Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T19:04:26.446Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The demography of human warfare can drive sex differences in altruism

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 February 2020

Alberto J. C. Micheletti*
Affiliation:
School of Biology, University of St Andrews, Dyers Brae, St AndrewsKY16 9TH, UK Institute for Advanced Study in Toulouse, Université Toulouse 1 Capitole, 1 esplanade de l'Université, 31080 Toulouse Cedex 06, France
Graeme D. Ruxton
Affiliation:
School of Biology, University of St Andrews, Dyers Brae, St AndrewsKY16 9TH, UK
Andy Gardner
Affiliation:
School of Biology, University of St Andrews, Dyers Brae, St AndrewsKY16 9TH, UK
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

Recent years have seen great interest in the suggestion that between-group aggression and within-group altruism have coevolved. However, these efforts have neglected the possibility that warfare – via its impact on demography – might influence human social behaviours more widely, not just those directly connected to success in war. Moreover, the potential for sex differences in the demography of warfare to translate into sex differences in social behaviour more generally has remained unexplored. Here, we develop a kin-selection model of altruism performed by men and women for the benefit of their groupmates in a population experiencing intergroup conflict. We find that warfare can promote altruistic, helping behaviours as the additional reproductive opportunities winners obtain in defeated groups decrease harmful competition between kin. Furthermore, we find that sex can be a crucial modulator of altruism, with there being a tendency for the sex that competes more intensely with relatives to behave more altruistically and for the sex that competes more intensely with non-relatives in defeated groups to receive more altruism. In addition, there is also a tendency for the less-dispersing sex to both give and receive more altruism. We discuss implications for our understanding of observed sex differences in cooperation in human societies.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2020

Media summary: Recent research has suggested that altruism and warfare might have evolved together. However, by focusing only on behaviours that improve success in battle, this work has ignored the potential for warfare to influence altruism more widely – and has also neglected the possible role of sex differences in this context. We developed a mathematical evolutionary model to explore these questions. We found that men, the sex that historically participated in war and also migrated less often, would have tended to be more altruistic and also receive more help from other men – forming ‘boys’ clubs’. Depending on the nature of warfare and migration, other systems are also possible, including societies where it is mainly men who help women or even ‘girls’ clubs’.

Introduction

The last decade has seen considerable multidisciplinary interest in understanding the potential evolutionary links between warfare and the high levels of altruism observed in human societies (Bauer et al. Reference Bauer, Blattman, Chytilová, Henrich, Miguel and Mitts2016; Rusch Reference Rusch2014; Rusch et al. Reference Rusch, Bohm and Herrmann2016; Turchin Reference Turchin2015). Darwin (Reference Darwin1871) was the first to explore this possibility, suggesting that intergroup conflict might have generated selection for altruism, on account of more cooperative groups being more successful in warfare. Recently, this idea has been modelled mathematically by Choi and Bowles (Reference Choi and Bowles2007), who showed that within-group altruism and between-group hostility could have coevolved, leading to an intersection of these two behaviours that has been termed ‘parochial altruism’ (see also Bowles Reference Bowles2006, Reference Bowles2009; Garcia and van der Bergh Reference Garcia and van der Bergh2011). Empirical evidence for the co-occurrence of these behaviours in both small-scale and industrialised societies is mixed and still subject to investigation (Doğan et al. Reference Doğan, Glowacki and Rusch2018; Gneezy and Fessler, Reference Gneezy and Fessler2011; Mathew and Boyd Reference Mathew and Boyd2011; Romano et al. Reference Romano, Balliet, Yamagishi and Liu2017; Schaub Reference Schaub2017; Silva and Mace Reference Silva and Mace2014; also reviewed in Rusch Reference Rusch2014; Rusch et al. Reference Rusch, Bohm and Herrmann2016).

However, the possibility that warfare, through its effect on demography, might shape human social behaviours more widely than just those connected with success in war has been largely neglected. Warfare can affect with whom individuals mate and whether or not they reproduce at all (Glowacki et al. Reference Glowacki, Wilson and Wrangham2017), thus possibly altering patterns of relatedness and competition. Patterns of relatedness and competition, in turn, are known to modulate incentives to perform social behaviours (Frank Reference Frank1998) and, in this way, warfare demographies could influence other forms of within-group altruism – not just those that result in greater success in battle and that have been the focus of mathematical analyses so far (also Bowles Reference Bowles2006, Reference Bowles2009; Choi and Bowles Reference Choi and Bowles2007; Garcia and van der Bergh Reference Garcia and van der Bergh2011; Lehmann and Feldman Reference Lehmann and Feldman2008; Micheletti et al. Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2017, Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2018). Moreover, incentives to behave altruistically could vary in sex-specific ways, as warfare might affect the demography of the two sexes differently – for example through sex-biased dispersal. While sex has been suggested to modulate behaviours in the context of intergroup conflict in both empirical (Johnson et al. Reference Johnson, McDermott, Barrett, Crowden, Wrangham, McIntyre and Rosen2006; van Vugt et al. Reference van Vugt, De Cremer and Janssen2006; McDonald et al. Reference McDonald, Navarrete and van Vugt2012; van Vugt Reference van Vugt2009) and theoretical studies (Micheletti et al. Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2017, Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2018), the role of sex-biased demographies in this respect has not been explored formally. Furthermore, the intensity of altruistic behaviours might depend on the sex of the recipient of altruism, as well as on the sex of the altruist – that is, the sex of both interactants may determine behavioural patterns. Since the evolutionary interests of men and women often diverge and the two sexes play different roles in social groups (Low Reference Low2015), elucidating the possible demographic drivers of sex-specific altruism is key to illuminate human sociality.

Here, we develop a kin-selection model to assess the scope for the demography of warfare – in particular, pre-war dispersal and the movements of individuals between groups resulting from victory or defeat in war – to influence overall levels of sex-specific, within-group altruism. We perform two analyses to generate comparative predictions as to which sex is favoured by natural selection to be more altruistic and which sex is favoured to receive more altruism under different demographic conditions. We adopt a behavioural ecological approach to human behaviour (Nettle et al. Reference Nettle, Gibson, Lawson and Sear2013), focusing on the inclusive fitness effects of acting altruistically and assuming – for the purposes of analysis – that these behaviours are controlled genetically. We define altruism broadly as any behaviour that reduces the competitiveness for reproductive opportunities of the actor, but increases the competitiveness of the recipient (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1964; West et al. Reference West, Griffin and Gardner2007). Such altruism may benefit the whole group – for example, remaining vigilant at night to alert groupmates of predatory threats, contributing to the construction of public goods – or be aimed at one or more individuals – for example, helping with foraging or cultivation work, or sharing fitness-enhancing resources, such as food, tools and shelter. By focusing on overall levels of altruism, our analysis can illuminate the role of sex and demography in generating variation in all of these cases. In order to assess the effects of warfare on social behaviours not directly related to warfare itself, we assume that the altruistic behaviours under consideration do not increase the group's probability of engaging in or winning confrontations with other groups.

Methods

We employ a two-sex kin-selection model of between-group conflict, adapting and expanding a previously developed framework (Lehmann and Feldman Reference Lehmann and Feldman2008; Micheletti et al. Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2017, Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2018) to consider the evolution of altruism. We perform two analyses. In the first analysis, we explore which sex is favoured to be more altruistic by considering altruism, performed by either men or women, that benefits the group as whole. In the second analysis we investigate which sex altruism should be aimed towards, by considering the evolution of four altruistic behaviours: male-to-male altruism, male-to-female altruism, female-to-male altruism and female-to-female altruism. We determine how selection acts on each of these six altruistic traits by conducting kin-selection analyses (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1964; Maynard Smith Reference Maynard Smith1964; Taylor Reference Taylor1996; Taylor and Frank Reference Taylor and Frank1996; Frank Reference Frank1997, Reference Frank1998; Rousset Reference Rousset2004; Taylor et al. Reference Taylor, Wild and Gardner2007) (see Supporting Information for full details).

Model assumptions

Following Lehmann and Feldman (Reference Lehmann and Feldman2008) and Micheletti et al. (Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2017, Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2018), we consider an infinitely large population subdivided into an infinite number of groups, each with finite numbers N i of adults of sex i ∈ {m,f} where m denotes male and f denotes female, and we consider that all groups are equally distant from each other (assumptions shared with Wright's (Reference Wright1931) infinite island model). These are simplifying assumptions that abstract away from some of the complexity that likely characterised ancestral human populations living a hunter-gather lifestyle in the Pleistocene and many small-scale societies until recent times. For example, distance might have influenced how often groups engaged in war or maintained peaceful relations, and conflicts might have been more frequent or intense between groups from different ethnolinguistic communities (Fry Reference Fry2013). However, these assumptions afford mathematical tractability (Servedio et al. Reference Servedio, Brandvain, Dhole, Fitzpatrick, Goldberg, Stern, Van Cleve and Yeh2014) and allow the derivation of analytical results regarding the selective pressures surrounding intergroup warfare, as demonstrated by previous work adopting them (Lehmann and Feldman Reference Lehmann and Feldman2008; Micheletti et al. Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2017, Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2018).

Life cycle

At the beginning of the life cycle, the N f women and N m men in each group mate in a regime of absolute promiscuity and each woman produces a large number K f of daughters and a large number K m of sons who mature to become young adults (for simplicity and following Lehmann and Feldman (Reference Lehmann and Feldman2008) and Micheletti et al. (Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2017, Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2018) we assume non-overlapping generations, so that only young adults, hereafter ‘individuals’, can disperse, be altruistic and then reproduce). Each sex-i individual may then disperse to a randomly chosen group with sex-specific probability m i. After the dispersal phase, individuals have the opportunity to be altruistic towards their groupmates. In the first analysis, we consider altruism x i that is performed by sex i and that benefits both male and female groupmates indiscriminately. In the second analysis, we consider altruism x ij that is performed by sex i and that is aimed exclusively towards groupmates of sex j – where i, j ∈ {m,f}. The war phase follows, with each post-dispersal group having the chance to attack another randomly chosen group with probability a and be attacked by a third group – again randomly selected – with the same probability a, and with attackers winning the war with probability ω. This is followed by density-dependent regulation, consisting of scramble competition among same-sex competitors for the N i sex-i reproductive spots in each group, with different individuals having potentially different competitiveness weightings, but all successful breeders having the same fertility (i.e. no reproductive skew among breeders). Notice that results for reproductive skew could be recovered by substituting N i with the appropriate number of ‘effective’ equal-fertility breeders, and our results hold in this case (see Supporting Information).

In groups that are not attacked or that are attacked and successfully defend themselves, sex-i individuals compete only with sex-i groupmates and have competitiveness t i, which is termed the individual's intrinsic competitiveness. In groups that are attacked and are defeated by their attackers, sex-i individuals instead compete for reproductive opportunities in their group with both sex-i groupmates and with their sex-i attackers, with the conquered group's sex-i individuals having competitiveness for reproductive opportunities (1 – σ i) t i and the conquering group's sex-i individuals having competitiveness σ it i. The competitiveness modifier σ i is equal to the fraction of sex-i reproductive opportunities in a conquered group seized by conquering sex-i individuals and thus modulates the additional reproductive opportunities afforded by warfare to individuals from victorious groups. Notice that, while the model allows for defeated individuals to be forcefully relocated to the victorious group by their conquerors, it does not allow them to have reproductive success in these groups.

Altruism by men or women towards all groupmates indiscriminately

In the first analysis, the intrinsic competitiveness t i of a sex-i individual is modulated by the altruism x i performed by that sex-i individual towards male and female groupmates indiscriminately, by the altruism x i′ the sex-i individual receives from other sex-i individuals, and by the altruism x j′ the sex-i individual receives from sex-j individuals in their group, such that $-\lpar {\partial t_{\rm i}/\partial x_{\rm i}} \rpar /\bar{t}_{\rm i}\; = c_{\rm i}$ is the competitive cost of being altruistic towards groupmates incurred by the sex-i individual, and $\left( {\partial t_{\rm i}/\partial x_{\rm i}^{\prime}} \right)\; /\bar{t}_{\rm i} = \left( {\partial t_{\rm i}/\partial x_{\rm j}^{\prime}} \right)\; /\bar{t}_{\rm i}\; = b_{\rm i}$ is the marginal increase in competitiveness enjoyed by the sex-i individual as a result of altruism received from groupmates of either sex i or sex j.

Altruism by men or women towards male or female groupmates exclusively

In the second analysis, the intrinsic competitiveness t i of a sex-i individual is modulated by the altruism x ii performed by that sex-i individual towards other sex-i individuals, by the altruism x ij performed by that sex-i individual towards sex-j individuals, by the altruism x ii′ the sex-i individual receives from other sex-i individuals, and by the altruism x ji′ the sex-i individual receives from sex-j individuals in their group, such that $-\left( {\partial t_{\rm i}/\partial x_{\rm {ii}}} \right)/\bar{t}_{\rm i}\; = c_{\rm {ii}}$ is the competitive cost of being altruistic towards sex-i groupmates incurred by the sex-i individual, $-\lpar {\partial t_{\rm i}/\partial x_{\rm {ij}}} \rpar /\bar{t}_{\rm i}\; = c_{\rm {ij}}$ is the competitive cost of being altruistic towards sex-j groupmates incurred by the sex-i individual, $\lpar {\partial t_{\rm i}/\partial x_{\rm {ii}}^{\prime}} \rpar \; /\bar{t}_{\rm i}\; = b_{\rm {ii}}$ is the marginal increase in competitiveness enjoyed by the sex-i individual as a result of altruism received from sex-i groupmates, and $\lpar {\partial t_{\rm i}/\partial x_{\rm {ji}}^{\prime}} \rpar \; /\bar{t}_{\rm i}\; = \lpar {\partial t_{\rm j}/\partial x_{\rm {ij}}^{\prime}} \rpar \; /\bar{t}_{\rm j}\; = b_{\rm {ij}}$ is the marginal increase in competitiveness enjoyed by the sex-i individual as a result of altruism received from sex-j groupmates.

Results

We first investigate which sex is favoured to perform more altruism, focusing on altruistic behaviours that are uniformly beneficial for the group, that is they are not targeted towards a specific sex of groupmates. Examples of such behaviours include staying on guard to alert groupmates about predators or sharing resources equally among all individuals in the group. Analysing the model, we find that natural selection – including both direct and indirect (i.e. kin selection) effects (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1964; Maynard Smith Reference Maynard Smith1964) – favours an individual of sex i ∈ {m,f} to increase altruism that benefits male and female groupmates indiscriminately when:

(1)$$-c_{\rm i} + \alpha _{\rm i}c_{\rm i}r_{\rm {ii}} + b_{\rm i}\left( {\displaystyle{1 \over 2}r_{\rm {im}} + \displaystyle{1 \over 2}r_{\rm {if}}} \right)-b_{\rm i}\left( {\displaystyle{1 \over 2}\alpha_{\rm m}r_{\rm {im}} + \displaystyle{1 \over 2}\alpha_{\rm f}r_{\rm {if}}} \right) \gt 0,$$

where c i is the marginal cost incurred by the sex-i individual on account of their altruism towards their groupmates; b i is the marginal benefit enjoyed by the recipient of the altruistic act performed by the sex-i individual; r ij = (1 – m i)(1 – m j)r x is the genetic relatedness between groupmates of sex i and of sex j (with i, j ∈ {m,f} and r x being relatedness between individuals born in the same group; see Supporting Information); and α i = 1 – 2aωM i is the extent to which individuals of sex i compete for reproductive opportunities with same-sex groupmates – i.e. ‘locally’ – as opposed to same-sex individuals in other groups – i.e. ‘globally’ (such that α i = 1 is fully local competition and α i = 0 is fully global competition).

The scale of competition coefficient α i is modulated by a quantity M i = (1 – σ i)σ i, which describes the extent to which reproductive opportunities in a conquered group are obtained by a mixture of individuals from the winning and the defeated groups (‘admixture’, Micheletti et al. Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2017; see also Methods). For example, consider a case in which warfare is a purely male domain and thus leads to men from victorious groups reproducing in defeated groups, while women only compete in their home group (σ m > σ f = 0). This will result in higher male than female admixture (i.e. male-biased admixture, M m > M f = 0), and thus men will be the more globally competing sex and women the more locally competing sex (α m < α f = 1). If instead women compete and reproduce in defeated groups to some extent, it can be possible for admixture to be female-biased and, consequently, for women to be competing more globally then men.

The inclusive fitness interpretation of condition (1) is that, by increasing their level of altruism towards groupmates, an individual of sex i incurs: a direct-fitness cost (first term) owing to a –c i loss of competitiveness for reproductive opportunities; an indirect-fitness benefit (second term) owing to a corresponding relaxation of kin competition in their own sex, as c i reproductive opportunities become available to sex-i individuals who are competing kin with probability α i and who are related to the focal individual by r ii; an indirect-fitness benefit (third term) owing to a b i increase in competitiveness for reproductive opportunities for groupmates who, with probability ½, are men related to the focal sex-i individual by r im or, with the same probability ½, are women related to the focal sex-i individual by r if; an indirect-fitness cost (fourth term) owing to a corresponding increase in kin competition, as fewer reproductive opportunities (–b i) are available for male groupmates (or female groupmates) who are derived from the same group – and are thus competing kin – with probabilities α m (or α f) and who are related to the focal individual by r im (or r if). Note that condition (1) holds even when individuals gain a direct benefit from performing the behaviour (c i < 0), in which case this constitutes mutual benefit rather than altruism (West et al. Reference West, Griffin and Gardner2007; the results of the present analysis thus hold for cooperative behaviours in general, i.e. including both altruism and mutually beneficial cooperation).

Consideration of condition (1) reveals that the demography of warfare can generate incentives for within-group altruism under broad conditions. Specifically, altruism can be favoured whenever warfare exports at least a fraction of male or female competition for reproductive opportunities from winning groups to defeated groups (α m ≠ 1 and/or α f ≠ 1). This ensures that the inclusive fitness benefit obtained by acting altruistically towards groupmates (third term in condition (1)) is not exactly cancelled by the associated inclusive fitness cost owing to an increase in kin competition (fourth term), as would happen in populations with limited dispersal in the absence of a mechanism decoupling these two effects (Taylor Reference Taylor1992; reviewed in Lehmann and Rousset Reference Lehmann, Perrin and Rousset2010).

Furthermore, condition (1) can be rearranged into the form c i/b i < A i, where

(2)$$A_{\rm i} = \displaystyle{{\displaystyle{1 \over 2}\left( {r_{\rm {im}}-\alpha _{\rm m}r_{\rm {im}}} \right) + \displaystyle{1 \over 2}\left( {r_{\rm {if}}-\alpha _{\rm f}r_{\rm {if}}} \right)} \over {1-\alpha _{\rm i}r_{\rm {ii}}}}$$

is the ‘potential for altruism’ by members of sex i towards their groupmates (cf. Gardner Reference Gardner2010). This approach separates the cost and benefit functions (c i/b i; left-hand side of the rearranged condition) from demographic effects on altruism (the ‘potential’ A i; right-hand side). By analysing potentials for altruism, we can focus on assessing the effects of sex-specific demography on altruism – the aim of the present study – independently of the details of the cost and benefits functions.

Consideration of the potential for altruism above (equation 2) reveals two key results regarding which sex is favoured to be more altruistic. First, all else being equal, the sex that disperses at a lower rate has a greater potential for altruism than the more dispersing sex (see Figure 1a). For example, if dispersal is female-biased (m m < m f), we predict that men will be more altruistic than women (A m > A f), all else being equal. This prediction arises because, since they disperse less, men are more related to groupmates of either sex than are women (r mm > r mf > r ff) and thus reap greater benefits from being altruistic. Second, all else being equal, the sex that – as a result of warfare – competes more locally for reproductive opportunities has a higher potential for altruism towards their groupmates than the more globally competing sex (see Figure 1b). For example, if men from winning groups compete in defeated groups more than women – that is, women compete more locally (α m < α f) – then we predict that women will be more altruistic than men (A m < A f), all else being equal. This prediction arises because, as women compete with other related women more often than men, they reap greater benefits by reducing kin competition through altruistic behaviours than men do (second term in condition 1). In addition, we find that, with increasing values of frequency of war (a), levels of potentials for altruism either increase or do not change, but they never decrease (that is, dA i/da ≥ 0).

Figure 1. Male and female altruism towards groupmates of either sex. Each pie chart shows potential for altruism by men towards groupmates (purple) vs potential for altruism by women towards groupmates (brown) and the sum of the two potentials (diameter of pie chart) – for low and high values of male and female dispersal rates (a), or for low and high values of male and female scale of competition (b). Other parameter values: (a and b) N m = N f = 3, a = 0.5, ω = 0.5; (a) σ m = σ f = 0.4 leading to M m = M f = 0.24 and α m = α f = 0.88; (b) m m = m f = 0.1, σ i = 0.4 leading M i = 0.24 (for α i = 0.88) and σ i = 0.2 leading M i = 0.16 (for α i = 0.96).

We have delineated the conditions under which men and women can be favoured to act altruistically to the benefit of all individuals in their group. We now consider cases in which altruistic behaviours can be targeted at individuals of exclusively one sex – and ask whether such altruism should be directed towards male or female groupmates. Analysing the model, we find that natural selection – including both direct and indirect (i.e. kin selection) effects (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1964; Maynard Smith Reference Maynard Smith1964) – favours an individual of sex i to increase their altruism towards groupmates of sex j (where i, j ∈ {m,f}) when:

(3)$$-c_{\rm {ij}} + \alpha _{\rm i}c_{\rm {ij}}r_{\rm {ii}} + b_{\rm {ij}}r_{\rm {ij}}-\alpha _{\rm j}b_{\rm {ij}}r_{\rm {ij}} \gt 0,$$

where c ij is the marginal cost incurred by the sex-i individual on account of their altruism towards groupmates of sex j and b ij is the marginal benefit enjoyed by the sex-j recipient of the altruistic act performed by the sex-i individual.

Condition (3) can be rearranged into the form c ij/b ij < A ij, where

(4)$$A_{\rm {ij}} = \displaystyle{{r_{\rm {ij}}-\alpha _{\rm j}r_{\rm {ij}}} \over {1-\alpha _{\rm i}r_{\rm {ii}}}}$$

is the potential for altruism by members of sex i towards groupmates of sex j. Notice that, if i = j, A ij is the potential for altruism towards the same sex whereas, if i ≠ j, A ij is the potential for altruism towards the opposite sex.

Consideration of the potential for altruism immediately above (equation 4) reveals two key results. First, all else being equal, both sexes have a greater potential for altruism towards the sex that disperses less (see Figure 2a). For example, in the case of female-biased dispersal (m m < m f), we predict that men receive more altruism (A mm < A mf and A fm < A ff), all else being equal. This is because, in this situation, men are more related to groupmates of both sexes than are women (r mm > r mf > r ff, as a result of the bias in dispersal) and thus the benefits reaped by actors of both sexes from being altruistic towards men are higher. Second, both sexes have a higher potential for altruism towards members of the sex that competes more globally, all else being equal (see Figure 2b). Considering again an example in which men compete relatively more globally and women relatively more locally (α f > α m), we predict that men will receive more altruism from groupmates of both sexes (A mf < A mm and A ff < A fm). This is because, as men compete more often with non-relatives, the indirect cost of increased kin competition is lower when helping them than when helping women, for both sexes (fourth term in condition 3). Notice how, in this example, men competing more globally and women more locally leads to women helping groupmates more than men, but both sexes biasing their help more towards men than women in their group (Figures 1b and 2b). In addition, we find that – while higher numbers of reproductive women and men in a group depress relatedness and result in lower potentials for altruism – differences in the numbers of female and male breeders (N mN f) do not result in sex differences in potential for altruism (A mf/A mm and A ff/A fm are constants with respect to N m and N f; see Supporting Information).

Figure 2. Male-to-male, male-to-female, female-to-male and female-to-female altruism. Each pie chart shows potential for altruism by men towards male groupmates (dark blue) vs potential for altruism by men towards female groupmates (dark orange) vs potential for altruism by women towards male groupmates (light blue) vs potential for altruism by women towards female groupmates (light orange) and the sum of the four potentials (diameter of pie chart) – for low and high values of male and female dispersal rates (a), or for low and high values of male and female scale of competition (b). Other parameter values: (a, b) N m = N f = 3, a = 0.5, ω = 0.5; (a) σ m = σ f = 0.4 leading to M m = M f = 0.24 and α m = α f = 0.88; (b) m m = m f = 0.1, σ i = 0.4 leading to M i = 0.24 (for α i = 0.88) and σ i = 0.2 leading to M i = 0.16 (for α i = 0.96).

Moreover, we find that the effects of sex biases in dispersal and the scale of competition – the two key modulators of altruism identified above – may reinforce each other or act in different directions, influencing both who helps and who receives help. Where these two forces act in different directions, who helps more and who receives more help may depend on the exact combination of demographic parameter values (see Supporting Information). It is nonetheless possible to identify four broad patterns of sex-specific altruism. If dispersal is strongly female-biased, men are more altruistic and also receive more help than women, independently of sex differences in the scale of competition. The same configuration is obtained with a moderate male bias in dispersal and men competing more globally. Societies with these demographies follow a ‘boys’ club’ or ‘men help men’ system, where altruism is mostly by and for men. Conversely, if dispersal is strongly male-biased, women are more altruistic and also receive more help than men, again independently of sex differences in the scale of competition. The same pattern is obtained with a moderate male bias in dispersal and women being the more globally competing sex. Societies with these demographies follow a ‘girls’ club’ or ‘women help women’ system, where altruism is mainly a female affair. In the other two configurations the sexes of the predominant helper and helped differ. Women are more altruistic than men, but men receive more altruism when dispersal is moderately male-biased or unbiased, and when men compete more globally (‘women help men’ societies). Instead, men are more altruistic than women, but women receive more altruism when dispersal is unbiased or moderately female-biased, and when women compete more globally (‘men help women’ societies; see Figure 3).

Figure 3. Patterns of altruism as a function of dispersal and the scale of competition. Each pie chart shows potential for altruism by men towards male groupmates (dark blue) vs potential for altruism by men towards female groupmates (dark orange) vs potential for altruism by women towards male groupmates (light blue) vs potential for altruism by women towards female groupmates (light orange) and the sum of the four potentials (diameter of pie chart) – for different combinations of male and female dispersal rates and male and female scale of competition coefficients. Other parameter values: N m = N f = 3, a = 0.5, ω = 0.5, σ m = 0.4 and σ f = 0.1 (‘men compete more globally’, M m = 0.24, M f = 0.09, α m = 0.94 and α f = 0.9775), σ m = 0.1 and σ f = 0.4 (‘men compete more globally’, M m = 0.09, M f = 0.24, α m = 0.9775 and α f = 0.94), m m = 0.1 and m f = 0.8 (‘strong female bias’), m m = 0.1 and m f = 0.2 (‘moderate female bias’), m m = 0.1 and m f = 0.1 (‘no bias’), m m = 0.2 and m f = 0.1 (‘moderate male bias’), m m = 0.8 and m f = 0.1 (‘strong male bias’).

Discussion

Recent years have seen great interest in the possible coevolution of between-group violence and within-group altruism, but the potential for warfare – via its impact on demography – to influence human social behaviours more widely and in sex-specific ways has been neglected. Here we performed an inclusive fitness analysis to determine how selection acts on altruistic behaviours performed by men and women – either for the benefit of all groupmates or targeted at males or females specifically – in populations experiencing intergroup conflict. We found that warfare can promote within-group altruism, even if this altruism does not improve the group's performance in war. Furthermore, we found that the degree of altruism may crucially depend upon the sex of the altruist and the recipient, and upon two sex-specific demographic parameters: dispersal and the scale of competition.

Our analysis has revealed that warfare – through its effect on demography – can promote altruism, broadly defined (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1964; West et al. Reference West, Griffin and Gardner2007). This is because, as a result of intergroup conflict, individuals from victorious groups compete for reproductive opportunities with non-relatives in defeated groups to some extent and, in this way, decrease harmful competition between kin that would have otherwise inhibited the evolution of altruism. This result contributes to clarifying the role of demography in promoting cooperation and altruism. In a much-celebrated paper, Taylor (Reference Taylor1992) showed that, in a population subdivided into groups with limited dispersal, altruism could not spread, because the benefit obtained by helping groupmates was exactly cancelled by the kin competition cost generated by these behaviours (see also Frank Reference Frank1985, Reference Frank1986a, Reference Frankb; Bulmer Reference Bulmer1986 for an earlier, analogous result for sex allocation). Subsequent work showed that a number of mechanisms could lead to the decoupling of the effects of dispersal on relatedness and kin competition, allowing for the evolution of altruism (reviewed in Lehmann and Rousset Reference Lehmann and Rousset2010). One such avenue involves individuals dispersing together with other groupmates, a mode of migration first discussed by Haldane (Reference Haldane1932) in his classic ‘tribe splitting’ model of altruism and now termed ‘budding dispersal’ (Gardner and West Reference Gardner and West2006; see also Goodnight Reference Goodnight1992). In this way, members of a group can be competing for resources with non-relatives to some extent – reducing kin competition – while staying in close proximity to their kin – maintaining high relatedness (Gardner and West Reference Gardner and West2006; Lehmann et al. Reference Lehmann, Perrin and Rousset2006).

In Lehmann and Feldman's (Reference Lehmann and Feldman2008) model of warfare, intergroup conflict allows for the decoupling of relatedness and competition: when a group is defeated in war, winning males compete for reproductive opportunities with losers, thus maintaining relatedness at a high level while reducing kin competition. This mechanism is distinct from budding dispersal as previously described – because competition involves a mix of individuals from two different groups rather than occurring between buds – but presents a strong analogy with it – as movement to other groups occurs in association with groupmates rather than individually. Owing to this demographic effect of warfare, natural selection can favour men to express costly altruistic belligerence and bravery behaviours that increase the group's probability of engaging in and winning a war (Lehmann and Feldman Reference Lehmann and Feldman2008). Here, we showed that this insight holds for all altruistic behaviours expressed by either men or women – not only those that directly impact on a group's success in warfare and are expressed exclusively by men. In this respect, our result also illuminates Haldane's (Reference Haldane1932) insight that within-group altruism could only have evolved genetically in early human societies if groups were small and composed of related individuals – a combination that, he argued, could have only been achieved by human groups splitting periodically. Our analysis suggests that warfare, with the movement of individuals to defeated groups after victory, offers a mechanism for this splitting to occur. In this way, related individuals, who are more likely to carry genes encoding a given altruistic behaviour, continue to be in close proximity to each other generation after generation – and altruism has the possibility to spread.

Moreover, we showed that sex biases in two factors in the demography of warfare – dispersal and the scale of competition – may drive sex-specific patterns of altruism. Firstly, we found that the sex that disperses less is favoured both to be more altruistic and to receive more altruism. It is important to underline that, following Lehmann and Feldman (Reference Lehmann and Feldman2008) and Micheletti et al. (Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2017, Reference Micheletti, Ruxton and Gardner2018), we have assumed that altruistic behaviours are performed after dispersal (the same assumption is made in other studies investigating the dispersal–altruism interplay outside the context of warfare; e.g. Johnstone and Cant Reference Johnstone and Cant2008). This means that members of the more philopatric sex are more related to their groupmates, but do not experience higher local competition. If, instead, altruistic behaviours were performed before dispersal, then members of the less-dispersing sex would experience relatively higher local competition – which could possibly outweigh the benefits of being altruistic towards highly related groupmates. Our major qualitative results about sex-biases in altruism would still hold in this case, although overall the benefits of altruism would need to be higher for the behaviour to be selected.

Secondly, we revealed that sex differences in patterns of altruism can be driven by biases in the scale of competition, that is the extent to which men and women from victorious groups compete with non-relatives in defeated groups. Specifically, the sex that competes more locally is favoured to be more altruistic, whereas the sex that competes more globally is favoured to receive more altruism, from members of both sexes. For example, consider a scenario in which most men in a defeated group are excluded from competing for reproduction by winning men, while both winning and defeated women compete for marriage and resources in that group. In this case, warfare results in competition being relatively more global for women than for men. Under these conditions, men are favoured to be more altruistic than women, because they have more to gain by reducing kin competition within their sex through altruism. At the same time, both sexes are favoured to behave more altruistically towards women. This is because, although altruism can improve the competitiveness of both female and male groupmates, the altruist's male groupmates tend to compete for reproductive opportunities against each other (such that one male relative's gain is another male relative's loss). On the other hand, the altruist's female groupmates are more likely to compete for reproductive opportunities against unrelated individuals in other social groups. For this reason, the returns in terms of inclusive fitness benefits are higher when helping the sex that competes more globally.

Our aim has been to capture how demography modulates sex-specific altruism in populations experiencing warfare. To this end, we have focused on the roles of dispersal and the scale of competition, whilst assuming that both sexes are equally capable of helping, that is they experience the same costs and provide the same benefits to their recipients. However, if the sexes did differ in the costs and benefits of altruism, then this – fairly trivially – would be expected to drive sex differences in their altruistic behaviour. For example, if one sex were less effective in helping – i.e. providing a lower benefit – this would lead to a higher cost-to-benefit ratio and thus a lower level of altruism than for the more effective sex. If instead the two sexes were equally effective in helping, but one incurred lower costs associated with it, this would lead to a lower cost-to-benefit ratio and thus a higher level of altruism than for the sex experiencing more substantial costs. In addition, we have not considered altruism that is targeted at specific individuals on the basis of kin recognition, which is likely to be an important modulator of human social behaviour. Incorporating kin recognition need not affect the overall level of altruism enacted and received by each sex (GS Faria and A Gardner, ‘Does kin discrimination promote cooperation?’, under review), but would enable investigation of individual-level variation in addition to the between-sex and between-population variation that we have considered in the present analysis.

Furthermore, we found that the effects of sex biases in dispersal and competition can reinforce each other or act in opposing directions, resulting in four broad patterns of sex-specific altruism which we term ‘boys’ club’, ‘women help men’, ‘men help women’ and ‘girls’ club’ (summarised in Figure 3). However, which of these patterns can we expect to find in current human populations? We suggest that two different timescales can be potentially relevant, and we explore them in turn.

It might be that demographic asymmetries need to persist for very long times – on the order of millions of years – to have an influence on patterns of sex-specific altruism. This would be the case if the traits under consideration were genetically inherited, or if we were considering genetic components contributing to them. In this circumstance, the demographic patterns relevant for our study would be those of ancestral human populations. Sex-biased dispersal in ancestral humans has been greatly debated in recent years (see Box 1). If, as some argue (Ember Reference Ember1975, Reference Ember1978; Manson and Wrangham Reference Manson and Wrangham1991; Seielstad et al. Reference Seielstad, Minch and Cavalli-Sforza1998; Chapais Reference Chapais2008), female-biased dispersal was dominant early in our evolutionary history and persisted rather uniformly until recently, then we would expect to find the altruism patterns revealed by our model under this dispersal regime. For example, had this migration pattern been accompanied by men competing more globally because of warfare, this would have led to ‘boys’ club’ systems where men both helped more and received more help. If instead, as others suggest (Marlowe Reference Marlowe2004; Wilkins and Marlowe Reference Wilkins and Marlowe2006; Hill et al. Reference Hill2011; Sugiyama Reference Sugiyama2017), dispersal was unbiased in ancestral human populations, then – with respect to genetic components – we would expect no sex differences in altruism.

Box 1. Sex-specific dispersal in ancestral humans

Recent years have witnessed a heated debate surrounding patterns of sex biased dispersal in ancestral human populations, living a hunter-gatherer lifestyle in the Pleistocene (Marlowe, Reference Marlowe2004; Wilkins and Marlowe, Reference Wilkins and Marlowe2006; Sugiyama, Reference Sugiyama2017). Here, we summarise the current state of the evidence.

Firstly, extant great apes – chimpanzees and bonobos, our closest living relatives, and gorillas – are all characterised by female-biased dispersal (Lawson Handley and Perrin Reference Lawson Handley and Perrin2007), which has led some to argue that ancestral humans too are likely to have followed this pattern (e.g. Manson and Wrangham Reference Manson and Wrangham1991; Chapais Reference Chapais2008; but see Sugiyama Reference Sugiyama2017). Secondly, population genetics studies have examined variation in mitochondrial DNA (maternally inherited) and the non-recombining region of the Y-chromosome (paternally inherited), offering contrasting dispersal estimates. In two global comparisons, Seielstad et al. (Reference Seielstad, Minch and Cavalli-Sforza1998) found evidence of higher female dispersal, but Wilder et al. (Reference Wilder, Kingan, Mobasher, Pilkington and Hammer2004) found no such bias. Wilkins and Marlowe (Reference Wilkins and Marlowe2006) argue that these results stem from differences in the sampling scheme adopted, with the study finding unbiased dispersal being more reflective of pre-agricultural societies and the study finding a female bias capturing residential patterns that emerged after the spread of agriculture. Thirdly, dispersal in extant hunter-gatherers can be informative as these societies are considered the best available models for pre-agricultural populations (Marlowe, Reference Marlowe2005). Hunter-gatherer societies have long been characterised as mostly patrilocal (i.e. women moving to the husband's group; Ember Reference Ember1975, Reference Ember1978; Foley Reference Foley1995). However, recent work has shown that hunter-gatherers move frequently between bands and spouses can move to either the husband's or the wife's band: a system best described as ‘multilocal’ or ‘bilocal’ (Marlowe Reference Marlowe2004; Hill et al. Reference Hill2011). However, this does not mean that dispersal is necessarily unbiased. For example, in a study of 32 extant hunter-gather societies, Hill et al. (Reference Hill2011) found more co-residing brothers than sisters in 17 societies, the opposite pattern in three societies, and no bias in the remaining 12.

Overall, notwithstanding the great developments in these three research avenues, it is still unclear what pattern of dispersal was followed by our Pleistocene ancestors. It is possible that dispersal was on average female-biased throughout our history, becoming more pronounced with the advent of agriculture. Alternatively, it may have been unbiased during the Pleistocene and became female-biased after the agricultural revolution, in association with patrilocal residence rules.

On the other hand, it might be that more recent changes in patterns of dispersal – on the order of centuries or millennia – can result in differences in sex-specific altruism between populations. This would be the case if the altruistic traits under investigation were culturally inherited, or if we were considering culturally inherited contributors to such behaviours. Notice that, since our model identifies men's and women's inclusive fitness interests, our qualitative predictions as to sex differences in altruistic behaviours would still be relevant if the traits under question were cultural variants selected on the basis of their effects on the biological fitness of their carrier (‘type-1 cultural selection’, Birch Reference Birch2017; see also Mace Reference Mace2014). Therefore, in such a case, we would expect societies with different post-marital residence rules – cultural norms mediating dispersal in humans that can change relatively rapidly (Jordan et al. Reference Jordan, Gray, Greenhill and Mace2009; Opie et al. Reference Opie, Shultz, Atkinson, Currie and Mace2014; Ji et al. Reference Ji, Zheng, He, Wu, Mace and Tao2016) – to show the patterns predicted by our model for the corresponding sex biases in dispersal.

In any of these two cases, empirical studies investigating sex differences in cooperation could offer some support for the results of our study. The potential for such differences has been studied extensively employing economic games in the laboratory, with contrasting results: one metanalysis revealed that interactions between men are more cooperative than interactions between women (Balliet et al. Reference Balliet, Wu and De Dreu2011), whereas another found that women are more cooperative than men (Engel Reference Engel2011). However, these studies – performed almost exclusively with WEIRD (western, educated, industrialised, rich, and democratic; Henrich et al. Reference Henrich, Heine and Norenzayan2010) participants – do not consider ecological variables and thus cannot illuminate the role of demographic effects on altruism. Instead, our predictions are best tested in the field, specifically in small-scale societies that vary in dispersal patterns and that currently engage in – or have a recent history of – intergroup conflict.

Two studies investigating cooperation in agro-pastoral societies in South-Western China with economic games (Gong et al. Reference Gong, Yan and Yang2015; Wu et al. Reference Wu, Ting, He, Du and Mace2015) might offer some support for the demographic effects identified in our model. These societies – Pumi, Han, Yi, Amdo, Khampa, Mosuo and Zhaba – share similar ecologies while differing substantially in post-marital residence rules, the cultural norms regulating dispersal in human societies (Jordan et al. Reference Jordan, Gray, Greenhill and Mace2009). In addition, blood feuds and cattle raiding are now very much limited by state policing but were common in most of these groups until recently (Cai Reference Cai2001; Yeh Reference Yeh2003; Pirie Reference Pirie2005; Harrell Reference Harrell2011; Shi Reference Shi2018) and it is reasonable that they might still influence cultural norms and actual behaviour. Wu et al. (Reference Wu, Ting, He, Du and Mace2015) showed that men are more cooperative and/or altruistic than women in both duolocal (neither sex migrates, unbiased dispersal) and patrilocal (female-biased dispersal) populations. At the same time, they found lower levels of cooperation when more men than women participate in the games (Wu et al. Reference Wu, Ting, He, Du and Mace2015), which might indicate that both sexes are more incentivised to be altruistic towards women than towards men. Our results suggest that this pattern might have been driven by warfare: men being more altruistic and women receiving more altruism is the outcome we obtain under unbiased or moderately female-biased dispersal – as observed in these societies – and with women competing more globally than men as a result of war (‘men help women’, see Figure 3). To our knowledge, patterns of post-war competition in defeated groups are unknown for these societies, but could be possibly inferred from oral reports and historical documents regarding intergroup conflict (an example of how greater female competition might be realised as a result of war is discussed above).

Moreover, Gong et al. (Reference Gong, Yan and Yang2015) found that duolocal Mosuo men give more than women in the Dictator game, and they also give more than patrilocal Yi men. Given that these societies show unbiased or moderately female-biased dispersal, these results might again be in line with our ‘men help women’ configuration (Figure 3), but the study does not test for the effect of receiver's sex. Furthermore, the finding that altruistic giving is lower in patrilocal populations (Gong et al. Reference Gong, Yan and Yang2015), might result from higher dispersal rates in these groups leading to lower relatedness – as predicted by our model. Interestingly, Wu et al. (Reference Wu, Ting, He, Du and Mace2015) found the opposite pattern: higher dispersal societies show more altruism. Additional work, both theoretical and empirical, is clearly needed to disentangle the effects of dispersal on relatedness and kin competition and determine how the two might interact to influence social behaviours in human populations. Elucidating demographic factors – and the within-group or between-group processes influencing it, including warfare – promises to be a fruitful avenue.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2020.5.

Acknowledgements

We thank Nathan Bailey, Gonçalo Faria, Laura Fortunato, Mauricio González-Forero, Thomas Hitchcock, Jasmeen Kanwal, Ruth Mace, Petri Rautiala, Jonathan Stieglitz, Cameron Turner, Michael Wilson, Jia-Jia Wu and attendees of the Friday Lab Chat, School of Biology, University of St Andrews, of the IAST Tuesday Seminar, and of the MMEE 2019 conference, and two anonymous referees for useful comments and discussion. A.J.C.M. thanks the HKU Library for providing him with a stimulating working space during summer 2019.

Author contributions

A.J.C.M., G.D.R. and A.G. designed the study and wrote the manuscript; A.J.C.M. led the mathematical analysis.

Financial support

Funding from a PhD studentship from the School of Biology, University of St Andrews (A.J.C.M.), a Natural Environment Research Council Independent Research Fellowship (A.G., grant number NE/K009524/1), a European Research Council Consolidator Grant (A.G., A.J.C.M., grant number 771387) and the French Agence Nationale de la Recherche (under the Investissement d'Avenir programme, ANR 17-EURE-0010) (A.J.C.M.) is gratefully acknowledged.

Publishing ethics

The manuscript is our own original work, and does not duplicate any other previously published work. The manuscript has been submitted only to the journal – it is not under consideration, accepted for publication or in press elsewhere. All listed authors know of and agree to the manuscript being submitted to the journal. The manuscript contains nothing that is abusive, defamatory, fraudulent, illegal, libellous or obscene.

Conflict of interest

None.

References

Balliet, D, Wu, J and De Dreu, CKW (2011) Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: a meta-analysis. Psychology Bulletin 140, 15561581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauer, M, Blattman, C, Chytilová, J, Henrich, J, Miguel, E and Mitts, T (2016) Can war foster cooperation? Journal of Economic Perspectives 30, 249274CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birch, J (2017) The Philosophy of Social Evolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S (2006) Group competition, reproductive levelling, and the evolution of human altruism. Science 314, 15691572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S (2009) Did warfare among ancestral hunter-gatherers affect the evolution of human social behaviour? Science 324, 293298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bulmer, MG (1986) Sex ratio theory in geographically structured populations. Heredity 56, 6973.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cai, H (2001) A Society without Fathers or Husbands: The Na of China. Cambridge, MA: Zone Books.Google Scholar
Chapais, B (2008) Primeval Kinship. How Pair-Bonding Gave Birth to Human Society. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Choi, JK and Bowles, S (2007) The coevolution of parochial altruism and war. Science 318, 636640.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Darwin, C (1871) The Descent of Man, and Selection in Relation to Sex. London: John MurrayGoogle Scholar
Doğan, G, Glowacki, L and Rusch, H (2018) Spoils division rules shape aggression between natural groups. Nature Human Behaviour 2, 322326.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ember, CR (1975) Residential variation among hunter-gatherers. Cross-Cultural Research 10, 199227.Google Scholar
Ember, CR (1978) Myths about hunter-gatherers. Ethnology 17, 439448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, C (2011) Dictator games: a meta study. Experimental Economics, 14, 583610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foley, R (1995) The adaptive legacy of human evolution: a search or the environment of evolutionary adaptedness. Evolutionary Anthropology 4, 194203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, SA (1985) Hierarchical selection theory and sex ratios. II. On applying the theory, and a test with fig wasps. Evolution 39, 949964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, SA (1986a) Hierarchical selection theory and sex ratios. I. General solutions for structured populations. Theoretical Population Biology 29, 312342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, SA (1986b) The genetic value of sons and daughters. Heredity 56, 351354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, SA (1997) Multivariate analysis of correlated selection and kin selection, with an ESS maximisation method. Journal of Theoretical Biology 189, 307316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, SA (1998) Foundations of Social Evolution. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fry, DP (ed.) (2013) War, Peace, and Human Nature: The Convergence of Evolutionary and Cultural Views. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garcia, J and van der Bergh, JCJM (2011) Evolution of parochial altruism by multilevel selection. Evolutionary Human Behaviour 32, 277287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardner, A (2010) Sex-biased dispersal of adults mediates the evolution of altruism among juveniles. Journal of Theoretical Biology 262, 339345.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gardner, A and West, SA (2006) Demography, altruism, and the benefits of budding. Journal of Evolutionary Biology 19(5), 17071716.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Glowacki, L, Wilson, ML and Wrangham, RW (2017) The evolutionary anthropology of war. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. In press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, A and Fessler, DMT (2011) Conflict, sticks and carrots: war increases prosocial punishments and rewards. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 279, 219223.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gong, B, Yan, H and Yang, C-L (2015) Gender differences in the dictator experiment: evidence from the matrilineal Mosuo and the patriarchal Yi. Experimental Economics 18, 302313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodnight, KF (1992) The effect of stochastic variation on kin selection in a budding-viscous population. American Nature 140, 10281040.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haldane, JBS (1932) The Causes of Evolution. London: Longmans, Green.Google Scholar
Hamilton, WD (1964) The genetical evolution of social behaviour. Journal of Theoretical Biology 7, 152.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harrell, S (2011) Cultural Encounters on China's Ethnic Frontiers. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press.Google Scholar
Henrich, J, Heine, SJ and Norenzayan, A (2010) The weirdest people in the world? Behavioral Brain Science 33, 6183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, KR. et al. (2011) Co-residence patterns in hunter-gatherer societies show unique human social structure. Science 331, 12861289.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ji, T, Zheng, X-D, He, Q-Q, Wu, J-J, Mace, R and Tao, Y (2016) Kinship as a frequency-dependent strategy. Royal Society Open Science 3, 150632.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Johnson, DDP, McDermott, R, Barrett, ES, Crowden, J, Wrangham, R, McIntyre, MH and Rosen, SP (2006) Overconfidence in war games: experimental evidence on expectations, aggression, gender and testosterone. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 273, 25132520.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Johnstone, RA and Cant, MA (2008) Sex differences in dispersal and the evolution of helping and harming. American Nature 172, 318330.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jordan, FM, Gray, RD, Greenhill, SJ and Mace, R (2009) Matrilocal residence is ancestral in Austronesian societies. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 276, 19571964.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lawson Handley, LJ and Perrin, N (2007) Advances in our understanding of mammalian sex-biased dispersal. Molecular Ecology 16, 15591578.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lehmann, L and Feldman, MW (2008) War and the evolution of belligerence and bravery. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 275, 28772885.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lehmann, L and Rousset, F (2010) How life history and demography promote or inhibit the evolution of helping behaviours. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B 365, 25992617.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lehmann, L, Perrin, N and Rousset, F (2006) Population demography and the evolution of helping behaviours. Evolution 60(6), 11371151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Low, BS (2015) Why Sex Matters. A Darwinian Look at Human Behaviour, revised edn. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Mace, R (2014) Human behavioural ecology and its evil twin. Behavioral Ecology 25, 443449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manson, JH and Wrangham, RW (1991) Intergroup aggression in chimpanzees and humans. Current Anthropology 32, 369390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marlowe, FW (2004) Marital residence among foragers. Current Anthropology 45, 277284CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marlowe, FW (2005) Hunter-gatherers and human evolution. Evolutionary Anthropology 14, 5467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mathew, S and Boyd, R (2011) Punishment sustains large-scale cooperation in prestate warfare Proceedings of the National Academy of Science USA 108, 1137511380.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Maynard Smith, J (1964) Group selection and kin selection. Nature, 201, 11451147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, MM, Navarrete, CD and van Vugt, M (2012) Evolution and the psychology of intergroup conflict: the male warrior hypothesis. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B 367, 670679.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Micheletti, AJC, Ruxton, GD and Gardner, A (2017) Intrafamily and intragenomic conflicts in human warfare. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 284, 20162699.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Micheletti, AJC, Ruxton, GD and Gardner, A (2018) Why war is a man's game. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 285, 20180975.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Nettle, D, Gibson, MA, Lawson, DW and Sear, R (2013) Human behavioral ecology: current research and future prospects. Behavioral Ecology 24, 10311040.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Opie, C, Shultz, S, Atkinson, QD, Currie, T and Mace, R (2014) Phylogenetic reconstruction of Bantu kinship challenges Main Sequence Theory of human social evolution. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science USA 11, 1741417419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pirie, F (2005) Segmentation within the state: the reconfiguration of Tibetan tribes in China's reform period. Nomadic Peoples 9, 83102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romano, A, Balliet, D, Yamagishi, T and Liu, JH (2017) Parochial trust and cooperation across 17 societies. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science USA 114, 1270212707.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rousset, F (2004) Genetic Structure and Selection in Subdivided Populations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rusch, H (2014) The evolutionary interplay of intergroup conflicts and altruism in humans: a review of parochial altruism theory and prospect for its extension. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 281, 20141539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rusch, H, Bohm, R and Herrmann, B (2016) Editorial: Parochial altruism: pitfalls and prospects. Frontiers in Psychology 7, 1004.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schaub, M (2017) Threat and parochialism in intergroup relations: lab-in-the-field evidence from rural Georgia. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 284, 20171560.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Seielstad, MT, Minch, E and Cavalli-Sforza, LL (1998) Genetic evidence for a higher female migration in humans. Nature Genetics 20, 278280.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Servedio, MR, Brandvain, Y, Dhole, S, Fitzpatrick, CL, Goldberg, EE, Stern, CA, Van Cleve, J and Yeh, DJ (2014) Not just a theory – the utility of mathematical models in evolutionary biology. PLoS Biology e1002017.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shi, S (2018) Ethnic flows in the Tibetan–Yi corridor throughout history. International Journal of Anthropology and Ethnology 2. https://link.springer.com/article/10.1186/s41257-018-0009-z#citeasCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silva, AS and Mace, R (2014) Cooperation and conflict: field experiments in Northern Ireland. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 281, 20141435.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sugiyama, Y (2017) Sex-biased dispersal of human ancestors. Evolutionary Anthropology 26, 172180.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Taylor, PD (1992) Altruism in viscous populations – an inclusive fitness model. Evolutionary Ecology 6, 352356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, PD (1996) Inclusive fitness arguments in genetic models of behaviour. Journal of Mathematical Biology 34, 654674.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Taylor, PD and Frank, SA (1996) How to make a kin selection model. Journal of Theoretical Biology 180, 2737.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Taylor, PD, Wild, G and Gardner, A (2007) Direct fitness or inclusive fitness: how shall we model kin selection? Journal of Evolutionary Biology 20, 296304.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Turchin, P (2015) Ultrasociety: How 10,000 Years of War Made Humans the Greatest Cooperators on Earth. Chaplin, CT: Beresta Books.Google Scholar
van Vugt, M (2009) Sex differences in intergroup competition, aggression, and warfare. The male warrior hypothesis. Annals of the NY Academy of Science 1167, 124134.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
van Vugt, M, De Cremer, D and Janssen, DP (2006) Gender differences in cooperation and competition. The male-warrior hypothesis. Psychological Sciences 18, 1923.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, SA, Griffin, AS and Gardner, A (2007) Social semantics: altruism, cooperation, mutualism, strong reciprocity and group selection. Journal of Evolutionary Biology 20, 415432.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wilder, JA, Kingan, SB, Mobasher, Z, Pilkington, MM and Hammer, MF (2004) Global patterns of human mitochondrial DNA and Y-chromosome structure are not influenced by higher migration rates of females versus males. Nature Genetics 36, 11221125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilkins, JF and Marlowe, FW (2006) Sex-biased migration in humans: what should we expect from genetic data? BioEssays, 28, 290300.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wright, S (1931) Evolution in Mendelian populations. Genetics 16, 97159.Google ScholarPubMed
Wu, J-J, Ting, J, He, Q-Q, Du, J and Mace, R (2015) Cooperation is related to dispersal patterns in Sino-Tibetan populations. Nature Communication 6, 8693.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Yeh, ET (2003) Tibetan Range Wars: spatial politics and authority on the grasslands of Amdo. Developmental Change 34(3), 499523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Male and female altruism towards groupmates of either sex. Each pie chart shows potential for altruism by men towards groupmates (purple) vs potential for altruism by women towards groupmates (brown) and the sum of the two potentials (diameter of pie chart) – for low and high values of male and female dispersal rates (a), or for low and high values of male and female scale of competition (b). Other parameter values: (a and b) Nm = Nf = 3, a = 0.5, ω = 0.5; (a) σm = σf = 0.4 leading to Mm = Mf = 0.24 and αm = αf = 0.88; (b) mm = mf = 0.1, σi = 0.4 leading Mi = 0.24 (for αi = 0.88) and σi = 0.2 leading Mi = 0.16 (for αi = 0.96).

Figure 1

Figure 2. Male-to-male, male-to-female, female-to-male and female-to-female altruism. Each pie chart shows potential for altruism by men towards male groupmates (dark blue) vs potential for altruism by men towards female groupmates (dark orange) vs potential for altruism by women towards male groupmates (light blue) vs potential for altruism by women towards female groupmates (light orange) and the sum of the four potentials (diameter of pie chart) – for low and high values of male and female dispersal rates (a), or for low and high values of male and female scale of competition (b). Other parameter values: (a, b) Nm = Nf = 3, a = 0.5, ω = 0.5; (a) σm = σf = 0.4 leading to Mm = Mf = 0.24 and αm = αf = 0.88; (b) mm = mf = 0.1, σi = 0.4 leading to Mi = 0.24 (for αi = 0.88) and σi = 0.2 leading to Mi = 0.16 (for αi = 0.96).

Figure 2

Figure 3. Patterns of altruism as a function of dispersal and the scale of competition. Each pie chart shows potential for altruism by men towards male groupmates (dark blue) vs potential for altruism by men towards female groupmates (dark orange) vs potential for altruism by women towards male groupmates (light blue) vs potential for altruism by women towards female groupmates (light orange) and the sum of the four potentials (diameter of pie chart) – for different combinations of male and female dispersal rates and male and female scale of competition coefficients. Other parameter values: Nm = Nf = 3, a = 0.5, ω = 0.5, σm = 0.4 and σf = 0.1 (‘men compete more globally’, Mm = 0.24, Mf = 0.09, αm = 0.94 and αf = 0.9775), σm = 0.1 and σf = 0.4 (‘men compete more globally’, Mm = 0.09, Mf = 0.24, αm = 0.9775 and αf = 0.94), mm = 0.1 and mf = 0.8 (‘strong female bias’), mm = 0.1 and mf = 0.2 (‘moderate female bias’), mm = 0.1 and mf = 0.1 (‘no bias’), mm = 0.2 and mf = 0.1 (‘moderate male bias’), mm = 0.8 and mf = 0.1 (‘strong male bias’).

Supplementary material: PDF

Micheletti et al. supplementary material

Micheletti et al. supplementary material

Download Micheletti et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 273 KB