Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T21:05:40.722Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The cycle of monasticism: understanding the nature of medieval economic and political innovation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 December 2024

Jørgen Møller*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Aarhus University, Aarhus C, Denmark
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This research note develops a new theory about innovation in medieval monastic orders that, first, allows us to better understand medieval society and the nature of its dynamism, and second, can be applied to other areas of research on medieval Europe. Medieval monasteries were set in a society that—despite its famous dynamism—was deeply backward-looking. But monastic life generated antinomies that came from the tension between the degeneration into well-living and the ideal of the asceticism of the first Christians. These tensions sparked repeated attempts to reform monastic life, which were understood by reformers not as innovations but rather as efforts to restore the good old ways. This invention of tradition had economic and political repercussions, first in the monasteries themselves and then in surrounding lay society. To understand these processes, we must avoid reading history backward from a modern context that looks entirely different.

Type
Note
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Religion and Politics Section of the American Political Science Association

Introduction

There is a broad agreement that the three centuries after AD 1000 saw a series of crucial developments that were to permanently shape European state-formation. In the last 50 years, historians have pushed the crucial period of European state-formation back to the tenth, eleventh, and twelfth centuries (e.g., Berman, Reference Berman1983; Black, Reference Black1992, 191; Bartlett, Reference Bartlett1993; Moore, Reference Moore2000; Oakley, Reference Oakley2010, xi; Siedentop, Reference Siedentop2014; Wickham, Reference Wickham2016, 254; Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022). Social scientists have emphasized the rule of law tradition that crystallized in this period, as well as other institutions of constraints such as medieval parliaments and urban self-government that also date to this period (e.g., Downing, Reference Downing1992; Ertman, Reference Ertman1997; Fukuyama, Reference Fukuyama2011; Stasavage, Reference Stasavage2011, Reference Stasavage2016; Blaydes and Chaney, Reference Blaydes and Chaney2013; Belloc et al., Reference Belloc, Drago and Galbiati2016; Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2019; Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022). Finally, economic historians have pointed to the technological innovations that took place and the economic growth they fostered (see, e.g., Boix, Reference Boix2015; Abramson and Boix, Reference Abramson and Boix2019).

Why was this period so innovative? New research has taken up but refined an old idea: that medieval monastic orders played a crucial role in both economic and political development in the high Middle Ages (AD 1000–1300). There is certainly nothing new about the claim that medieval monasteries are an important part of European history. During the early Middle Ages (AD 500–1000), they preserved a flicker of learning in a society where urban civilization had collapsed and where secular education had disappeared. In Anderson's (Reference Anderson1974, 131) marvelous metaphor, the monasteries were “the main, frail aqueduct across which the cultural reservoirs of the Classical World now passed to the new universe of feudal Europe, where literacy had become clerical” (see also Oakley, Reference Oakley2012, 44–45; Fried, Reference Fried2015, 53). But recent years have seen more specific work on the way medieval monastic orders affected European state-formation in the high Middle Ages. According to a series of new contributions, three monastic orders—the Cistercians, the Cluniacs, and the Dominicans—spearheaded a series of startling innovation: they promoted early capitalist work ethics (Cistercians), they facilitated the transition to urban self-government (Cluniacs), and they spread the practice of representation (Dominicans) (Andersen et al., Reference Andersen, Bentzen, Dalgaard and Sharp2016; Doucette, Reference Doucette2021; Doucette and Møller, Reference Doucette and Møller2021; Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022).

If we accept these findings, the medieval monastic orders played a crucial role in European processes of state-formation, regime change, and economic development. They made up what in retrospect can be seen as a sledgehammer of economic and political change in a society where tradition normally kept such startling change in check, or at least kept it moving at a snail's pace. So far, the new research has mainly focused on the lay receptivity of monastic innovations—that is, how they diffused from monastic centers to lay society and what enabled this diffusion. These are, of course, crucial questions. Had there been no receptivity, the monastic innovations would have remained isolated—in their islands of learning—soon to be forgotten. But the first-order questions surely concern the mechanisms of production: Why was it that innovations would regularly occur within monastic orders? How and why did bursts of innovation begin and how and why did they end?

The new research on monastic orders has so far had very little to say about the conditions that facilitated the innovations themselves. In this short research note, I propose an explanation for why startling innovations repeatedly took place in monasteries in the period from 1000 to 1300 AD. This is what I term “the cycle of monasticism,”Footnote 1 which again and again played out in monasteries in the period 1000–1300 as reformers introduced innovations to secure a return to lost piety, followed by a gradual fall back into sumptuousness that triggered another burst of innovation. These dynamics were facilitated by state weakness which created the demand for bottom-up religious renewal, and the innovations had lay knock-on effects, first in the areas surrounding the monasteries and then diffusing wider in medieval society. I first place these developments in historical context, then proceed to develop my argument, which emphasizes how breakthroughs paradoxically owed to efforts to return to tradition. The penultimate section discusses how far the argument can travel; the Conclusions reflect on the wider consequences for European state-formation and economic development.

Context: the invention of tradition

It is widely recognized today that the European Middle Ages were innovative in several respects, from technology and intellectual pursuits to law and politics (Wickham, Reference Wickham2009, Reference Wickham2016; Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022). However, as all great agrarian civilizations, the medieval Latin West was also a society that was traditionalist in a way that is difficult to understand today. In medieval Europe, authority—political, legal, and intellectual—was normally venerated because it was old. In their self-understanding, medieval intellectuals did not attempt to create new knowledge. Even after the advent of universities, academic study took the form of revisiting classical authorities, not going beyond them (Oakley, Reference Oakley2012, 207–208).

Much the same can be said about the nature and exercise of law, singled out as one of the great contributions of the Middle Ages. It is to this period we normally date the notion of the supremacy of law or that “law transcends politics” (Berman, Reference Berman1983, 9) by standing above and constraining rulers (Berman, Reference Berman1983, 86; Tamanaha, Reference Tamanaha2004; Krygier, Reference Krygier2016, 209–210). The medieval conception was indeed that “law was found not made”; that it was “a matter of knowledge rather than of will” (Tierney, Reference Tierney1982, 30). For a very long period, no medieval monarch had the right to make new laws: rather than lawmakers, they are better seen as judges who in royal courts or by visiting local courts interpreted the rules that already existed (Boucoyannis, Reference Boucoyannis2021).

So, even in the areas where medieval society was most vibrant—the study of theology and the study and exercise of law—it was vibrant in a backward-looking way that is very different from modern intellectual pursuits.Footnote 2 How do we reconcile the dynamism of the Middle Ages with its veneration for established authority and knowledge? At the core of this paradox lay what we today refer to as the “invention of tradition” (Hobsbawm and Ranger, Reference Hobsbawm and Ranger1983). The Middle Ages were characterized by a series of staggering changes that were presented as nothing more than a return to the good old ways. The dynamism of the Middle Ages was, thus, combined with a constant need to invoke historical precedent. Astonishing innovations were constantly dressed up as a revival of tradition.

The cycle of monasticism: antinomies of monastic life and radical innovation

It is through this lens that we should understand the monastic innovations of the high Middle Ages (AD 1000–1300). Monastic environments were characterized by the same mental outlook as the rest of society, but the yearning for tradition paradoxically carried the seeds of radical innovations. There was constantly a minority of fervent monks and friars who “sought the renewal of Christianity and the raising of the standards of the Christian life” (Cowdrey, Reference Cowdrey1998, 242). In their own understanding, what they longed for was a return to the vita religiosa of the early believers, even the asceticism of the apostles (the vita apostolica).

These yearnings were so strong because they ultimately concerned salvation, or the status of the individual believer in the afterlife.Footnote 3 In the Christian East, these cravings found extreme expression in hermits who chose to live in total asceticism in the desert or even on pillars, such as the famous Syrian Christian ascetic Simeon Stylites who in the fifth century allegedly spent 36 years on top of a column near Aleppo. In the Latin West, we find similar individual cases of holy men, but the restorative efforts were mainly channeled into monastic institutions. The desires for a return to the purer Christian life were particularly strong in the well-functioning monasteries, especially in new foundations that had been established to make a break with laxness and well-living in monasteries that had lost their zeal. In these new communities, pious reformers would attempt to restore the Christian ways by reforming lax practices and replacing these with a much sterner discipline. Then—after a couple of generations guided by this revolutionary spirit—the monastic communities would gradually fall back on the easier living that their founders had broken with.

A case in point is the Franciscan order, which was based on a lifestyle of evangelical poverty, or more precisely, the assumption that the apostles had owned no property but had begged for their daily bread and a place to sleep. Massive endowments to the pious Franciscans quickly created a tension with this doctrine, which was illustrated by their sumptuous church buildings in, for example, Italian cities. Pope Gregory IX (r. 1227–1241) had come to the aid of the Franciscans by ruling that the property bequeathed to them belonged to the papacy but that they had the (full) right to use it. Gradually, a conflict arose within the order where some Franciscans (known as “Spirituals”) attempted to defend St. Francis' principle of evangelical poverty whereas the majority of the friars accepted the new situation and the benefits it created for the order (as well as the individual friar). The conflict came into the open and split the order when Pope John XXII (r. 1316–1334) revoked Gregory IX's ruling and forced the Franciscans to own up to their endowments or forfeit them.

We can, thus, think of monastic environments as having a life cycle where individual monasteries (and later, new monastic orders) were repeatedly founded to improve discipline and adhere to the monastic rule in stricter ways than in old establishments. As Andersen et al. (Reference Andersen, Bentzen, Dalgaard and Sharp2016, 1756) write about the early Cistercians, “[t]hey rejected the developments the Benedictines had undergone and tried to reproduce life exactly as it had been in St. Benedict's time; in fact, they often ventured beyond it in austerity.” Over time, and often as a consequence of the successes of these revolutionaries, a new laxness and ossification was introduced before the cycle began anew with new reforms and reactions (see Figure 1). The analogy to Khaldun's (Reference Khaldūn1958 [1377]) theory of civilization in the Muqaddimah is obvious: fervent nomads conquer stale civilized areas and establish a fresh start that creates renewed progress. Over time, the new rulers become corrupted by civilization, and decay sets in, which is the point of departure for a new cycle (see Gellner, Reference Gellner1981).

Figure 1. Monastic life cycle of reform, innovation, and reaction.

This cycle characterizes all three of the examples that have been singled out in the new body of scholarship referred to above. The Cluniacs had been the vanguard of monasticism around AD 1000. But the Cistercians broke with the Cluniacs in 1098 because of the latter's perceived lapse into ceremony and sumptuousness. Shortly after AD 1200, the mendicant orders—Dominicans and Franciscans—rebelled against the old monastic environment that the Cistercians represented. In the case of the Dominicans, one of the main points of contention was that the established Church did not provide the kind of pastoral care that townsmen were seeking—a vacuum that had opened the door to heretic ideas such as those of the Cathars of Languedoc.

The core mechanism of innovation is thus a very simple one. In the words of church historian MacCulloch (Reference MacCulloch2022, 9), “[w]ell-functioning monasteries constantly do their best to reform themselves, because monastic life is always prone to lapse into unheroic comfort and modified austerity.” These reforms then—if we trust the new literature reviewed in the Introduction—have wider repercussions: in the case of the Cistercians, in the form of economic development that would fan out in the vicinity of the monastic environments (Andersen et al., Reference Andersen, Bentzen, Dalgaard and Sharp2016), and in the case of the Cluniacs and Dominicans, in the form of institutional creation that would trigger lay political regime change in medieval towns (Doucette, Reference Doucette2021; Doucette and Møller, Reference Doucette and Møller2021; Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022). We thus see different variations of the same basic mechanism in the three cases of the Cluniacs, the Cistercians, and the Dominicans. These lay repercussions were, in all cases, unintended consequences of attempts to return to the vita religiosa.

The cases of the Cluniacs, the Cistercians, and the Dominicans also show how the mechanisms of innovation were nested in a more general scope condition that characterizes the high Middle Ages. Throughout most of the early Middle Ages (AD 500–1000), monasteries in the Latin West had been subservient to lay power and especially monarchical power. This came to an end with the ninth- and tenth-century state collapse, aka. the Carolingian state collapse (Wickham, Reference Wickham2009, Reference Wickham2016; see Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022). As recently as in the first part of the ninth century, Carolingian monarchs had controlled and reformed their monasteries. A case in point is Benedict of Aniane's monastic reforms, which Carolingian Emperor Louis the Pious forced on monastic communities of his realm at three synods in Aachen in 816, 817, and 818/19 (Melville, Reference Melville2016, 40).

After the Carolingian state collapse—inaugurated by the tripartition of the realm at the treaties of Verdun (843) and Meerssen (870)—this royal control over and regulation of monastic institutions was missing (see Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022). The post-Carolingian absence of strong royal power, capable of reforming monastic environments from above, gave free rein to the bottom-up reforms that we find in the cases of the Cluniacs, the Cistercians, and the Dominicans. We can thus think of state collapse or at least political fragmentation as a scope condition for medieval monastic innovation.

How far can the argument travel?

This last point help explain why these radical features of monastic environments gradually weakened as state power grew again in the late Middle Ages (after AD 1300) (Wickham, Reference Wickham2016, 142). Nonetheless, the monastic life cycle and the innovations it created did not entirely go away.

Perhaps the best example is the Society of Jesus, or Jesuits, founded by the Spanish nobleman Ignatius of Loyola in 1540. The Jesuits soon spread across Catholic Europe and later Latin America. In their pursuit of Catholic renewal, they emphasized education and helped spread institutions of higher learning across Europe (Friedrich, Reference Friedrich2022). It seems plausible to see this as yet another example of how monastic reform—a deliberate return to piety—had lay repercussions in the areas it affected. This was especially important in areas of low state power such as Poland and much of Latin America, whereas the dynamic was more difficult in “absolutist” countries such as Spain itself, or France.

Likewise, the Lutheran and especially the Calvinist Reformation can be viewed through the prism developed above. These reformations were sparked by deeply pious reformers who confronted what they saw as a stale and corrupt Church establishment. As in the monasteries in the high Middle Ages, the aim of the reformations was strictly religious. But the known-on effects were substantial: the new piety and new organizations founded by the reformers have been attributed a cornucopia of effects on state formation, regime change, and economic development (for an overview, see Becker et al., Reference Becker, Pfaff and Rubin2016). It has also been persuasively argued that the spread of the reformation was facilitated by state weakness or political fragmentation. Reformation ideas spread first in the many self-governing cities that we find in the “urban belt” running from the Netherlands, via Western Germany and Switzerland to northern Italy (Cantoni, Reference Cantoni2012). Had state power been more robust in this area, rulers such as the Habsburg emperor Charles V (r. 1519–1558)—and later the Counterreformation leadership—would have been able to root out the Reformation.

To what extent can the argument travel beyond the Latin West? Here, it is important to recall that the purpose of this research note is not to put the theory formulated above to an empirical test. But the question still merits a brief discussion. One would imagine that at least in Eastern Christianity, similar mechanisms could play out in monastic environments. After all, here, too, we find the yearning for a return to the vita apostolica, backed by the incentives created by the awesome concepts of eternal salvation and eternal damnation. But historically, state power in, for example, the Byzantine Empire remained much more robust than in the Latin West, and church institutions were generally subjected to the state (Oakley, Reference Oakley2010, 103–105; Stasavage, Reference Stasavage2020, 104–105). In other words, we do not find the combination of politically autonomous church institutions and state weakness that characterized the Latin West at least in the high Middle Ages (see Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022). This likely inhibited “the cycle of monasticism” theorized in this research note. It might also help explain why in the Christian East, the most famous attempts to practice religious asceticism were, as mentioned above, carried out by individual hermits rather than monastic institutions.

Nonetheless, it would be interesting to empirically apply these theoretical ideas to monastic environments in the different branches of Eastern Christianity, especially in periods where state power was low. It would also be interesting to probe whether similar dynamics played out in other monastic traditions, for instance, in Buddhist agrarian civilizations. After all, we find many areas and periods with monastic traditions where state power was rather feeble, including in what is today India (see Stasavage, Reference Stasavage2020). But this kind of comparative empirical outlook lies beyond the scope of this short research note, the purpose of which is simply to shed light on the theoretical puzzle left by the new research on medieval Western monastic orders.

Conclusions

The new research on medieval monastic orders has important implications for our understanding of European history. They corroborate recent arguments that European state-formation and patterns of economic development cannot be understood without factoring in the role of ecclesiastical institutions and religious ideas (Schulz et al., Reference Schulz, Bahrami-Rad, Beauchamp and Henrich2019; Henrich, Reference Henrich2020; Møller and Doucette, Reference Møller and Doucette2022; Schulz, Reference Schulz2022; Grzymala-Busse, Reference Grzymala-Busse2023). More specifically, they underline the importance of Western monasticism. The paradox is thrilling. Monasticism represented a retreat from the sinful world, but monks could not escape the world in two respects. First, sin constantly crept back in, and this became unbearable for many genuinely pious monks and friars who yearned for the asceticism of the early Christians. Second, the political and economic innovations that the consequent attempts to reform monasteries spurred time and again diffused to lay society.

But the argument I have presented about monastic innovation has wider implications. The medieval “invention of tradition” might have been most radical in reform-oriented monasteries, but it arguably characterized other medieval innovations. I have already mentioned the universities as milieus where authority was venerated because it was old and where the knowledge produced had already, preferably, been formulated by classical authors of high status, such as Aristotle. We misunderstand the universities if we do not factor in that intellectual pursuits did not aim to create anything new but to rediscover forgotten knowns. A hugely learned work in the eyes of contemporaries would, therefore, be one that revisited and rearranged knowledge, not an attempt to formulate new ideas. The ultimate ideal was to systematize all the knowledge that had ever existed, especially the knowledge of antiquity, much of which had been partially or fully lost.

But these ambitious endeavors to rearrange knowledge would often prove surprisingly dynamic and flexible, and they would carry the germ of innovation. The best example of this dynamic flexibility is perhaps the rediscovery and startling reinterpretation of Roman law in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries. The university men studying Roman law believed that they were simply reviving it, but in reality, they “produced something quite new” (Berman, Reference Berman1983, 149; see also Oakley, Reference Oakley2012, 149; Stasavage, Reference Stasavage2016, 150–152; Møller, Reference Møller2018).

Just as in the case of the monasteries, this dynamism and flexibility was enabled by the collapse of state power in the period from the mid-ninth to the early twelfth centuries. This weakening of royal power created a social order where rulers had to negotiate with strong social groups. It “helped to create political systems across Europe which allowed engagement” (Wickham, Reference Wickham2016, 256). One historian has compared it to the “social revolutions” Theda Skocpol (Reference Skocpol1979) analyzed in her work on the French, Russian, and Chinese revolutions (see Moore, Reference Moore2000, 5). This absence of top-down authority was a scope condition of medieval innovation and perhaps what set it apart from many other great agrarian civilizations. To understand these processes properly, we must avoid reading history backward from the modern world where science and innovations are deliberately understood as the production of new knowledge and where state power is high.

Competing interests

None.

Jørgen Møller has a PhD from the European University Institute, Italy and is currently a professor at the Department of Political Science, Aarhus University, Denmark. His research interests include conceptualization of democracy and the rule of law, patterns of state formation and regime change, the relationship between religion and politics, especially in medieval Europe, the historical development of state systems, and historical comparative methodology.

Footnotes

1. I am indebted to an anonymous reviewer for suggesting this formulation.

2. A case in point is the revolutionary political practices of representation and consent, developed via a very creative interpretation of rediscovered Roman law in the twelfth century. These practices were based on the explicit wording in clauses such as quod omnes tangit ab omnibus approbetur (“that which affects all people must be approved by all people”) that had never been used in this way in Roman law before. They were first used in ecclesiastical courts where lawyers met as proctorial representatives, a way of committing the parties (say monasteries or cathedral chapters) in trials about ecclesiastical rights while having the court meet in faraway Rome. In the early thirteenth century, however, popes began to use them in a political way, for instance at the Fourth Lateran Council 1215 where representatives of cathedral chapters all over the Latin West met in order to be able to consent to taxation (Møller, Reference Møller2018).

3. On the power of religious motivations in medieval society, see Riley-Smith (2005 [Reference Riley-Smith1987]).

References

Abramson, SF and Boix, C (2019) Endogenous parliaments: the domestic and international roots of long-term economic growth and executive constraints in Europe. International Organization 73(4), 793837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D and Robinson, JA (2019) The Narrow Corridor: States, Societies, and the Fate of Liberty. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Andersen, T, Bentzen, J, Dalgaard, C-J and Sharp, P (2016) Pre-Reformation roots of the Protestant ethic. The Economic Journal 127(604), 17561793.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, P (1974) Lineages of the Absolutist State. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Bartlett, R (1993) The Making of Europe: Conquest, Colonization and Cultural Change 950–1350. London: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Becker, S, Pfaff, S and Rubin, J (2016) Causes and consequences of the Protestant Reformation. Explorations in Economic History 62, 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belloc, M, Drago, F and Galbiati, R (2016) Earthquakes, religion, and transition to self-government in Italian cities. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131(4), 18751926.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, HJ (1983) Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Black, A (1992) Political Thought in Europe 1250–1450. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaydes, L and Chaney, E (2013) The feudal revolution and Europe's rise: political divergence of the Christian West and the Muslim World before 1500 CE. American Political Science Review 107(1), 1634.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, C (2015) Political Order and Inequality: Their Foundations and Their Consequences for Human Welfare. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucoyannis, D (2021) Kings as Judges: Power, Justice, and the Origins of Parliaments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cantoni, D (2012) Adopting a new religion: the case of Protestantism in 16th century Germany. The Economic Journal 122(560), 502531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowdrey, HEJ (1998) Pope Gregory VII, 1073–1085. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doucette, JS (2021) The diffusion of urban medieval representation: the Dominican order as an engine of regime change. Perspectives on Politics 19(3), 723738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doucette, JS and Møller, J (2021) The collapse of state power, the Cluniac Reform Movement, and the origins of urban self-government in medieval Europe. International Organization 75(1), 204223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downing, BM (1992) The Military Revolution and Political Change: Origins of Democracy and Autocracy in Early Modern Europe. New Haven: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ertman, T (1997) Birth of the Leviathan. Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fried, J (2015) The Middle Ages. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Friedrich, M (2022) The Jesuits: A History. New Haven: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, F (2011) The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution. London: Profile Books.Google Scholar
Gellner, E (1981) Muslim Society. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Grzymala-Busse, A (2023) Sacred Foundations: The Medieval and Religious Roots of European State Formation. New Haven: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Henrich, J (2020). The Weirdest People in the World: How the West Became Psychologically Peculiar and Particularly Prosperous. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Hobsbawm, E and Ranger, T (eds) (1983) The Invention of Tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Khaldūn, I (1958 [1377]) The Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History (in three volumes). Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Krygier, M (2016) The rule of law: pasts, presents, and two possible futures. Annual Review of Law and Social Science 12, 199229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacCulloch, D (2022) A Monk's-Eye View, London Review of Books, March 10, 9–12.Google Scholar
Melville, G (2016) The World of Medieval Monasticism: Its History and Forms of Life. Collegeville, MN: Cistercian Publications.Google Scholar
Møller, J (2018) The ecclesiastical roots of representation and consent. Perspectives on Politics 16(4), 10751084.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Møller, J and Doucette, JS (2022) The Catholic Church and European State Formation, AD 1000–1500. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, RI (2000) The First European Revolution, c. 970–1215. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Oakley, F (2010) Empty Bottles of Gentilism: Kingship and the Divine in Late Antiquity and the Early Middle Ages (to 1050). New Haven and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Oakley, F (2012) The Mortgage of the Past: Reshaping the Ancient Political Inheritance (1050–1300). New Haven and London: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riley-Smith, J (2005 [1987]) The Crusades: A History. London: Continuum.Google Scholar
Schulz, JF (2022) Kin networks and institutional development. The Economic Journal 132(647), 25782613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schulz, JF, Bahrami-Rad, D, Beauchamp, JP and Henrich, J (2019) The church, intensive kinship, and global psychological variation. Science (New York, N.Y.) 366(6466), 707719.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Siedentop, L (2014) Inventing the Individual: The Origins of Western Liberalism. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skocpol, T (1979) States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia and China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, D (2011) States of Credit. New Haven: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Stasavage, D (2016) Representation and consent: why they arose in Europe and not elsewhere. Annual Review of Political Science 19, 145162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, D (2020) The Decline and Rise of Democracy. New Haven: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tamanaha, B (2004) On the Rule of Law: History, Politics, Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tierney, B (1982) Religion, Law, and the Growth of Constitutional Thought, 1150–1650. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wickham, C (2009) The Inheritance of Rome: A History of Europe From 400 to 1000. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Wickham, C (2016) Medieval Europe: From the Breakup of the Western Roman Empire to the Reformation. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Monastic life cycle of reform, innovation, and reaction.