawa (Reference Chu and Furukawa2013), Konishi (Reference Konishi2018)). We consider two separate activities of applied innovation; thus, firms earn profits in both stages of innovation. This differs from existing models, in which there is no profit in the early, basic research stages of innovation. Therefore, our study complements the literature by first considering two commercial stages of innovation and further characterizing the role of consumer love of novelty on aggregate innovation and growth.

3. Innovation-based growth model with love of novelty

This section presents our basic innovation-based growth model, following Matsuyama (Reference Matsuyama1999, Reference Matsuyama2001). As in his models, innovation occurs endogenously as a product of the firms’ profit-seeking R&D investment, and the variety of products increases over time (Romer (Reference Romer1990)) with the assumption that firms can only enjoy temporary (one period) monopoly power. This assumption is used because new and old products play separate but essential roles in equilibrium, facilitating the modeling of people’s love of novelty—as will be apparent later.

Our model demonstrates two new assumptions to investigate the role of love of novelty of optimizing agents. First, we assume that the representative agent is endowed with the standard love-of-product variety and love of novelty; therefore, they would have some extra weight on new products compared with old products.Footnote 10 Second, we think of two types of innovation: one is to invent new products, and the other is to ensure invented products have a long life in the market. We refer to these two types of innovation as new and existing product development, which both require R&D investment by profit-seeking firms.

3.1 Consumption and love of novelty

An infinitely lived representative agent inelastically supplies $L$ units of labor during each period. The representative agent solves the standard dynamic optimization of consumption and saving over an infinite horizon:

(1) \begin{equation} \max U=\sum _{t=0}^{\infty }\beta ^{t}\ln{u{(t),}} \end{equation}

where $\beta \in (0,1)$ is the time preference rate, and $u(t)$ is an index of consumption in period $t$ . We assume that periodic utility $u$ is defined over differentiated consumption goods, and each is indexed by $j$ .Footnote 11 Namely, the agent is endowed with so-called love-of-variety preferences. As is standard, we consider a constant elasticity of substitution utility function:

(2) \begin{equation} u(t)=\left ( \int _{j\in A(t)\cup N(t)}(\varepsilon (j,t)\ {x(j,t))^{\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }}dj}\right ) ^{\frac{\sigma }{\sigma -1}}\text{, } \end{equation}

where $x(j,t)$ represents the consumption of good $j$ in period $t,$ $\sigma \geq 1$ represents the elasticity of substitution between any two consumption goods, and $\varepsilon (j,t)$ is a variable determining the consumer’s preference for each good, $j$ . Here, the consumption goods are categorized into two types: new goods and old goods. Let $N(t)$ be the set of new goods invented in period $t$ and $A(t)$ be the set of old goods invented prior to period $t.$ To simplify the description, let $A(t)$ and $N(t)$ also denote the number (measure) of goods.

When considering the innate love of novelty, we assume that the representative agent is endowed with love-of-novelty preferences, in addition to the standard love-of-variety preferences.

First, we attempt to observe a benchmark wherein the consumer prefers new goods and old goods equally; there is no particular love of novelty. In this case, all goods should have identical $\varepsilon (j,t)$ for all $j\in A(t)\cup N(t)$ . Normalizing this parameter to 1, the consumer’s utility function can be written as

(3) \begin{equation} u(t)=\left ( \int _{j\in A(t)}{x(j,t)^{\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }}dj+}\int _{j\in N(t)}{x(j,t)^{\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }}dj}\right ) ^{\frac{\sigma }{\sigma -1}}. \end{equation}

Now, suppose that the consumer has some extra preference, ${\varepsilon },$ for novelty that he/she considers in terms of a good being new or a condition in which a good is new:

(4) \begin{equation} \varepsilon (j,t)=\left \{ \begin{array} [c]{ll}1 & \text{if }j\in A(t)\ \text{(old goods)}\\{\varepsilon } & \text{if }j\in N(t)\ \text{(new goods)}\end{array} \right. . \end{equation}

Applying (4) to (2) yields

(5) \begin{equation} u(t)=\left ( \int _{j\in A(t)}{x(j,t)^{\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }}dj+}\int _{j\in N(t)}{({\varepsilon } \, x(j,t))^{\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }}dj}\right ) ^{\frac{\sigma }{\sigma -1}}. \end{equation}

When ${\varepsilon }=1,$ first, the consumer has no preference for novelty and prefers all goods equally, as in (3). This provides the benchmark, which has been intensively investigated in the literature. When $\varepsilon \gt 1,$ the consumer has a love of novelty and prefers new goods to old goods. The higher ${\varepsilon },$ the stronger the love of novelty. To retain generality, we also allow for $\varepsilon \lt 1.$ When $\varepsilon \lt 1,$ the consumer’s love of novelty is very weak, or we can say that the consumer has a so-called “fear of novelty” (Barber (Reference Barber1961)), preferring old goods to new goods. This sort of negative preference for novelty can also be observed in reality and develops from people’s innate “mental resistance to new ideas” (Beveridge (Reference Beveridge1959)). For simplicity, we refer to $\varepsilon$ as the consumer’s love of novelty for all $\varepsilon \gt 0.$ Footnote 12

The infinitely lived consumer solves the static optimization in (1); as is well known, we have the demand functions:

(6) \begin{equation} x(j,t)=\varepsilon (j,t)^{\sigma -1}\frac{E(t)p(j,t)^{-\sigma }}{P(t)^{1-\sigma }}\text{,} \end{equation}

where the consumer’s spending on differentiated goods is

(7) \begin{equation} E(t)\equiv \int _{j\in A(t)\cup N(t)}p(j,t)x(j,t)dj, \end{equation}

$P(t)$ is the usual price index, defined as

(8) \begin{equation} P(t)\equiv \left ( \int _{j\in A(t)\cup N(t)}(p(j,t)/\varepsilon (j,t))^{1-\sigma }dj\right ) ^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }}, \end{equation}

and $p(j,t)$ is the price of good $j$ in period $t$ . By solving the dynamic optimization, we also obtain the Euler equation:Footnote 13

(9) \begin{equation} \frac{E(t+1)}{E(t)}=\beta (1+r(t))\text{,} \end{equation}

where $r(t)$ denotes the interest rate.

3.2 Production

A continuum of firms produces consumption goods $j\in A(t)\cup N(t)$ . Each good $j,$ a new or old good, is dominated by a monopolistic producer. We consider a one-for-one technology in goods production. Namely, any producer, $j\in A(t)$ or $N(t),$ hires $x(j,t)$ units of labor to produce $x(j,t)$ units of good $j$ , and monopolistically sells them to the consumer. The marginal cost is, therefore, equal to the wage rate, $w(t).$

As shown in (6), the consumption good producers, $j\in A(t)\cup N(t),$ face a constant price elasticity of market demand, equal to $\sigma \geq 1.$ The unconstrained mark-up for a monopolistic producer is $\sigma/(\sigma -1)\gt 1.$ Thus, the mark-up goes to infinity in a Cobb–Douglas case of $\sigma =1.$ Nevertheless, to observe the role of substitutability between goods, captured by $\sigma$ , we allow for the case of $\sigma =1,$ Footnote 14 by introducing an upper bound of the mark-up, say, $\mu \gt 1$ . This upper bound $\mu$ has often been referred to as a patent breadth.Footnote 15 Following the literature, we assume $\mu \leq \sigma/(\sigma -1).$ Footnote 16 Notably, this introduction of a mark-up upper bound, $\mu,$ is only for clarifying what occurs in the Cobb–Douglas case ( $\sigma =1$ ). Therefore, the main results do not alter qualitatively at all without the upper bound $\mu .$

Accordingly, each firm sets a monopolistic price at:

(10) \begin{equation} p(j,t)=\mu w(t) \end{equation}

for all $j.$ Using (4), (6), and (10), the output and monopolistic profit for a new good are given by

(11) \begin{equation} x(j,t)=\frac{\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}E(t)}{P(t)^{1-\sigma }}\left ( \mu w(t)\right ) ^{-\sigma }\equiv x^{n}(t)\ \text{for }j\in N(t) \end{equation}

and

(12) \begin{equation} \pi (j,t)=\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}\frac{\mu -1}{\mu ^{\sigma }}E(t)\left ( \frac{w(t)}{P(t)}\right ) ^{1-\sigma }\equiv \pi ^{n}(t)\ \text{for }j\in N(t). \end{equation}

Equation (12) shows that when $\sigma \gt 1$ , the profit for a new good, $\pi ^{n}(t),$ increases with the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ and the total expenditure, $E(t)$ , and decreases with the real wage, $w(t)/P(t)$ . When $\sigma =1$ (the Cobb–Douglas case with no substitutability between goods), it becomes independent of the love of novelty $\varepsilon,$ and the real wage, $w(t)/P(t)$ .

We can also derive the output and monopolistic profit for an old good, from (4), (6), and (10):

(13) \begin{equation} x(j,t)=\frac{E(t)}{P(t)^{1-\sigma }}\left ( \mu w(t)\right ) ^{-\sigma }\equiv x^{a}(t)\ \text{for }j\in A(t) \end{equation}

and

(14) \begin{equation} \pi (j,t)=\frac{\mu -1}{\mu ^{\sigma }}E(t)\left ( \frac{w(t)}{P(t)}\right ) ^{1-\sigma }\equiv \pi ^{a}(t)\ \text{for }j\in A(t). \end{equation}

The profit $\pi ^{a}(t)$ associated with an old good is always free from the love of novelty $\varepsilon .$

3.3 Innovation

In this section, we present two types of innovation. One is to invent new goods, and the other is to ensure that invented goods have a long life in the market; we label these two types of innovation new product development and existing product development, respectively. First, R&D firms invent new consumption goods. We suppose new goods will become obsolete without further investments. Firms would further invest in existing product development. If investments succeed, new goods would be transformed and developed into new “old” goods.Footnote 17

3.3.1 New product development

There is a potentially infinite number of R&D firms. A firm can invent a new good in period $t$ by making an investment of $1/A(t-1)$ units of labor in period $t-1$ . We follow Romer (Reference Romer1990) to consider “external effects arising from knowledge spillovers” of the stock of existing technologies, represented by $A(t-1)$ . There is no spillover from newly invented goods as they are so new that their information would not be diffused appropriately. Nevertheless, even if we allow for new goods in the stock of existing technologies, the main results will not change qualitatively. Firms that invent new goods earn a monopolistic profit in period $t,$ $\pi ^{n}(t).$

As aforementioned, in the baseline model, we assume that the monopolistic firm can enjoy only a temporary (one-period) monopoly, following Matsuyama (Reference Matsuyama1999, Reference Matsuyama2001). The free entry condition for new product development can be written as:

(15) \begin{equation} W^{n}(t-1)\equiv \frac{\pi ^{n}(t)}{1+r(t-1)}-\frac{w(t-1)}{A(t-1)}\leq 0\ \text{for }t\geq 1, \end{equation}

where $W^{n}(t-1)$ denotes the discounted present value of inventing a new good. $R^{N}(t-1)$ denotes the units of labor devoted to new product development in period $t-1.$ Then, we have

(16) \begin{equation} N(t)=A(t-1)R^{N}(t-1). \end{equation}

3.3.2 Existing product development

Owing to the one-period nature of monopoly power, the new goods, $N(t),$ invented in period $t$ can potentially be manufactured by any firm in the subsequent period, $t+1.$ At this point, the goods are no longer new but “old.” We assume that each new good becomes obsolete before becoming an old good unless additional investments are made and succeed; however, one can utilize new goods as seeds and develop them into new “old goods.” We refer to this type of activity for developing old goods as existing product development.

As a first step, an R&D firm engaging in existing product development invests one unit of labor in period $t$ and searches through the set of new goods, $N(t)$ . From among $N(t),$ the firm meets only a fraction, $\phi \in (0,1)$ , of the new goods as seeds for old goods. The new goods each firm meets are randomly chosen from $N(t)$ . The firm then makes $\chi (t)$ units of old products from the new goods of $\phi N(t)$ by coming up with different combinations of those new goods. It is worth mentioning that the number of differentiated old goods that can potentially emerge from $N(t)$ is not bounded. This is because the number of possible combinations of $\phi N(t)$ new goods is not bounded due to continuity.

After existing product development, the firm enjoys a one-period monopoly for those $\chi (t)$ old goods to earn the profits of $\chi (t)\pi ^{a}(t+1)$ . The free entry condition for existing product development can be given as

(17) \begin{equation} W^{a}(t)\equiv \frac{\chi (t)\pi ^{a}(t+1)}{1+r(t)}-w(t)\leq 0\ \text{for }t\geq 0, \end{equation}

in which $W^{a}(t)$ denotes the discounted present value for existing product development. Concerning $\chi (t)$ , we consider a simple technology, $\chi (t)\equiv \lambda (\phi N(t))$ , where $\lambda \gt 0$ is a productivity parameter.Footnote 18 For descriptive purposes, we define a composite parameter, $\kappa \equiv \lambda \phi \gt 0$ . Then we have $\chi (t) = \kappa N(t)$ .

Through this process, the new goods of $N(t)$ are partially converted into the old goods, whose number is expressed as $A(t+1)-A(t)$ . Denote $R^{A}(t)$ as the units of labor devoted to existing product development in period $t.$ Further we obtain

(18) \begin{equation} A(t+1)-A(t)=\chi (t)R^{A}(t). \end{equation}

For simplicity, we assume that none of the old goods becomes obsolete. However, it is easy to allow for some depreciation for $A(t)$ without rendering any essential change to the result. For descriptive purposes, we define $\rho (t)$ as a macroeconomic rate of existing product development at which old goods are made from new goods:

(19) \begin{equation} \rho (t+1)\equiv \chi (t)R^{A}(t)/N(t). \end{equation}

In the subsequent period, $t+2,$ owing to the temporary monopoly again, the new “old” goods, $A(t+1)-A(t),$ could potentially be produced by any firm. We follow Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Aghion, Bursztyn and Hemous2012) by assuming that monopoly rights will be allocated randomly to a firm from the pool of potential firms whose ownership belongs to the representative agent. Thus, the monopoly profits for these “new” old goods will be transferred to new monopolistic firms owned by the representative agent.Footnote 19 Consequently, in our model, all goods are monopolistically competitively produced in equilibrium, and their profits are allocated to the representative agent as dividends.

Alternatively, we could also adopt another standard setting that old goods are sold at a perfectly competitive price (e.g., Matsuyama (Reference Matsuyama1999, Reference Matsuyama2001)). However, we understand that this option would complicate the analysis without changing the results qualitatively. In addition, while the interaction between monopolistic and competitive sectors is known as a source of perpetual cycles in the literature, our analysis shows that without this source, cycles can persist on an equilibrium path owing to a novel mechanism depending on the strength of consumer love of novelty. Therefore, in this study, we ensure that the analysis is as simple as possible to highlight the insight derived from our new framework.

3.4 Labor market

As shown in (12) and (14), the real wage $w(t)/P(t)$ is a critical component of the profits. Thus, having the following is beneficial:

(20) \begin{equation} \frac{w(t)}{P(t)}=\frac{1}{\mu }\left [ A(t)+\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}N(t)\right ] ^{\frac{1}{\sigma -1}}, \end{equation}

which uses $p(j,t)=\mu w(t)$ for any $j\in A(t)\cup N(t)$ with (8). The labor market clearing condition is

(21) \begin{equation} L=\int _{j\in A(t)\cup N(t)}x(j,t)dj+R^{N}(t)+R^{A}(t). \end{equation}

The left side in (21) denotes the labor supply, and the right side denotes the labor demand for production, new product development $R^{N}(t)$ , and existing product development $R^{A}(t)$ in each period $t.$ It is useful to derive the labor demand from the production sector as

(22) \begin{equation} \int _{j\in A(t)\cup N(t)}x(j,t)dj=\frac{1}{\mu }\frac{E(t)}{w(t)}, \end{equation}

which uses (11), (13), (20), and (21).

4. Equilibrium dynamics

In order to derive the dynamical system that characterizes the law of motion for the equilibrium trajectory of the economy, it is beneficial to define $n(t)\equiv N(t)/A(t),$ which is the ratio of new to old goods. By using the free entry conditions in (15) and (17), along with (12) and (14), we derive the following lemma.

Lemma 1. Only new product development occurs in equilibrium when $n(t)\lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa .$ Only existing product development occurs when $n(t)\gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa .$

Proof. Suppose that firms invest in new product development in equilibrium. Then, the free entry condition (15) must hold with equality (giving firms a zero net payoff). With (12), (14), (17), and (20), this equality implies $n(t)\leq \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa .$ Where $n(t)\lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa,$ that is, (17) holds with inequality, there is no investment in existing product development in equilibrium. Using this information, we can easily prove the first half of the lemma. An analogous proof can be applied to the second half.

Figure 2 presents the result of Lemma 1. The cutoff level of $n(t),$ $\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa,$ generates two regimes in the economy. The first regime corresponds to $n(t)\in (0,\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa ),$ which we refer to as a new product development regime. The second regime corresponds to $n(t)\in (\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa,\infty ),$ which we refer to as an existing product development regime. At the cutoff point, the economy includes both activities; however, we can ignore it because the point has zero measure.

Figure 2. Illustration of Lemma 1.

As shown in Lemma 1, a type of specialization occurs in this model. In reality, any economy appears to be engaged in both new and existing product development, more or less, at any point in time. We can easily eliminate this unrealistic aspect concerning specialization from the model by allowing the innovator a long-lived monopoly or simply introducing an exogenous growth factor. Either change to the baseline model could provide another interesting analysis, but the tractability of our model would cease to exist.Footnote 20 Thus, we adopt the present setting for simplicity.

In each period, $t$ , the value of $n(t)$ should be given, because it is a predetermined (stock) variable. In a hypothetical situation in which $n(t)$ is taken as given, Lemma 1 implies that, for a given $n(t),$ an economy is more likely to engage in new product development if (and only if) the love of novelty, $\varepsilon,$ is stronger and/or the productivity for existing product development, $\kappa,$ is lower. This is because there is a higher relative profit for the invention of a new good, compared to the investment in existing product development, when the consumer prefers new goods to old goods more strongly (owing to larger $\varepsilon$ ) and/or the cost for investments in existing product development is higher (owing to lower $\kappa$ ). The development of technologies that earn a higher profit is encouraged in market equilibrium. For the analogous reason, an economy is more likely to engage in existing product development when $\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ is smaller, in which case there is a higher relative profit for investments in existing product development.

4.1 New product development regime

With $n(t)\lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa,$ by Lemma 1, the economy falls into the new product development regime. With (9), (15), (12), and (20), the free entry condition for invention, $W^{n}(t)=0,$ becomes:

(23) \begin{equation} N(t+1)=\frac{A(t)}{\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}}\left [ \frac{\beta \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}}{\mu/(\mu -1)}\frac{E(t)}{w(t)}-1\right ], \end{equation}

which uses $A(t+1)=A(t)$ (or $\rho (t+1)=0$ ). Given $A(t),$ this describes a profit-motive aspect of the inventive activity: the larger the discounted profit from selling new goods ( $(\beta \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}(\mu -1)/\mu )E(t)/w(t)$ ), the greater the incentives for firms to invent a new good. The profit for a new good increases as the wage-adjusted expenditure $E(t)/w(t)$ increases and as the consumer’s love of novelty $\varepsilon$ increases. Additionally, when $n(t)\lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa,$ no firm has an incentive to invest in existing product development; in such a case, $R^{A}(t)=0.$ The labor market condition (21), therefore, becomes:

(24) \begin{equation} N(t+1)=A(t)\left [ L-\frac{1}{\mu }\frac{E(t)}{w(t)}\right ], \end{equation}

which uses (16) and (22). Given $A(t)$ , the greater the wage-adjusted expenditure $E(t)/w(t),$ the more resources will be devoted to production, leaving fewer resources for innovation, resulting in a smaller $N(t+1)$ .

Figure 3 depicts (23) and (24) and is labeled with $FE$ and $LE$ , respectively, which determine the equilibrium number of new goods, $N(t+1),$ and the wage-adjusted expenditure, $E(t)/w(t)$ , as a unique intersection. Given the predetermined variable, $A(t),$ new goods, $N(t+1),$ are increasing in the time preference rate $\beta,$ the labor force $L,$ and the patent breadth $\mu$ , all of which are natural effects.

Figure 3. New product development regime.

The effect of the elasticity of substitution between goods, $\sigma \geq 1,$ is more complex, and it becomes positive if the consumer has a love of novelty, that is, if $\varepsilon \gt 1.$ Because $\sigma$ determines the level of goods substitutability, a higher $\sigma$ generally results in a larger demand for a preferable good (relative to a less preferred good). Thus, with the consumer’s love of novelty ( $\varepsilon \gt 1$ ), the elasticity of substitution $\sigma$ positively affects $N(t+1)$ through an upward shift of the $FE$ curve in Figure 3, by increasing the expenditure share for a new good and thereby its profit. However, in the benchmark case of $\varepsilon =1,$ comprising neither a love or fear of novelty, the elasticity of substitution $\sigma$ has no role because all new and old goods are equally desirable for the consumer; thus, their demands/profits are also equal. When the consumer has a fear of novelty, that is, $\varepsilon \lt 1,$ the effect of $\sigma$ on $N(t+1)$ is negative because old goods are now preferable. Again, a higher substitutability $\sigma$ leads to a larger demand for a preferable good, generally. Therefore, in this fear-of-novelty case, higher $\sigma$ generates a downward shift of the $FE$ curve, by decreasing the profits for new goods (and increasing the profits for old goods).

Regarding the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ , a higher $\varepsilon$ causes an upward shift in the $FE$ curve in the standard case of $\sigma \gt 1,$ where goods are substitutes. This result is simply because the demand for a new good becomes larger if the consumer prefers new goods to old goods more strongly (higher $\varepsilon$ ). Further, the equilibrium profit for new goods, $(\beta \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}(\mu -1)/\mu )E(t)/w(t),$ is also larger.Footnote 21 The upward shift of the $FE$ curve results in an increase in $N(t+1)$ in equilibrium. In the special case of $\sigma =1$ (where goods are independent goods), the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ has no role because the expenditure share for any independent good, new or old, is constant, and free from $\varepsilon .$

We can formally confirm this effect of $\varepsilon$ by solving (23) and (24):

(25) \begin{equation} N(t+1)=\Theta A(t), \end{equation}

where

(26) \begin{equation} \Theta \equiv \frac{\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}(\mu -1)L-1/\beta }{\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}\left ( \left ( \mu -1\right ) +1/\beta \right ) }. \end{equation}

Equation (25) determines the equilibrium amount of new goods in the new product development regime. The coefficient $\Theta$ is increasing in the love of novelty $\varepsilon $ and the standard parameters $\beta,$ $L,$ and $\mu .$ We can interpret the parameter composite $\Theta$ as the potential demand for new goods. Assuming $\Theta \gt 0,$ we exclude a trivial case where there is no invention of new goods in any situation, by imposing $\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}\beta (\mu -1)L\gt 1,$ which provides a lower bound of $\varepsilon$ as $[1/(\beta (\mu -1)L)]^{1/(\sigma -1)}\equiv \varepsilon _{0}$ . Additionally, because $R^{A}(t)=0$ and then $\rho (t+1)=0$ in the present regime, from (18), the old goods do not increase; $A(t+1)=A(t).$ Therefore, we easily verify that if $\Theta \gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ holds, then $N(t+1)/A(t+1)\equiv n(t+1)\gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ holds, whereby the economy moves to the existing product development regime in period $t+1.$ Conversely, if $\Theta \lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa,$ $n(t+1)\lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa .$ Then, the economy is trapped in the new product development regime. In this situation, $N(t)$ and $A(t)$ are constant over time, resulting in less innovation in the sense that there is only one type of innovation—new product development, $N(t).$ Consequently, there is no long-run growth because the variety of goods, $N(t)+A(t),$ is constant over time.

Lemma 2. The economy is trapped in the new product development regime if and only if $\Theta \lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa .$

4.2 Existing product development regime

With $n(t)\gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa,$ by Lemma 1, the economy is in the existing product development regime in period $t;$ $R^{A}(t)\geq 0,$ and $R^{N}(t)=0.$ Rearranging the labor market condition (21), with (22), yields the rate of existing product development for new goods as

(27) \begin{equation} \rho (t+1)=\kappa R^{A}(t)=\kappa \left ( L-\frac{1}{\mu }\frac{E(t)}{w(t)}\right ). \end{equation}

Analogous to (24), (27) captures the trade-off on resources between the production of goods and the investment in existing product development. With (9), (14), and (17), the free entry condition $W^{a}(t)=0$ becomes

(28) \begin{equation} \rho (t+1)=\frac{\kappa \beta }{\mu/(\mu -1)}\frac{E(t)}{w(t)}-\frac{A(t)}{N(t)}, \end{equation}

which uses $N(t+1)=R^{N}(t)=0$ from (16) and $A(t+1)=A(t)+\chi (t)R^{A}(t)=A(t)+\chi (t)\rho (t+1)/\kappa$ from (18). Naturally, the rate of existing product development $\rho (t+1)$ increases with the discounted profit from producing the old good $(\beta (\mu -1)/\mu )E(t)/w(t)$ and also increases with the number of new goods $N(t)$ because R&D firms can find more inventions (i.e., opportunities for improvement). Figure 4 illustrates how $\rho (t+1)$ is determined by (27) and (28). Solving (27) and (28), we obtain:Footnote 22

(29) \begin{equation} \rho (t+1)= \frac{1}{1+\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }\left ( \kappa \beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) L-\frac{A(t)}{N(t)}\right ). \end{equation}

Using (29), with (18), the growth of old goods is as follows:

Figure 4. Existing product development regime.

(30) \begin{equation} A(t+1)=\frac{\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }{1+\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }\left ( 1+\kappa L\frac{N(t)}{A(t)}\right ) A(t). \end{equation}

Lemma 3. The existing product development regime is always unstable; thus, the economy necessarily shifts to the new product development regime.

5. Role of love of novelty in innovation and long-run growth

In this section, we examine the effects of consumers’ love of novelty on innovation and growth in the long run. We follow the standard literature to assume $\sigma \gt 1$ .Footnote 23 Lemma 2 shows that in the case with $\Theta \lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa,$ the economy is fatally caught in the trap without existing product development, in which no long-run growth is possible because new goods $N(t)\ $ and old goods $A(t)$ are constant. In such a trapped economy, the inventive potential $\Theta$ is relatively low, and the consumer’s love of novelty, $\varepsilon,$ is relatively strong. On the one hand, the new product development regime is larger owing to a high $\varepsilon$ . On the other hand, the invention flow $N(t)$ within the regime tends to be low, owing to a low $\Theta .$ These two effects are negative on innovation; therefore, the economy with $\Theta \lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ is trapped. To avoid traps, $\Theta \gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ must hold as shown in Lemma 3. As is common in the standard R&D-based growth model, traps can be avoided only if labor is sufficiently abundant.Footnote 24 Specifically, we assume the following condition:

(31) \begin{equation} L\gt 2\sqrt{\frac{1}{\kappa }\left ( 1+\frac{1}{\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }\right ) \frac{1}{\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }}\equiv L_{0}. \end{equation}

Lemma 4. Under ( 31 ), there exist threshold values $\varepsilon _{+} \gt \varepsilon _{- } \gt \varepsilon _{0}$ for which

\begin{align*} \Theta \gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma - 1}/ \kappa \ \Longleftrightarrow \ \varepsilon \in (\varepsilon _{-}, \varepsilon _{+}). \end{align*}

Proof. From (26), we can show that $\Theta \gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ if and only if

(32) \begin{equation} F\left(\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}\right)\equiv \frac{1}{\kappa }\left ( 1+\frac{1}{\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }\right ) \left ( \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}\right ) ^{2}-L\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}+\frac{1}{\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }\lt 0. \end{equation}

Because $F$ is quadratic and convex in $\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}$ , (32) is possible only when $F(x)=0$ has two distinct real roots. The positiveness of the discriminant ensures this,

(33) \begin{equation} D\equiv L^{2}-\frac{4}{\kappa }\left ( 1+\frac{1}{\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }\right ) \frac{1}{\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }\gt 0, \end{equation}

which is equivalent to (31). Suppose that (31) holds and let the solutions to $F(x)=0$ be $\varepsilon _{-}^{\sigma -1}\lt \varepsilon _{+}^{\sigma -1}$ .Footnote 25 As is easily verified, $\varepsilon _{+}^{\sigma -1}\gt 0$ holds. Because $F(0)\gt 0$ , $\varepsilon _{-}^{\sigma -1}\gt 0$ also holds. To prove that $\varepsilon _{0}^{\sigma -1}=1/(\beta (\mu -1)L)\lt \varepsilon _{-}^{\sigma -1}$ , it suffices to show that $F\left(\varepsilon _{0}^{\sigma -1}\right)\gt 0$ and $F^{\prime }\left(\varepsilon _{0}^{\sigma -1}\right)\lt 0$ . In fact,

\begin{align*} F\left(\varepsilon _{0}^{\sigma -1}\right) & =\frac{1}{\kappa }\left ( 1+\frac{1}{\beta (\mu -1)}\right ) \left ( \varepsilon _{0}^{\sigma -1}\right ) ^{2}\gt 0,\\ F^{\prime }\left(\varepsilon _{0}^{\sigma -1}\right) & =\frac{2}{\kappa }\left ( 1+\frac{1}{\beta \left ( \mu -1\right ) }\right ) \frac{1}{\beta L\left ( \mu -1\right ) }-L=\frac{1}{2L}(L_{0}^{2}-L^{2})\lt 0. \end{align*}

Because the solution set to $F(x)\lt 0$ is $(\varepsilon _{-}^{\sigma -1},\varepsilon _{+}^{\sigma -1})$ , with $\varepsilon _{0}\lt \varepsilon _{-}$ , any $\varepsilon \in (\varepsilon _{-},\varepsilon _{+})$ satisfies both $\varepsilon \gt \varepsilon _{0}$ and the no-trap condition. Conversely, any $\varepsilon \gt \varepsilon _{0}$ outside of this interval violates the no-trap condition.

Condition (31) is indispensable for our analysis. Notably, there exists an $\varepsilon \gt \varepsilon _{0}$ that satisfies the no-trap condition, $\Theta \gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ , if and only if (31) holds.Footnote 26 Thus, in the following analysis, we assume (31) to avoid the trivial case of any economies trapped in the no-innovation situation.

Lemma 4 characterizes the parameter range in which the economy has the potential to innovate and grow in the long run. Lemma 4 also states that the role of love of novelty $\varepsilon$ in achieving $\Theta \gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ is ambiguous because $\Theta$ is increasing in $\varepsilon,$ which generates two opposite effects of $\varepsilon .$ On the one hand, (a) a higher $\varepsilon$ makes the invention of new goods profitable relative to the investment in existing product development. As a result of this relative profitability effect, the new product development regime $(0,\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa )$ will become large, whereby the economy is more likely to become trapped in the new product development regime. However, (b) a higher $\varepsilon$ also results in a larger potential demand $\Theta$ , and there are more new goods $N(t)$ to be created in the new product development regime. This leaves more incentives for firms to engage in existing product development, noting that new goods are the essential source of existing product development. With this positive indirect effect of $\varepsilon$ , the economy is more likely to jump out of the new product development region. These two opposite effects interact to create an equilibrium role for $\varepsilon .$ The following two propositions show that the role of the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ in innovation is also ambiguous.

Proposition 1. When the infinitely lived consumer’s love of novelty $\varepsilon$ is moderate, such that $\varepsilon \in (\varepsilon _{-},\varepsilon _{+}),$ the economy achieves long-run growth, through perpetual cycles between periods of new product development and existing product development.

Proof. For $\varepsilon \in (\varepsilon _{-},\varepsilon _{+}),$ because of Lemmas 2 and 4, $\Theta \gt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ holds and the new product development regime is always explosive. Thus, any path starting from initial values lower than $\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ eventually moves toward the existing product development regime. Furthermore, because of Lemma 3, the economy will necessarily go back to some point within the new product development regime. Therefore, if $\varepsilon$ is moderate, the economy perpetually fluctuates, moving back and forth between the two regimes. In this case, innovation occurs perpetually and cyclically because both $N_{t}$ and $A_{t}$ permanently grow over time, but alternately.

Proposition 1 suggests that the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ can be a source of innovation-driven growth in the long run, because there are permanently expanding goods spaces, $N(t)$ and $A(t)$ . Innovation-driven growth occurs here because the aforementioned two opposite effects of $\varepsilon$ can be balanced well in a moderate range of $\varepsilon .$ However, if the level is extreme, the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ can be a cause of underdevelopment traps rather than the source of growth, by depressing innovation.

Proposition 2. When the infinitely lived consumer’s love of novelty $\varepsilon$ is sufficiently weak or strong, such that $\varepsilon \notin (\varepsilon _{-},\varepsilon _{+}),$ a globally stable equilibrium trap occurs in which new products are invented, but none can survive in the market, owing to the absence of existing product development. The economy fails to achieve long-run growth.

Proof. For $\varepsilon \notin (\varepsilon _{-},\varepsilon _{+}),$ because of Lemmas 2 and 4, $\Theta \leq \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ holds and the new product development regime is a trap. Because of Lemma 3, the existing product development regime is always explosive, and any path starting from any point in either regime is eventually trapped in the new product development regime.

Proposition 2 implies that the “fear of novelty” (Beveridge (Reference Beveridge1959), Barber (Reference Barber1961)) and “love of novelty” may both cause an economy to fall into an underdevelopment trap. It is straightforward to understand that the consumer’s fear of novelty negatively affects innovation. Intuitively, with a smaller $\varepsilon,$ the consumer has a smaller demand for new products $N(t)$ , implying smaller $N(t).$ Because new goods are the input for existing product development, a smaller $N(t)$ discourages existing product development by lowering its net benefit, which results from the aforementioned effect (b). Consequently, with a strong fear of novelty, or a very low $\varepsilon,$ the economy is more likely to be caught in the trap, in which investments in new product development occur and investments in existing product development do not occur. Because both types of innovative investments are essential, the numbers of new goods and old goods, $N(t)$ and $A(t),$ are constant over time. Thus, a very weak of love of novelty, or a strong fear of novelty, can cause the underdevelopment trap of no long-run growth. This result is consistent with the historical view in Mokyr (Reference Mokyr2000), who considers that the lack of “receptivity of a society to new technological ideas” is “an integral part of underdevelopment.” The innate fear of novelty for consumers should be an important source of the absence of receptivity.

Significantly, Proposition 2 also identifies the negative role of a too strong love of novelty. This role may seem counter-intuitive, but the mechanism is natural. Owing to effect (b), a high $\varepsilon$ encourages new product development, providing more new goods $N(t).$ It further encourages existing product development because existing product development uses new goods as input. However, owing to effect (a), $\varepsilon$ increases the relative profitability of new product development to existing product development. When $\varepsilon$ is very high, this relative profitability effect dominates the positive one to take away/remove any incentives from firms for existing product development. In this case, only new product development occurs in equilibrium. The economy is trapped again, in which $N(t)$ and $A(t)$ are constant over time. Thus, no long-run growth is observed in an economy with a too strong love of novelty.

Those two propositions identify the ambiguous role of the consumer’s love of novelty in innovation and innovation-based growth. The following theorem provides a summary:

Theorem 1. When the love of novelty is moderate, it is the fundamental source of innovation-based economic growth in the long run. However, a too strong love of novelty and a too weak love of novelty causes an underdevelopment trap, in which new goods are invented (owing to the presence of new product development) but not developed into old goods (owing to the absence of existing product development). In the trapped situation, the total number of goods, $N(t)+A(t),$ is constant over time; there is no long-run growth.

Proof. Proven in the text by using Propositions 1 and 2.

In Theorem 1, we identify an ambiguous role of the public’s love of novelty in innovation and innovation-based economic growth. Intuitively, the love of novelty encourages the invention of new goods, but each innovation also involves investments for existing product development. Thus, innovation at the aggregate level can be maximized with a good balance between new and existing product development. This is why the role of love of novelty is ambiguous; a too weak and a too strong love of novelty depresses innovation, whereby the economy can be caught in underdevelopment traps with no long-run growth. We conclude that the love of novelty is a source of innovation-based growth but can become a cause of underdevelopment traps when it is too strong.

It is worth repeating that the key assumption generating the ambiguous role of love of novelty is the structure of an innovation market: innovation covers various activities including the creation of new goods but also the development of existing (relatively old) goods. Too strong love for new goods, as well as the same for old goods, can be harmful for innovation-driven growth because long-run innovation essentially depends on a good balance between two separate but sequential innovation activities, new and existing good development.

In summary, the theoretical analysis in this section suggests that, empirically, we should expect an inverted-U relationship between love of novelty and innovations. Besides, assuming new product development generates more original innovations than existing product development, we should also expect a positive relationship between love of novelty and original innovations. The scatter plots in Figure 1 are consistent with these predictions. Additional regression results are shown in the Appendix.

6. Quantitative analysis

In this section, we calibrate the model to aggregate US data to perform quantitative exercises. We aim to quantify the love of novelty and then simulate the transition dynamics of the economy switching between the two innovation processes, which also gives an idea concerning values of the upper/lower bounds of love of novelty, $\varepsilon .$ In calibrating the model, we normalize the labor size $L$ to be unity as is standard in the endogenous growth literature.

Now, the model features the following parameters: $\left \{ \beta,\sigma,\kappa,\mu,\varepsilon \right \}$ . We set the discount rate $\beta$ to $0.95,$ which falls in the range of conventional values.Footnote 27 Then, we consider a range of values for the markup ratio $\mu \in \left \{ 1.1,1.2,1.3,\sigma/(\sigma -1) \right \}$ , which roughly cover the empirically plausible range, $1.05-1.4$ , of markups suggested in Jones and Williams (Reference Jones and Williams2000). Note that $\sigma/(\sigma -1)$ gives a theoretical upper bound of $\mu$ . Further, we set the elasticity of substitution between differentiated goods $\sigma$ to $4$ , which is the mean of estimates of substitution elasticity at the three-digit level in Broda and Weinstein (Reference Broda and Weinstein2006). Accordingly, the upper bound of $\mu$ becomes $ \sigma/(\sigma -1) = 1.33\cdots$ , which is also within the empirically plausible range. Since this value of $\sigma =4$ is calculated using data during the period from 1990 to 2001, for the rest of the parameters $\left \{ \kappa, \varepsilon \right \},$ we calibrate the model using an average of aggregate data during the same period. For each value of $\mu$ , we calibrate the values of R&D productivity $\kappa$ and love of novelty $\varepsilon$ targeting a GDP growth rate of $3.09\%$ and an R&D share in GDP of $2.54\%$ .Footnote 28 We report the calibrated parameter values in Table 1.

Table 1. Calibrated parameters

Under these calibrated parameter values, for all values of markup $\mu$ , the calibrated love-of-novelty parameter, $\varepsilon,$ is larger than unity, that is, a love of novelty, not a fear of novelty. Note, however, that for the lowest markup $\mu = 1.1$ , the growth condition, $\varepsilon \in (\varepsilon _-, \varepsilon _+)$ , does not hold because (31) is violated. This indicates that the economy with lower markups tends to be trapped in underdevelopment, consistent with the usual intuition. Thus, depending on the markup, our quantitative exercise may suggest the U.S. economy in the 1990s had a love of novelty.

We also demonstrate the transitional dynamics of the economy switching between the two innovation processes, that is, new and existing product development. Figure 5 illustrates an equilibrium path of (the logarithm of) the total output (in real terms), that is, $Y^i (t) \equiv E(t)/P(t)+w (t) R^{i}(t)/ P(t) \ $ with $i=\left \{ N,A\right \} .$ Without any loss of generality, we may suppose that the initial period, $t=0,$ is a period where new product development occurs and normalize $A(0)$ to be $1$ .Footnote 29

Figure 5. The dynamics of total output.

Figure 5 (a) illustrates four equilibrium paths of the total output, $Y^i (t)$ , with different levels of the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ . As shown in the figure, with either level of $\varepsilon$ , the total output fluctuates along an equilibrium path, and the growth rate trend is higher with higher $\varepsilon$ . It also suggests that the growth path becomes first less volatile and then more volatile as the love $\varepsilon$ of novelty becomes stronger, implying a nonmonotonic effect of $\varepsilon$ on volatility.

To formally identify the relationship between the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ and growth volatility, in the lower half of Figure 5(b), we illustrate the relationship between $\varepsilon$ and the three growth rates: one in the new product development (NPD) regime (the blue line, labeled as “NPD”), another in the existing product development (EPD) regime (the orange line, labeled as “EPD”), and an arithmetic mean of these two (the green line, labeled as (NPD + EPD)/2).Footnote 30 As shown, as $\varepsilon$ increases, the growth rate with NPD increases; then, the growth rate with EPD first increases and then decreases, showing an inverted U-shaped relationship. Notably, these two growth rates are equated at two points, where the total output grows at a constant rate without any fluctuations (i.e., balanced growth). This further implies that the volatility is minimized at these two points; as shown in the upper half of Figure 5(b), a very strong love of novelty, $\varepsilon$ , causes higher volatility as well as higher trend growth. In summary, our numerical exercise indicates that (a) a stronger love of novelty increases the trend growth rate, but (b) a substantial increase from the benchmark level may tend to increase volatility.

To end up this section, we elaborate on an intuition behind the relationship between the love of novelty $\varepsilon$ and the growth rates. Potentially, there are four effects of a stronger love of novelty (i.e., higher $\varepsilon$ ) on growth. Higher $\varepsilon$ , at first, encourages NPD. The increased NPD investment results in two effects. On the one hand, (i) it leaves fewer labor resources for production in the NPD regime, decreasing $Y^N$ . On the other hand, (ii) it also brings about more new products in the EPD regime, which encourages production in the EPD regime and increases the output $Y^A$ . Since more new products also imply more “seeds” for EPD, (iii) it increases the EPD investment, which leaves fewer resources for production in the EPD regime and decreases $Y^A$ . Finally, (iv) the increased EPD investment leads the old goods $A(t)$ to grow faster from the EPD to NPD regime, and the NPD regime has more old goods, which encourages production in the NPD regime and increases $Y^N$ . Given that the growth rate in the NPD (EPD) regime is defined as $g^N \equiv Y^A/ Y^N -1$ ( $g^A \equiv Y^N/ Y^A -1$ ), effects (i) and (ii) affect $g^N (t)$ positively and $g^A (t)$ negatively; effects (iii) and (iv) do the opposite. Therefore, the total effects are potentially ambiguous. With our calibrated parameters, as shown in Figure 5(b), the positive effect on $g^N$ dominates; the opposite effects on $g^A$ interact with each other to create an inverted-U relationship between $\varepsilon$ and $g^A$ .

7. Concluding remarks

In this study, we explore the role of people’s love of novelty in innovation and innovation-based growth by developing a new innovation-based growth model. In the model, innovation is the combination of two types of innovations, new product development and existing product development; additionally, the infinitely-lived representative consumer has a particular preference for new products (compared with old products) in addition to the standard love-of-variety preferences. Using this model, we show that the consumer’s love of novelty can be a source of innovation and long-run growth when moderate. Further, we demonstrate a mechanism through which the love of novelty can cause underdevelopment traps that result in fewer innovations when its level is too weak or too strong. Therefore, we conclude that people’s love of novelty might have an ambiguous effect: too weak and too strong love for novelty can depress innovation and innovation-driven growth.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the Co-editor (Oded Galor), an anonymous referee, Kenzo Abe, Taro Akiyama, Tomohiro Ara, Martine Carré-Tallon, Nicola Coniglio, Mario Curucini, Erkan Gören, Gene Grossman, Makoto Hanazono, Tomoya Hanibuchi, Keisaku Higashida, Takeo Hori, Mitsuhide Hoshino, Kenta Ikeuchi, Jun-ichi Itaya, Arata Ito, Takashi Kamihigashi, Yoshimasa Komoriya, Keisuke Kondo, Sung-Ho Lee, Ryo Makioka, Junya Masuda, Kiyoshi Matsubara, Koyo Miyoshi, Akira Momota, Masayuki Morikawa, Hiroshi Mukunoki, Takumi Naito, Kenta Nakamura, Masao Oda, Ryoji Ohdoi, Yuka Ohno, Masayuki Okawa, Rui Ota, Pascalis Raimondos, Yoko Sakamoto, Yoichi Sugita, Takaji Suzuki, Yasuhiro Takarada, Yasuo Takatsuki, Yoshihiro Tomaru, Yoshiaki Usui, Annalisa Vinella, Akihiko Yanase, Makoto Yano, and the conference/seminar/meeting participants at Economic Theory and Policy Workshop, Fukushima Economics Workshop 2018, Chonnam National University, Copenhagen Business School, Dosisha University (Goshokita Seminar), 2015/2017 IEFS JapanAnnual Meeting, IESEG School of Management, JapanPatent Office, Paris-Dauphine University, RIETI (Discussion Paper Seminar), Sophia University, University of Bari, University of Porto, and Yokohama National University for their helpful comments and support. Yuichi Furukawa acknowledges the partial financial support from a Research Grant Program of the Toyota Foundation as well as JSPS Grant-in-Aids for Scientific Research (#18K01522, #22K01405, #16H03612, and #20H01492). Kenji Sato acknowledges the partial financial support from JSPS (a Grant-in-Aid for JSPS Research Fellow and Grant-in-Aids #16K03552 and #19K13650).

Appendix: Some suggestive country-level evidence between love of novelty and innovation

Our theoretical analysis suggests an inverted-U relationship between love of novelty and innovations and a positive relationship between love of novelty and original innovations. Figure 1 already shows some unconditional correlations between love of novelty and innovations. In this Appendix, we provide further details about the data sources and variables as well as some additional regression results.

Data and Variables. To measure the “Love of novelty” of the people of a country, we use data from Question E046 of the World Values Survey (WVS). This survey question asks respondents to score the statement, “Ideas stood test of time better vs New ideas better.” The score ranges from 1 (“Ideas that stood test of time are generally best”) to 10 (“New ideas are generally better than old ones”). To construct the country-level measure, we collapse the WVS sample with valid responses to E046 into country-level means.Footnote 31

We use patent data from the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) and population data from the World Bank to construct several measures of innovation, including Patent applications per million capita in log, Trademark applications per million capita in log, Industrial design applications per million capita in log, and Scientific and technical journal articles per million capita in log.Footnote 32 As an alternative measure of innovation, we also use the Global Innovation Index.Footnote 33

Our “Originality” variable measures a country’s “original” patents relative to the “benchmark” U.S. patent within the same patent class and granting year. Specifically, we use the NBER patent data from Hall et al. (Reference Hall, Jaffe and Trajtenberg2001) to construct this variable. The NBER patent database contains a measure of originality for each patent granted between 1973 and 1999, defined asFootnote 34

(A1) \begin{equation} 1-\sum _{j=1}^{J}\left ( \frac{\text{Citations made which belong to patent class $j$}}{\text{Total citations made}}\right ) ^{2}. \end{equation}

This measure takes a high value when a patent cites other patents that belong to a wide range of patent classes but a low value when only citing other patents that belong to a narrow range of patent classes. For each patent class and granting year, we identify the “benchmark” as the median value of the above measure in (A1) for U.S. patents. For each patent, we compute the difference between the patent’s originality measure in (A1) and the U.S. benchmark. Then our Originality index for a country is the average of this difference; when a country has a higher Originality index, then this country’s patents tend to be more original than the U.S. benchmarks.

Below we estimate several simple ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions with additional country-level controls, including log GDP per capita, log Population, intellectual property protection, years of tertiary schooling, net inflow of foreign direct investment as a percentage of GDP, and religiosity (share of religious people and share of people believing in God).Footnote 35 Data for GDP per capita are from the World Bank; data for the net inflow of foreign direct investment (FDI) as a percentage of GDP are from the World Development Index (WDI); the index of patent rights comes from Park (Reference Park2008); data for years of tertiary schooling are from Barro and Lee (Reference Barro and Lee2013). To construct the two measures of religiosity, we use the survey questions F034 and F050 of WVS. More specifically, F034 asks whether the respondent is a religious person (the survey question is: “Independently of whether you go to church or not, would you say you are $\ldots$ ” with possible answers 1 (“A religious person”), 2 (“Not a religious person”), and 3 (“A convinced atheist”).) F050 asks whether the respondent believes in god (the survey question is: “Which, if any, of the following do you believe in? $\ldots$ God” with possible answers 0 (“No”) and 1 (“Yes”).) Notably, the control variables are country-level means between 1990 and 2010 except that the two religiosity measures are means between 1981 and 2002. Table 2 reports the summary statistics of the various variables used.Footnote 36

Table 2. Summary statistics

Regression Results and Discussions. In addition to the scatter plots shown in Figure 1(a) to Figure 1(e), we also estimate a set of OLS regressions by including various country-level control variables. These results are reported in Tables 3 to 7, respectively. We find that the inverted-U relationship is significant (except when the Global Innovation Index is the outcome variable).

Table 3. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (1)

Note: The dependent variable is Patent applications per million capita in log. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. $^{*}$ : significance at 10% level; $^{**}$ : significance at 5% level; $^{***}$ : significance at 1% level.

Table 4. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (2)

Note: The dependent variable is Trademark applications per million capita in log. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. $^{*}$ : significance at 10% level; $^{**}$ : significance at 5% level; $^{***}$ : significance at 1% level.

Table 5. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (3)

Note: The dependent variable is Industrial design applications per million capita in log. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. $^{*}$ : significance at 10% level; $^{**}$ : significance at 5% level; $^{***}$ : significance at 1% level.

Table 6. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (4)

Note: The dependent variable is Scientific and technical journal articles per million capita in log. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. $^{*}$ : significance at 10% level; $^{**}$ : significance at 5% level; $^{***}$ : significance at 1% level.

Table 7. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (5)

Note: The dependent variable is Global Innovation Index. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. $^{*}$ : significance at 10% level; $^{**}$ : significance at 5% level; $^{***}$ : significance at 1% level.

Next, we examine the relationship between Love of novelty and Originality. Figure 1(f) shows a scatter plot of the country-level means of E046 of WVS against our Originality measure. The linear fitted line has a positive slope (but is statistically insignificant). In Table 8, we also estimate a set of OLS regressions. We find that, when other control variables are included (in Columns (2) to (4)), Love of novelty is positively and significantly related to Originality.

Table 8. The relationship between love of novelty and originality

Note: The dependent variable is Originality. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. $^{*}$ : significance at 10% level; $^{**}$ : significance at 5% level; $^{***}$ : significance at 1% level.

Overall, there seems to be an inverted-U relationship between Love of novelty and Innovation and a positive relationship between Love of novelty and Originality. All in all, the cross-country patterns seem to support the relevance of our theory.

Nevertheless, we are certainly aware of various limitations of the empirical analysis. For instance, one major concern is regarding the measurement of “love of novelty.” In the empirical analysis, we use data from the WVS to construct the country-level love of novelty index. We can argue that answers to such types of survey questions do not necessarily provide an accurate measure of the extent to which consumers love new products. One further question is whether these answers can be compared across countries; this comparison is especially relevant in our case because we cannot control for country-level differences through country fixed effects in our country-level regressions. An even more challenging concern is whether the relationships we observe are causal. Without a credible instrument that is correlated with people’s love of novelty but is not correlated with other factors that can potentially affect innovation activities, we cannot show that love of novelty causally affects innovation activities.

Although these empirical concerns are important, it is beyond the scope of this study to address them. Therefore, we emphasize that the empirical results reported in this Appendix should be interpreted as suggestive evidence in line with the predictions of the theoretical predictions of our model.

Footnotes

*

This study is conducted as part of a research project, Evidence-based Policy Study on the Law and Economics of Market Quality, undertaken by the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). An earlier version of this paper was part of RIETI Discussion Paper Series 18-E-073 under the title “Novelty-Seeking Traits and Innovation.”

1 See Section 2 for a literature review.

2 Details about the data sources and variables and additional regression results are in the Appendix. A recent study by Gören (Reference Gören2017) reports cross-country evidence for a significant inverted-U relationship between individual traits of seeking novelty and economic development. His empirical results suggest that novelty-seeking traits can be a source of growth and development provided that it is moderate, but it can have a negative effect if it is too strong or too weak. This is consistent with our theoretical findings. The key difference between Gören (Reference Gören2017) and our study is that Gören (Reference Gören2017) characterizes people’s novelty-seeking traits by genetic information whereas we consider love of novelty as an individual cultural preference. Certainly, the two views are related; see, for example, Ashraf and Galor (Reference Ashraf and Galor2013a, b) for evidence for the significant relationship between genetic diversity and cultural fragmentation.

3 An advantage of using this class of innovation-based growth models is that new and old products are clearly distinguished and have separate roles in the equilibrium, which facilitates the process of modeling love of novelty; see also below for more information on this class of growth models.

4 This categorization essentially follows the latest Oslo Manual (OECD/Eurostat (2018)), which proposes two general categories of innovation “by comparing both new and improved innovations to the firm’s existing products.”

5 In our model, an innovative economy is perpetually cyclical; however, we can show that it also stably converges to a unique balanced growth path by considering a natural extension of our model. See Furukawa et al. (Reference Furukawa, Lai and Sato2019) for the details.

6 In a broader context, as Yano (Reference Yano2009) asserts, the coordination of such cultural factors with laws and rules is indispensable to deriving high-quality markets and thereby healthy economic growth. This study extends this literature by investigating a composition effect of the public’s love of novelty and patent on innovation and long-run growth. See Dastidar and Yano (Reference Dastidar and Yano2021) and Yano and Furukawa (Reference Yano and Furukawa2023) for recent studies on market quality theory.

7 Doi and Mino (2008) also explore the role of consumption-side factors in innovation and innovation-based growth by focusing on habit formation and consumption externalities.

8 See also Chu and Cozzi (Reference Chu and Cozzi2011) for cultural preferences for fertility. A large body of empirical literature is also available: Tabellini (Reference Tabellini2010) shows that cultural propensities such as trust significantly affect regional per-capita income in Europe. Alesina and Giuliano (Reference Alesina and Giuliano2010) examine the effects of family ties on economic performance. See also Bénabou et al. (Reference Bénabou, Ticchi and Vindigni2022), who show that innovation can be negatively associated with people’s religiosity.

9 See, for instance, Iwaisako and Tanaka (Reference Iwaisako and Tanaka2017) for endogenous growth cycles in an overlapping generations model.

10 In this stream of literature, some models have physical capital accumulation (e.g., Matsuyama (Reference Matsuyama2001)). To make our analysis tractable, we abstract from this aspect because we focus on preferences for new products, innovation, and innovation-driven growth.

11 This follows Grossman and Helpman (Reference Grossman and Helpman1991, ch. 3). In our model, the variety of consumption goods endogenously increases over time, unlike in the original Romer model (in which the variety of intermediate goods increases). Therefore, in our model, patents are granted for consumption goods, but they are often for intermediate goods in reality. Nevertheless, we adopt the present setting because we are interested in modelling consumers’ love of novelty. Notably, however, we can obtain similar results even if we consider an expanding variety of intermediate goods.

12 In this study, we exclude any possibility of $\varepsilon \lt 0$ because this is a trivial case, in which the consumer obtains disutility from buying new products and chooses $x(j,t)=0$ for all $j\in N(t).$

13 Here we consider the standard lifetime budget constraint as follows: $E(t+1)+Q(t+1)=(1+r(t))Q(t)+w(t)L,$ where $Q(t)$ denotes the value of financial assets (i.e., equity of monopolistic firms) owned by the representative consumer.

14 When $\sigma =1,$ consumption goods are not substitutes but independent goods. Thus, if one needs to examine the role of goods substitutability, it is useful to think of the case without substitutability (i.e., the case of $\sigma =1).$

15 See, for example, Li (Reference Li2001), Goh and Olivier (Reference Goh and Olivier2002), Iwaisako and Futagami (Reference Iwaisako and Futagami2013), and Chu et al. (Reference Chu, Cozzi, Pan and Zhang2020, Reference Chu, Cozzi, Furukawa and Liao2022) for growth-theoretic analyses. The breadth of a patent here is identified with “the flow rate of profit available to the patentee” and often interpreted as “the ability of the patentee to raise price” (Gilbert and Shapiro (Reference Gilbert and Shapiro1990)). We can easily justify the existence of a price upper bound, or patent breadth, by considering potential imitators whose production cost increases with patent breadth, $\mu$. In a different context, $\mu$ can also be considered a result of price regulation (Evans et al. (Reference Evans, Quigley and Zhang2003)).

16 Notably, as shown later, our result can hold when $\mu =\sigma/(\sigma -1),$ that is, when there is no upper bound of a mark-up.

17 Our two types of innovations correspond to the standard categories of innovations, namely, product innovation and business process innovation (OECD/Eurostat (2018)).

18 From a broader perspective, this $\lambda$ can relate to firms’ absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal (Reference Cohen and Levinthal1989)). See also Aghion and Jarave (Reference Aghion and Jarave2015) for a recent contribution, in consideration of the role of absorptive capacity in innovation and growth.

19 The financial asset $Q(t)$ owned by the consumer (in the form of equity of monopolistic firms) earns the return rate, $r(t),$ in each period, $t;$ see footnote.Footnote 13 As is standard in the canonical innovation-based growth model, this earning is from the profits of all monopolistic firms (in the form of dividends).

20 See Furukawa et al. (Reference Furukawa, Lai and Sato2019) for details.

21 See also (12).

22 Note that $\rho (t+1)\gt 0$ always holds, owing to $\varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}\beta (\mu -1)L\gt 1.$

23 If $\sigma =1,$ the consumption goods are independent goods; thus, the expenditure share between new and old goods is constant, and free from love of novelty $\varepsilon$. Notably, under $\sigma =1,$ the condition in Lemma 2 becomes independent of $\varepsilon .$

24 This is owing to the well-known scale effect within the model. Although the existence of the scale effect has been empirically rejected from a long-run perspective, by using 100 years of data (Jones (Reference Jones1995)), it might contribute to world development in the very long run: As Boserup (Reference Boserup1965) argues, population growth often triggers the adoption of new technology because people are forced to adopt new technology when their population becomes too large to be supported by existing technology. The empirical finding of Kremer (Reference Kremer1993) also suggests that total research output increases with population. Consistent with these views, Lemma 4 shows that population size affects technological progress in the long run. The threshold level of $L$ in (31), $L_{0},$ comprises several parameters. Because, for instance, $L_{0}$ decreases with $\kappa,$ the productivity of firms has a role in avoiding traps, which is natural and intuitive.

25 $\varepsilon _{-}^{\sigma -1}=\frac{L-\sqrt{D}}{(2/\kappa )(1+1/(\beta (\mu -1)))}$, $\varepsilon _{+}^{\sigma -1}=\frac{L+\sqrt{D}}{(2/\kappa )(1+1/(\beta (\mu -1)))}$.

26 The sufficiency of (31) is proven in Lemma 4. Notably, $D\leq 0\Leftrightarrow L\leq L_{0}$. (31) is also necessary because quadratic inequality (32) has no solution if $L\leq L_{0}$.

27 Note that a time preference rate $\beta$ of $0.95$ in discrete-time models is analogous to a subjective discount rate of $0.05$ in continuous-time models (e.g., Acemoglu and Akcigit (Reference Acemoglu and Akcigit2012)).

28 These are an average value using World Bank Open Data. Note that we only use data of 1996–2001 for the R&D share owing to data availability. Additionally, note that the derivations for theoretical moments used in our calibration are available upon request.

29 This requires $n(0)\equiv N(0)/A(0)\lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ (Lemma 1). Since the economy alternates between those two innovation processes, only existing product development occurs in period $t-1,$ hence, $N(0)=0.$ Thus, $n(0)\lt \varepsilon ^{\sigma -1}/\kappa$ always holds.

30 Our simulation does not replicate the inverted-U relationship we document in Figure 1 in a strict sense. However, in our model, the average growth rate becomes zero if $\varepsilon \notin (\varepsilon _-, \varepsilon _+)$, and it becomes positive with moderate $\varepsilon \in (\varepsilon _-, \varepsilon _+)$. Thus, very high and very low $\varepsilon$ can hurt innovation and growth. In this sense, our theory can capture an essential aspect of the nonmonotonic relationship in Figure 1.

31 This variable is also used by Bénabou et al. (Reference Bénabou, Ticchi and Vindigni2015) to measure people’s general openness to novelty.

32 More specifically, Patent applications per million capita for a country is computed as the sum of the country’s patent applications over 2010–2015 divided by the country’s average population over 2010–2015. The other measures are computed in a similar way.

33 For each country, we take the average of nonmissing values over 2011–2015 as its Global Innovation Index.

34 See Bento (Reference Bento2021) for a recent study that also uses Hall et al.’s (Reference Hall, Jaffe and Trajtenberg2001) originality measure. Notably, his focus is quite different from ours, and particularly on the effects of patent protection on patent originality.

35 These control variables are also used in Bénabou et al. (Reference Bénabou, Ticchi and Vindigniforthe coming).

36 Notably, this variable has an outlier (for Colombia); its value is 8.210, whereas the maximum value of the remaining countries is approximately 6.185. In the results reported, this outlier is excluded.

References

Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., Bursztyn, L. and Hemous, D. (2012) The environment and directed technical change. American Economic Review 102(1), 131166.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. A. (2005) Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-term growth. Handbook of Economic Growth 1A, 386464.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Akcigit, U. (2012) Intellectual property rights policy, competition and innovation. Journal of the European Economic Association 10(1), 142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acs, Z., and Sanders, M. (2012) Patents, knowledge spillovers, and entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics 39(4), 801817.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., and Howitt, P. (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(2), 323351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., and Howitt, P. (1996) Research and development in the growth process. Journal of Economic Growth 1(1), 4973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., and Jarave, X. (2015) Knowledge spillovers, innovation and growth. Economic Journal 125(583), 533573.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akiyama, T. (2009) R&D, entrepreneurship, and growth. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., and Giuliano, P. (2010) The power of the family. Journal of Economic Growth 15(2), 93125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashraf, Q., and Galor, O. (2007) Cultural assimilation, cultural diffusion and the origin of the wealth of nations. CEPR Discussion Papers No. 6444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashraf, Q., and Galor, O. (2013a) The out of Africa hypothesis, human genetic diversity, and comparative economic development. American Economic Review 103(1), 146.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ashraf, Q., and Galor, O. (2013b) Genetic diversity and the origins of cultural fragmentation. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 103(3), 528533.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ashraf, Q., and Galor, O. (2018) The macrogenoeconomics of comparative development. Journal of Economic Literature 56(3), 11191155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barber, B. (1961) Resistance by scientists to scientific discovery. Science 134(3479), 596602.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Barro, R., and Lee, J.-W. (2013) A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950-2010. Journal of Development Economics 104, 184198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bénabou, R., Ticchi, D. and Vindigni, A. (2015) Religion and innovation. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 105(5), 346351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bénabou, R., Ticchi, D. and Vindigni, A. (2022) Forbidden fruits: The political economy of science, religion, and growth. Review of Economic Studies 89(4), 17851832.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bento, P. (2021) Quantifying the effects of patent protection on innovation, imitation, growth, and aggregate productivity. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 21(1), 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beveridge, W. I. B. (1959) The Art of Scientific Investigation. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Boserup, E. (1965) The Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of Agrarian Change under Population Pressure. Chicago: Aldine.Google Scholar
Broda, C., and Weinstein, D. E. (2006) Globalization and the gains from variety. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(2), 541585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. C. (2007) Confidence-enhanced economic growth. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics (Topics) 7(1), Article 13.Google Scholar
Chu, A. C., Cozzi, G., Furukawa, Y. and Liao, C.-H. (2022) Should the government subsidize innovation or automation? Macroeconomic Dynamics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Chu, A. C., Cozzi, G. and Galli, S. (2012) Does intellectual monopoly stimulate or stifle innovation? European Economic Review 56(4), 727746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. C., Cozzi, G., Pan, S. and Zhang, M. (2020) Do stronger patents stimulate or stifle innovation? The crucial role of financial development. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 52(5), 13051322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. C., Fan, H. and Wang, X. (2020) Status-seeking culture and development of capitalism. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 180, 275290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. C., Furukawa, Y., Mallick, S., Peretto, P. and Wang, X. (2021) Dynamic effects of patent policy on innovation and inequality in a Schumpeterian economy. Economic Theory 71(4), 14291465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. C., and Cozzi, G. (2011) Cultural preference on fertility and the growth and welfare effects of intellectual property rights. MPRA Paper No. 31283.Google Scholar
Chu, A. C., and Furukawa, Y. (2013) Patentability and knowledge spillovers of basic R&D. Southern Economic Journal 79(4), 928945.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, W. M., and Levinthal, D. A. (1989) Innovation and learning: The two faces of R&D. Economic Journal 99(397), 569596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cozzi, G. (1998) Culture as a bubble. Journal of Political Economy 106(2), 376394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cozzi, G., and Galli, S. (2009) Science-based R&D in Schumpeterian growth. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 56(4), 474491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cozzi, G., and Galli, S. (2013). Privatization of knowledge: Did the U.S. get it right? Economics Working Paper Series 1307, University of St. Gallen, School of Economics and Political Science. Google Scholar
Cozzi, G., and Galli, S. (2014) Sequential R&D and blocking patents in the dynamics of growth. Journal of Economic Growth 19(2), 183219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dastidar, K. G., and Yano, M. (2021) Corruption, market quality and entry deterrence in emerging economies. International Journal of Economic Theory 17(1), 101117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deneckere, R., and Judd, K. (1992) Cyclical and chaotic behavior in a dynamic equilibrium model. In: Deneckere, R. and Judd, K..(eds.), Cycles and Chaos in Economic Equilibrium, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Doepke, M., and Zilibotti, F. (2014) Culture, entrepreneurship, and growth. Handbook of Economic Growth 2A, 148.Google Scholar
Doi, J., and Mino, K. (2008) A variety-expansion model of growth with external habit formation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32(10), 30553083.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, L., Quigley, N. and Zhang, J. (2003) Optimal price regulation in a growth model with monopolistic suppliers of intermediate goods. Canadian Journal of Economics 36(2), 463474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fagerberg, J. (2004) Innovation: A guide to the literature. In: Fagerberg, J.(eds.), Oxford Handbook of Innovation, Nelson: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fagerberg, J. (2013) Innovation: A new guide. Working Paper, University of Oslo, Aalborg University, and Lund University. (accessed on August 29, 2017). Available at: http://www.sv.uio.no/tik/InnoWP/tik_working_paper_19112013.pdf.Google Scholar
Francois, P., and Shi, S. (1999) Innovation, growth, and welfare-improving cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 85(2), 226257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furukawa, Y. (2015) Leapfrogging cycles in international competition. Economic Theory 59(2), 401433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furukawa, Y., Lai, T.-K. and Sato, K. (2019) Love of novelty: A source of innovation-based growth … or underdevelopment traps? MPRA Paper No. 95700. Google Scholar
Gale, D. (1996) Delay and cycles. Review of Economic Studies 63(2), 169198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O., and Michalopoulos, S. (2012) Evolution and the growth process: Natural selection of entrepreneurial traits. Journal of Economic Theory 147(2), 759780.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O., and Moav, O. (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 11331192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, R., and Shapiro, C. (1990) Optimal patent length and breadth. RAND Journal of Economics 21(1), 106112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goh, A.-T., and Olivier, J. (2002) Optimal patent protection in a two-sector economy. International Economic Review 43(4), 11911214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gören, E. (2017) The persistent effects of novelty-seeking traits on comparative economic development. Journal of Development Economics 126, 112126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. M., and Helpman, E. (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hall, B. H., Jaffe, A. and Trajtenberg, M. (2001) The NBER patent citations data file: Lessons, insights and methodological tools. NBER Working Papers No. 8498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hof, F. X., and Prettner, K. (2019) The quest for status and R&D-based growth. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 162, 290307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iwaisako, T., and Futagami, K. (2007) Dynamic analysis of patent policy in an endogenous growth model. Journal of Economic Theory 132(1), 306334.Google Scholar
Iwaisako, T., and Futagami, K. (2013) Patent protection, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Economic Theory 52(2), 631668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iwaisako, T., and Tanaka, H. (2017) Product cycles and growth cycles. Journal of International Economics 105, 2240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I. (1995) Time series tests of endogenous growth models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(2), 495525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I., and Williams, J. C. (2000) Too much of a good thing? The economics of investment in R&D. Journal of Economic Growth 5(1), 6585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, K. L. (1985) On the performance of patents. Econometrica 53(3), 567586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konishi, K. (2018) Basic and applied research: A welfare analysis. Japanese Economic Review 69(4), 414437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kremer, M. (1993) Population growth and technological change: One million B.C. to 1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3), 681716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, C.-W. (2001) On the policy implications of endogenous technological progress. Economic Journal 111(471), C164C179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuyama, K. (1999) Growing through cycles. Econometrica 67(2), 335347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuyama, K. (2001) Growing through cycles in an infinitely lived agent economy. Journal of Economic Theory 100(2), 220234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michelacci, C. (2003) Low returns in R&D due to the lack of entrepreneurial skills. Economic Journal 113(484), 207225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2000 (1996, DP)) Innovation and its enemies: The economic and political roots of technological inertia. In: Olson, M. and Kahkohnen, S. (eds.), A Not-so-dismal Science: A Broader View of Economies and Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2005) Long-term economic growth and the history of technology. Handbook of Economic Growth 1B, 11141174.Google Scholar
OECD/Eurostat (2018) Oslo Manual 2018: Guidelines for Collecting, Reporting and Using Data on Innovation, 4th Edition, The Measurement of Scientific, Technological and Innovation Activities. Paris/Eurostat, Luxembourg: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
Pan, S., Zhang, M. and Zou, H.-F. (2018) Status preference and the effects of patent protection: Theory and evidence. Macroeconomic Dynamics 22(4), 837863.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, W. G. (2008) International patent protection: 1960-2005. Research Policy 37(4), 761766.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogers, E. M. (1962) Diffusion of Innovations. New York: Free Press of Glencoe.Google Scholar
Romer, P. M. (1990) Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98(5, Part 2), S71S102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A. (1986) Implementation cycles. Journal of Political Economy 94(6), 11631190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunaga, M. (2017) Endogenous growth cycles with financial intermediaries and entrepreneurial innovation. Journal of Macroeconomics 53, 191206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tabellini, G. (2010) Culture and institutions: Economic development in the regions of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association 8(4), 677716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tellis, G. J., Yin, E. and Bell, S. (2009) Global consumer innovativeness: Cross-country differences and demographic commonalities. Journal of International Marketing 17(2), 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yano, M. (2009) The foundation of market quality economics. Japanese Economic Review 60(1), 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yano, M., and Furukawa, Y. (2023) Two-dimensional constrained chaos and industrial revolution cycles. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 120, e2117497120.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Figure 0

Figure 1. Scatter plots. Note: This figure shows various scatter plots between love of novelty (measured by Question E046 of the world values survey) and measures of innovation. Further details about the data sources and the variables are in the Appendix.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Illustration of Lemma 1.

Figure 2

Figure 3. New product development regime.

Figure 3

Figure 4. Existing product development regime.

Figure 4

Table 1. Calibrated parameters

Figure 5

Figure 5. The dynamics of total output.

Figure 6

Table 2. Summary statistics

Figure 7

Table 3. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (1)

Figure 8

Table 4. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (2)

Figure 9

Table 5. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (3)

Figure 10

Table 6. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (4)

Figure 11

Table 7. The relationship between love of novelty and innovation (5)

Figure 12

Table 8. The relationship between love of novelty and originality