Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-8ctnn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T09:50:58.512Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - The Tax Effort

A Comparison between Sub-Saharan Africa and Benin

from Part II - A Deeper Investigation of Some Key Sectors and Institutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 November 2023

François Bourguignon
Affiliation:
École d'économie de Paris and École des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, Paris
Romain Houssa
Affiliation:
Université de Namur, Belgium
Jean-Philippe Platteau
Affiliation:
Université de Namur, Belgium
Paul Reding
Affiliation:
Université de Namur, Belgium

Summary

This chapter analyses the efforts by Benin and other sub-Saharan African countries to raise tax revenue, in regard to structural characteristics, and explores possible determinants of, and the scope for, greater domestic revenue mobilisation and for tax policy and administration reforms. First, the tax effort in Benin remained relatively stable in 1980–2015, but Benin performed poorer (14th) compared to its neighbour Togo (5th). Second, there is evidence of a positive effect of government transparency and accountability, ‘control of corruption’, and political stability on tax effort. On the contrary, foreign aid is associated with low tax effort. Third, several strategies are investigated to reduce the tax gaps in Benin. If the tax policy seems relatively constrained by reference to the West Africa Economic and Monetary Unions Tax Directives, the Togolese experiment of switching to a semi-autonomous revenue authority may provide guidance to find some room to improve domestic revenue mobilisation. In particular, Benin should review the management of human resources in the tax and customs administrations, and the scope of derogatory regimes that generate tax expenditures.

Type
Chapter
Information
State Capture and Rent-Seeking in Benin
The Institutional Diagnostic Project
, pp. 212 - 241
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

I Introduction

The 2015 Addis Ababa Conference highlighted the central role of domestic revenue mobilisation for financing development in the context of the Sustainable Development Goals. Improving tax revenue contributes not only to the financing of public spending, but also to reinforcing the accountability of the government (see Brautigam et al., Reference Brautigam, Fjeldstad and Moore2009).

With a tax revenue to gross domestic product (GDP) ratio equal to 13.5 per cent in 2017 (IMF, 2018),Footnote 1 Benin remains below the West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU) criterion of 20 per cent. Meanwhile, at the same date, Togo, a neighbouring country, managed to raise 18.3 per cent of its GDP in terms of tax revenue. Such a gap (between Benin and Togo) is not temporary, but seems to be lasting and has even increased in 2010–2015 (see Figures 6.1a and 6.1b).

Figure 6.1a Share tax over GDP

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Figure 6.1b Non-resource tax over GDP

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Both countries inherited the same tax law, the French Tax Code, when they gained their independence – on 1 August 1960 for Benin and on 27 April 1960 for Togo. Both countries belong to the same customs and monetary union, WAEMU. The WAEMU Commission has produced several tax Directives, covering the main taxes (corporate income tax, value-added tax, excises, etc.), which aims to bring about tax harmonisation or coordination among the eight member statesFootnote 2 (see Mansour and Rota-Graziosi, Reference Mansour and Rota-Graziosi2013). These Directives strictly limit any potential divergence of Beninese and Togolese tax laws after 1960. However, some discrepancy may still emerge not only in the enforcement of these tax laws by the tax and customs administrations, but also as a result of the scope of derogatory regimes (for instance, the Investment Code) that generate tax expenditures.Footnote 3

An important difference between Togo and Benin relates to the administrative side. In 2014, Togo transformed its tax and customs administrations into a single revenue authority (the Office Togolais des Recettes), while Benin has a more ‘classic’ organisation for French-speaking countries, with two separate administrations: tax and customs administrations.Footnote 4

First, using a database providing information on tax revenue over the period 1980–2015, covering forty-two sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries,Footnote 5 we analyse the efforts by Benin to raise tax revenue, as relates to its structural characteristics. The analysis aims to compare the non-resource tax-to-GDP ratio in Benin with its peers, to identify whether Benin is near to, or far away from, its tax frontier, before exploring possible scope for greater tax revenue raising and for tax policy and administration reforms.

We conclude that the tax effort in Benin has remained relatively stable during the period, with an average of 63.5 per cent of its total potential tax revenue over the period, ranked fourteenth out of forty-two countries. A tax effort of 63.5 per cent means that the level of non-resource tax revenue is at 36.5 per cent of the country’s maximum capacity. Knowing that, on average, Benin collects 11.45 per cent of its GDP in non-resource tax revenue and is at 63.5 per cent of its capacity, it would have raised 18.03 per cent of its GDP as non-resource tax revenue if it had used all its potential, given its characteristics. The estimated gap is higher than that estimated by Cui et al. (Reference Cui, Sola and Dieterich2016), which was 1.5–2 per cent of GDP based on a sample of SSA countries for the period 1995–2011.

The analysis identifies a higher tax effort in Togo, which exhibits a tax effort of 69.9 per cent on average and is ranked fifth out of forty-two countries. Togo would have mobilised 21.61 per cent of non-resource tax revenue as a percentage of GDP if it had made the maximum tax effort. This result appears intuitive. Indeed, Togo has a lower GDP per capita than Benin (US$6,280 for the former and US$6,480 for the latter) and its agricultural share is more important (35.73 per cent of GDP in Togo; 35.11 per cent in Benin). These characteristics penalise the mobilisation of non-resource tax. At the same time, Togo mobilises more non-resource tax revenues (15.11 per cent of GDP in Togo; 11.45 per cent in Benin). Hence, unfavourable characteristics of Togo, combined with its relative success in mobilising revenues, translate into a higher tax effort of Togo with respect to Benin.

Second, we study the effect of some economic and institutional variables on tax effort. While the calculation of the tax effort includes only structural supply factors of the tax pressure as inputs to the stochastic frontier analysis, we then study the effect of demand factors on the estimated level of tax effort.Footnote 6 Using a logistic regression, we study in particular the effect of the presence of natural resources, aid, transparency, corruption, and accountability, and the political regime and stability. We find that aid is associated with a lower probability of belonging to a quartile of high tax effort, while institutional quality – measured by the Country Policy and Institutional Assessment (CPIA) index – increases the probability of belonging to an efficient quartile in terms of tax effort. If the effect of the political system is not clear, political stability is strongly and positively associated with a greater likelihood of having a high tax effort.

Third, we analyse the potential policy and administrative sources of the tax gaps. We shed light in particular on the human resource policy of the tax administrationFootnote 7 and the remuneration mechanisms, which may be obsolete.

The chapter is structured as follows: Section II presents the tax effort estimation; Section III proposes an empirical study of the effect of some institutional and economic factors on the estimated tax effort scores; Section IV reviews some tax policy and tax administrative issues and proposes reforms, with a view to improving tax mobilisation; and Section V concludes.

II Empirical Estimation of Tax Effort in Benin: A Stochastic Frontier Analysis

We define tax effort as the extent to which the actual tax revenue collected is near the maximum level of tax resource that could be collected. In other words, tax effort in Benin is the extent to which Benin makes use of its potential for tax revenue regarding its tax base and its structural supply characteristics.

The empirical analysis is based on a sophisticated stochastic frontier analysis in which commonly used supply factors driving government tax revenue are considered as the inputs and the total non-resource tax revenue as the output (see Box 6.1). The rationale behind these methods is that an economic agent cannot exceed an ‘ideal frontier’, which is the optimal level of output, given the limited endowment of inputs. The tax frontier refers to the tax capacity, which represents the maximum tax revenue that a country could raise given its structural characteristics. The model used in the study by Kumbhakar et al. (Reference Kumbhakar, Lien and Hardaker2014) makes it possible to distinguish country effects, persistent inefficiency, and time-varying inefficiency. Hence, we control for country effects – which capture the effect of time-constant variables for each country – and obtain a total level of inefficiency that is the result of an identified persistent inefficiency and of a time-varying inefficiency for each country.

In the first stage of the estimation, countries’ tax ratio is regressed on a vector of structural explanatory variables. The calculation of the tax effort includes only structural supply factors of the tax pressure as inputs to the stochastic frontier analysis. Demand factors are excluded from the estimation of the tax effort: the impact of these factors on the level of tax effort is studied in the second part of the analysis. Based on the relevant literature on the determinants of government tax revenue, we introduce the following set of inputs in the stochastic frontier analysis:

  1. i. The level of development: Countries’ tax capacity is positively associated with the level of economic development (proxied by real GDP per capita), which is linked to the efficiency of tax administration, the degree of economic and institutional sophistication, and the demand for public goods and services (see Lotz and Morss, Reference Lotz and Morss1967; Tanzi, Reference Tanzi, Newbery and Stern1987; Pessino and Fenochietto, Reference Pessino and Fenochietto2010; Crivelli and Gupta, Reference Crivelli and Gupta2014).

  2. ii. Agriculture value-added (percentage of GDP): In addition to the numerous sectoral tax exemptions and tax holidays typically provided in developing countries, agriculture is often considered hard to tax in developing countries. Focusing on SSA countries, Stotsky and WoldeMariam (Reference Stotsky and WoldeMariam1997) emphasise that the share of value-added of this sector in GDP is negatively associated with tax revenue.

  3. iii. Trade openness: Trade liberalisation policies implemented in most developing countries in the early 1970s have substantially increased trade volume in these countries. Therefore, trade openness expressed as total trade (imports and exports) as a share of GDP is expected to influence tax revenue, in particular through household consumption and domestic corporate profits (Stotsky and WoldeMariam, Reference Stotsky and WoldeMariam1997; Pessino and Fenochietto, Reference Pessino and Fenochietto2010; Keen and Perry, Reference Keen and Perry2013, among others).

  4. iv. Financial development: High financial development combined with high access to credit allows individuals and firms to finance profitable projects, which favour tax collection (Gordon and Li, Reference Gordon and Li2009). On the other hand, in the presence of an ineffective financial system, firms can successfully evade tax payment by conducting business in cash, which is harder for tax administrations to monitor.

Table 6.1 displays the pairwise correlation between interest variables. As expected, all variables are positively associated with non-resource tax revenues, except the agriculture sector, which is significantly and negatively correlated with non-resource tax revenues. The detailed sources and definitions of variables are provided in the Appendix to this chapter (Table 6.A1).

Table 6.1 Pairwise correlation between interest variables

[1][2][3][4][5]
(1) Non-resource taxes (% GDP)1
(2) GDPPC (constant 2010 US$)0,51Footnote *1
(3) Total trade (% of GDP)0,43Footnote *0,63Footnote *1
(4) Agriculture, value-added (% GDP)−0,54Footnote *−0,62Footnote *−0,62Footnote *1
(5) Financial development index0,62Footnote *0,37Footnote *0,37Footnote *−0,59Footnote *1
Source: Authors’ calculations.

* Coefficient significant at 10% level. GDPPC, gross domestic product per capita.

Box 6.1 Estimation Strategy: Stochastic Frontier Analysis

An approach that is increasingly being used to capture countries’ tax effort is the stochastic frontier method, which was introduced in the seminal work of Aigner et al. (Reference Aigner, Lovell and Schmidt1977) to model firms’ production behaviour (see Pessino and Fenochietto, Reference Pessino and Fenochietto2010; Langford and Ohlenburg, 2015). The literature proposes several parametric and non-parametric models for stochastic frontier estimation. Data envelopment analysis (Charnes et al., Reference Charnes, Cooper, Lewin and Seiford2013) and the free disposal hull (Deprins et al., Reference Deprins, Simar, Tulkens, Marchand, Pestieau, Tulkens, Marchand, Pestieau and Tulkens1984) are the two main – and increasingly popular – methods used for non-parametric stochastic frontier models. The main disadvantage of such methods lies in the fact that the production function is more heavily influenced by outliers, and thus more vulnerable to measurement errors (Clements, Reference Clements2002).

We draw on a parametric model to estimate the tax effort as we are dealing with a single output (the total non-resource tax-to-GDP ratio). In panel data analysis, parametric models can be categorised into five groups: (1) time-invariant technical inefficiency models; (2) time-varying technical inefficiency models; (3) models that separate firm heterogeneity from inefficiency; (4) models distinguishing persistent and time-varying inefficiency; and (5) models separating firm effects, persistent inefficiency, and time-varying inefficiency. We use the model by Kumbhakar et al. (Reference Kumbhakar, Lien and Hardaker2014) that makes it possible to distinguish country effects, persistent inefficiency, and time-varying inefficiency. We estimate the following equation:

NRTAXi,t=α+Xi,t1β+ψi+ϕit(1)
whereϕit= ϵit ηi μitμit>0 ;  ηi>0(2)

The dependent variable NRTAXi,t (Equation 1) represents the natural logarithm of total non-resource tax revenue. The subscripts i and t and denote country and time dimensions, respectively. Xi,t1 is a vector of structural and institutional factors explaining countries’ tax ratios, which are one period lagged to mitigate endogeneity issues and to account for delays in their effect on non-resource tax revenue. Time-invariant country-level characteristics that could potentially affect government non-resource tax revenue are captured by ψi. The last term, ϕit, is a three-component error term (Equation 2) including time-invariant tax inefficiencies ηi (i.e. persistent tax inefficiencies owing, for instance, to sociological, cultural, religious, or geographical factors) and time-varying tax inefficiency μit (e.g. tax losses due to tax policy, tax administration, or tax officials’ qualifications, which can change over time). Thus, the model makes it possible to identify persistent and time-varying factors determining SSA countries’ tax effort.

The combination of Equation 1 and Equation 2 can be rewritten as follows:

NRTAXi,t=α0*+Xi,t1β+αi+ϑit(3)

with:

α0*=αEηiEμit(4)
αi= ψi ηi+ Eηi(5)
ϑit= ϵit μit+Eμit(6)

Equation 3 is then estimated following a three-stage procedure: (1) In stage 1, the β^ is estimated by performing a random-effect-based regression (Equation 3). This stage gives the predicted values α^i and ϑ^it of αiand ϑit, respectively. (2) In stage 2, the time-varying tax inefficiency, μit, is estimated using the predicted values α^i and ϑ^it from the first stage. To do this, Equation 6 is estimated by performing a standard stochastic frontier technique. Using Battese and Coelli’s (Reference Battese and Coelli1988) model, this procedure gives the prediction of the time-varying tax effort, expμit|ϑit; (3) Finally, in stage 3, the persistent tax inefficiency component ηi, is estimated by performing a stochastic frontier model on Equation 5 as in the previous stage. The persistent tax effort is then predicted and given by expηi. Hence, the overall tax effort is obtained by the product of the time-varying tax effort and the persistent tax effort.

Table 6.2 presents the summary statistics for the full sample and for Benin and Togo. Benin is generally below the mean for the full sample (except for the agriculture share). It is slightly above the average of its income group, the low-income countries. Benin and Togo have very similar characteristics. As we noted, however, the ratios of tax and non-resource tax over GDP are higher on average in Togo than in Benin (Figure 6.1), while Benin has a higher GDP per capita and a lower agriculture share, which should facilitate tax revenue mobilisation. Although Togo has a higher trade openness and a better financial development index, this is not sufficient to explain the far higher tax over GDP ratio for Togo relative to Benin. While Benin’s performance is growing relatively steadily, Togo’s performance is more unstable. Except over the period 1992–2002, the ratios of tax and non-resource tax over GDP have been lower in Benin than in Togo (for more details see Caldeira and Rota-Graziosi, Reference Caldeira, Rota-Graziosi, Bourguignon, Houssa, Platteau and Reding2019).

Table 6.2 Descriptive statistics

VariableMeanStandard deviation (SD)MedianMinMax
Full sample
Total taxes (% GDP)16.198.9713.790.5753.33
Non-resource taxes (% GDP)12.466.6711.140.5549.85
GDPPC (constant 2010 US$)6.921.066.684.8710.16
Agriculture, value-added (% GDP)27.6415.7429.140.8972.03
Total trade (% of GDP)73.9747.0760.986.32531.74
Financial development index0.110.080.100.000.64
Benin
Total taxes (% GDP)11.922.5712.456.7616.04
Non-resource taxes (% GDP)11.462.2912.026.3614.96
GDPPC (constant 2010 US$)6.500.096.486.366.70
Agriculture, value-added (% GDP)35.111.9231.9231.5439.01
Total trade (% of GDP)55.378.0056.2438.3076.53
Financial development index0.090.010.090.070.11
Togo
Total taxes (% GDP)16.895.9615.287.7130.15
Non-resource taxes (% GDP)15.114.5715.076.2726.17
GDPPC (constant 2010 US$)6.260.096.266.016.53
Agriculture, value-added (% GDP)35.734.2235.2026.9644.14
Total trade (% of GDP)90.2215.6192.3256.48125.03
Financial development index0.100.010.100.070.12
Source: Authors’ calculations.

Table 6.3 presents the three-stage estimation results. The first-stage estimation involves regressing countries’ tax ratio on a vector of explanatory variables. All variables have the expected sign and are strongly significant at the 1 per cent level: per capita real GDP, trade openness, and financial development are positively associated, while the share of the agriculture sector is negatively and significantly correlated with non-resource tax revenues (Table 6.3 A). The level of development measured by the per capita real GDP has a significant effect on countries’ non-resource tax ratio: a 1 per cent increase in real GDP per capita is associated with a 0.243 percentage point increase in non-resource tax revenue.

Table 6.3 Three-stage estimates of the tax effort in sub-Saharan African countries

(A) First-stage random-effect estimates
Dependent variable[1]
NRTAX
[3]
CIT
[4]
PIT
[5]
Goods and services
Log GDPPC(–1) (constant 2010 US$)0.235***(0.0331)0.457***0.240***0.202***
(0.0361)(0.0552)(0.0565)(0.0725)
Agriculture, value-added(–1) (% of GDP)–0.056***(0.0141)0.406***0.456***0.141*
(0.0420)(0.0625)(0.0682)(0.0847)
Total trade(–1) (% of GDP)0.018***(0.0042)−0.0128−0.440***−1.018***
(0.0121)(0.0137)(0.0173)
Financial development(–1)0.526***(0.1238)−0.0827***−0.142***0.0274
(0.133)(0.199)(0.223)(0.269)
Constant0.622***(0.247)−4.452***−2.260***1.028
(0.405)(0.580)(0.617)(0.818)
Observations11901.2041.1171.121.185
R-squared0.19940.7940.6560.7390.568
No. of countries3941404041
Country FEyesyesyesyesyes
(B) Second stage, estimation of the time-varying tax inefficiency (stochastic frontier)
Number of observations = 1,190
Wald chi2(1) = 430.30
Log likelihood = 73.1133Prob > chi2 = 0.000
ErrorCoefficientStandard errorzP>|z|[95% confidence interval]
frontierone0.238***0.011420.740.0000.2159
0.2609
usigmas_cons−2.385***0.0911−26.160.000−2.5637
−2.2064
vsigma_cons−3.875***0.1076−36.020.000−4.0862
−3.6645
(C) Third stage, estimation of time-varying tax inefficiency (stochastic frontier)
Number of observations = 1,190
Wald chi2(1) = 1447.19
Log likelihood = –543.512Prob > chi2 = 0.000
ErrorCoefficientStandard errorzP>|z|[95% confidence interval]
frontierone_te0.509***0.013338.040.0000.482
0.535
usigmas_cons−1.009***0.0584−17.270.000−1.124
−0.894
vsigma_cons−3.463***0.1078−32.120.000−3.6747
−3.2520
(D) Summary of the estimation results
ObservationsMeanStandard deviationMinMax
Time-varying tax effort1,1900.80050.10430.16890.9577
Persistent tax effort1,1900.67240.17020.04440.9307
Total tax effort1,1900.53960.15480.02180.8268
Source: Authors’ calculations.

Standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. CIT, corporate income tax revenue; NRTA, non-resource tax revenue; PIT, personal income tax revenue.

From that first stage, the Kumbhakar et al. (Reference Kumbhakar, Lien and Hardaker2014) model determines the maximum tax potential for each country, given its structural characteristics, estimates the persistent and time-varying inefficiencies, and computes the total inefficiency. On average in the period, SSA countries are at 53.96 per cent of their potential, so that they have room for about 46.04 per cent additional non-resource tax revenue (see Table 6.3 D). Knowing that, on average, countries collect 12.46 per cent of their GDP in non-resource tax revenue, they would have raised 23.09 per cent of their GDP as non-resource tax revenue if they achieved their maximal capacity, given their characteristics. The differences in total tax effort across SSA countries are mainly driven by persistent factors: the full sample average stands at 0.8005, 0.6724, and 0.5396 for the time-varying, the persistent, and the total tax effort, respectively. That room includes both tax administration (e.g. corrupt tax officers, tax evasion, inadequacy of tax administrations, tax exemptions, etc.) and tax policy. It is hard to determine whether persistent and variant inefficiencies are attributable to a tax gap or an administrative gap. If there is a tendency to associate the persistent inefficiencies with an administrative gap, and time-varying inefficiencies with a tax policy gap, significant administrative reforms may be implemented over time while tax policy may experience some persistence over time. In any case, the persistent factors – whether they come from administrative or tax policy inefficiencies – explain the major part of the inefficiencies.

Table 6.4 provides a country ranking over the period studied based on their total tax effort scores.Footnote 8 Lesotho, Burundi, and Malawi appear to be the most efficient countries, while Equatorial Guinea, Angola, and Nigeria record the lowest tax efforts. The tax revenue ratio as a percentage of GDP is high in efficient and low in non-efficient countries. At the same time, Angola and Equatorial Guinea have GDP per capita levels well above the average. Thus, Angola and Equatorial Guinea’s poor performance are the result of the combination of low output and advantageous inputs. These two countries are rich in natural resources and the effort made to raise non-resource tax revenues appears to be very low. By contrast, Burundi manages to raise more revenues than the average while its characteristics are very unfavourable. Over the 2001–2015 subperiod, Togo emerges as the top performer, with a tax effort score of 0.78 in 2015 (rank 1).

Table 6.4 Full sample tax effort-based ranking

CountryAverage tax effortRankCountryAverage tax effortRank
Lesotho0.7671Swaziland0.55521
Burundi0.7582Uganda0.54722
Malawi0.723Seychelles0.54523
Ethiopia0.7044Mali0.53924
Togo0.6995Cabo Verde0.52425
Gambia0.6956Ghana0.49526
Senegal0.6697Guinea0.48427
Mozambique0.6698Cameroon0.47428
Namibia0.6589South Africa0.46229
Kenya0.65810Sierra Leone0.44630
Zambia0.65611Mauritius0.40531
Côte d’Ivoire0.65212Guinea-Bissau0.38432
Rwanda0.64913Botswana0.36633
Benin0.63514Congo Republic0.33134
Comoros0.61515Gabon0.27435
Niger0.616Chad0.27436
Burkina Faso0.59817Nigeria0.25737
Central African Republic0.58318Angola0.21938
Madagascar0.57919Equatorial Guinea0.03339
Tanzania0.57120
Source: Authors’ calculations.

The average tax effort score for the full sample – which amounts to around 54 per cent – remained on average relatively stable (Figure 6.2) during the period. Starting in the late 1980s for Benin and early 1990s for Togo, the performance in terms of tax effort for both countries has improved. The trend for Togo is more one of boom and bust, but the gap in performance between the two countries stands around 6 percentage points. Togo has 9 percentage points more than Benin at the end of the period and ranks first among all countries. However, with a total tax effort level of 0.78 and 0.69 in 2015, Togo and Benin have not recovered their level of tax effort of the beginning of the period. Nigeria, Côte d’Ivoire, Cameroon, and Malawi also experienced an overall decline in performance during the period. Togo has experienced an increase in the last fifteen years (Figure 6.3). By contrast, Benin’s tax effort has declined over the same period.

Figure 6.2 Tax performance over time

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Figure 6.3 Growth rate of tax effort over the period 2000–2015

Source: Authors’ calculations.

We extend the analysis by estimating the tax effort by type of tax: value-added tax (VAT), corporate income tax, personal income tax, trade tax, and excise (Table 6.5). These results should be interpreted with caution. Indeed, tax revenue determinants of the different taxes (inputs) may differ. At the same time, comparison would be complex if a different model were determined for estimating the tax effort for each type of tax. We therefore chose to maintain the same model.

Table 6.5 Tax effort by type of tax

VATTax effortRankCorporate income taxTax effortRankPersonal income taxTax effortRankTrade taxTax effortRankExciseTax effortRank
AngolaNANAAngolaNANAAngolaNANAAngola0.6835AngolaNANA
BurundiNANABurundi0.7122Burundi0.5442Burundi0.66331BurundiNANA
Benin0.6864Benin0.34413Benin0.39614Benin0.66628Benin0.73915
Burkina Faso0.6776Burkina Faso0.32614Burkina Faso0.44510Burkina Faso0.67710Burkina Faso0.7486
Botswana0.63412Botswana0.16933Botswana0.1435Botswana0.6779BotswanaNANA
Central African Rep0.46927Central African Rep0.18431Central African Rep0.4566Central African Rep0.65737Central African Rep0.73916
Côte d’Ivoire0.47925Côte d’Ivoire0.2427Côte d’Ivoire0.33922Côte d’Ivoire0.67315Côte d’Ivoire0.70828
Cameroon0.6649Cameroon0.27922Cameroon0.31523Cameroon0.66925Cameroon0.7467
Congo, Dem. Rep.NANACongo, Dem. Rep.NANACongo, Dem. Rep.NANACongo, Dem. Rep.NANACongo, Dem. Rep.NANA
Congo, Rep.NANACongo, Rep.0.19929Congo, Rep.0.19732Congo, Rep.0.66233Congo, Rep.NANA
Comoros0.44630Comoros0.28320Comoros0.20830Comoros0.67119Comoros0.73817
Cabo Verde0.7093Cabo Verde0.28221Cabo Verde0.29926Cabo Verde0.6834Cabo VerdeNANA
Ethiopia0.6115Ethiopia0.6664Ethiopia0.27328Ethiopia0.6721Ethiopia0.73420
Gabon0.47626Gabon0.17732Gabon0.14234Gabon0.6972GabonNANA
Ghana0.57121Ghana0.29619Ghana0.3918Ghana0.6787Ghana0.73818
Guinea0.56922Guinea0.10537Guinea0.18633Guinea0.66332Guinea0.73122
Gambia, The0.6698Gambia, The0.5745Gambia, The0.4469Gambia, The0.686Gambia, The0.72325
Guinea-Bissau0.46229Guinea-Bissau0.15734Guinea-Bissau0.20231Guinea-Bissau0.6722Guinea-Bissau0.72724
Equatorial Guinea0.23633Equatorial Guinea0.03138Equatorial Guinea0.01838Equatorial Guinea0.65139Equatorial GuineaNANA
Kenya0.59517Kenya0.7291Kenya0.5193Kenya0.66727Kenya0.7485
LesothoNANALesotho0.26724Lesotho0.39416Lesotho0.7261LesothoNANA
Madagascar0.58718Madagascar0.30118Madagascar0.30724Madagascar0.67217Madagascar0.74412
Mali0.64311Mali0.27123Mali0.34821Mali0.67512Mali0.70329
Mozambique0.6795Mozambique0.4787Mozambique0.4498Mozambique0.66924Mozambique0.74114
Mauritius0.31831Mauritius0.14135Mauritius0.13636Mauritius0.66629Mauritius0.66230
Malawi0.60816Malawi0.693Malawi0.5461Malawi0.66726Malawi0.74510
Namibia0.6777Namibia0.3512Namibia0.42611Namibia0.6843Namibia0.72823
Niger0.58119Niger0.38611Niger0.39317Niger0.67118Niger0.73321
Nigeria0.31532Nigeria0.26525Nigeria0.12537Nigeria0.66923Nigeria0.7127
Rwanda0.62414Rwanda0.43510Rwanda0.4735Rwanda0.6636Rwanda0.7468
Senegal0.7152Senegal0.30317Senegal0.3620Senegal0.67513Senegal0.74213
Sierra Leone0.46328Sierra Leone0.2626Sierra Leone0.4213Sierra Leone0.66430Sierra Leone0.73719
Sao Tome and PrincipeNANASao Tome and PrincipeNANASao Tome and PrincipeNANASao Tome and PrincipeNANASao Tome and PrincipeNANA
Swaziland0.64610Swaziland0.21228Swaziland0.30525Swaziland0.67316Swaziland0.71226
Seychelles0.7491Seychelles0.30416Seychelles0.29827Seychelles0.6778Seychelles0.7561
ChadNANAChad0.14136Chad0.36219Chad0.6720ChadNANA
TogoNANATogo0.5046Togo0.4527Togo0.67611Togo0.7459
Tanzania0.55323Tanzania0.32315Tanzania0.42312Tanzania0.66235Tanzania0.74411
Uganda0.58120Uganda0.1930Uganda0.21329Uganda0.67414Uganda0.7484
South Africa0.53224South Africa0.4569South Africa0.39415South Africa0.66234South Africa0.7493
Zambia0.62713Zambia0.468Zambia0.484Zambia0.65738Zambia0.752
ZimbabweNANAZimbabweNANAZimbabweNANAZimbabweNANAZimbabweNANA

NA, not available.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

The tax effort is heterogeneous according to the type of tax. In particular, Benin appears relatively better ranked in terms of VAT (rank 4) and corporate income tax (rank 13) than in terms of trade tax (rank 28), excise (rank 15), and personal income tax (rank 14). The tax effort for VAT is 0.686 and on trade tax 0.666, and only 0.344 and 0.396 on average for corporate income tax and personal income tax. The ranking in terms of Togo’s performance is more homogeneous, but the values of the tax effort vary according to the type of tax: from 0.676 for trade tax to 0.504 for corporate income tax and only 0.452 for personal income tax. These results tend to corroborate those of Cui et al. (Reference Cui, Sola and Dieterich2016), which show an under-performance in terms of income tax relative to the performance in terms of trade tax in Benin.

III The Determinants of Tax Effort: A Logistic Regression Analysis

Using a logistic regression, we now study the effect of some variables – natural resources, aid, institutional quality, political regime, and political stability – on tax effort.

As a first step of the analysis we present some general descriptive statistics. We can observe that non-resource-rich countries and non-fuel exporters have higher tax effort scores than their resource-rich peers. This may support the view that governments in resource-rich countries have less incentive to mobilise tax revenues when they have resource rent. Similarly, landlocked countries make a more intense tax effort and countries that are considered as offshore financial centres have low performance in terms of tax effort. East African Community (EAC) and WAEMU member countries appear to have better performance than Communauté Economique et Monétaire d’Afrique Centrale (CEMAC) and South African Community (SAC) countries. If we look at the evolution of tax effort in the WAEMU and CEMAC countries, it appears that WAEMU countries are on average better performing, which lends some support to the arguments in favour of regional harmonisation (of both customs and domestic tax policies).

Benin has little room to increase tax revenues unless it addresses the reasons why it is below weak taxable capacity by conducting institutional reforms to expand its tax revenue potential. Using the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) database and following Frankel et al. (Reference Frankel, Vegh and Vuletin2013), we compute an index of institutional quality based on an average of four normalised variables: investment profile, corruption, law and order, and bureaucratic quality. Higher values of the index are associated with better economic and political institutions that should favour tax revenue collection.

In order to study rigorously the determinants of tax effort, we carry out an econometric analysis to complement the previous statistical analysis. Based on an international comparison, we examine the effect of some variables on tax effort scores. Our focus here is on the effect of natural resources, official development assistance (ODA), transparency, corruption and accountability (CPIA indicator), and the political regime and stability.

The analysis of the factors explaining the level of tax effort is based on a logistic regression. Tax effort scores range from 0 to 1, the most efficient countries having the highest scores. The ranking is grouped in quartiles according to the score obtained: we have four classes, from Q1 to Q4. Thus, the observations with the lowest scores belong to the first quartile, while the observations with the highest scores are in the fourth quartile. These quartiles are considered as the dependent variable. Using quartiles allows us to estimate the effects associated with each group of countries.

As the dependent variable is thus an ordinal variable, we use a mixed-effects ordered logistic model (see Liu and Hedeker, Reference Liu and Hedeker2006; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, Reference Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal2012). This model is an ordered logistic regression containing both fixed and random effects. The identification strategy makes it possible to control for the characteristics of countries that can affect the evolution of efficiency over time. We use a two-tier model. For M countries, the cumulative probability that a Yit observation belongs to an efficiency quartile greater than q is given by:

PrYit>q|Xit,φq,ui=HXitβ+Zituiφq

with Xit a set of covariates, φq a set of cut points,Footnote 9 and ui a set of random effects (i=1,…,M country, each i has a given number of occurrences in time t=1,…,n occurrences). H() is the cumulative logistic distribution function that represents the cumulative probability. The Xit vector of dimension 1*p represents covariates for fixed effects with β coefficients. The 1*q vectors of Zit are covariates corresponding to random effects and can be used to represent intercepts and random coefficients.

While the estimation of tax effort scores requires focusing on structural supply variables, we now consider the potential effect of demand factors on the estimated level of tax effort: natural resource rent, aid, institutional quality (transparency, corruption, and accountability), political regime, and political stability.

The effect of natural resource rent on tax revenue ratio is widely evidenced in the literature. Natural resource endowment is associated with lower non-resource tax revenue, suggesting a natural resource curse (Sachs and Warner, Reference Sachs and Warner2001; Eltony, Reference Eltony2002; Melou et al., Reference Melou, Belinga, Paul and Nganou2017). In particular, during commodity price upswings, governments in resource-rich countries have less incentive to mobilise tax revenues so that resource rent crowds out tax revenue. We consider in our model total natural resource rents (percentage of GDP) as the sum of oil rents, natural gas rents, coal rents (hard and soft), mineral rents, and forest rents.Footnote 10

ODA can also modify government behaviour (Bahl, Reference Bahl2000; Bird and Smart, Reference Bird and Smart2002). The literature highlights several effects. Among the most documented, the flypaper effect is an empirical regularity: any increase in transfers/aid leads to greater public spending than an equivalent rise in the private revenue of the population (Hines and Thaler, Reference Hines and Thaler1995). In a context of informational asymmetries, aid challenges the fiscal discipline of recipient governments by raising a moral hazard problem (Pisauro, Reference Pisauro2001; Kornai et al., Reference Kornai, Maskin and Roland2003): it can be perceived as a kind of windfall resource, which crowds out own-source revenue by reducing the willingness of governments to improve their tax effort. More broadly, aid dependency seems to erode governments’ accountability, a prerequisite for the quality of public expenditure and taxpayers’ voluntary compliance. Hence, we consider in our model ‘Net ODA’ (from the World Bank). This consists of ‘disbursements of loans made on concessional terms (net of repayments of principal) and grants by official agencies of the members of the Development Assistance Committee (DAC), by multilateral institutions, and by non-DAC countries to promote economic development and welfare in countries and territories in the DAC list of ODA recipients’.Footnote 11

Institutional quality may also play a key role in mobilising resources. Indeed, it can improve tax policies and administrations’ ability to collect revenues, as well as taxpayers’ voluntary compliance. In particular, the degree of transparency, accountability, and corruption in the public sector determines the extent to which citizens can hold the executive accountable for its use of funds, and for the results of its decisions and actions. It also determines the extent to which public employees within the executive are required to account for administrative decisions, use of resources, and the final results obtained. Using the ‘CPIA transparency, accountability, and corruption in the public sector rating’ variable makes it possible to account for these potential effects. The three main dimensions assessed in that indicator are ‘the accountability of the executive to oversight institutions and of public employees for their performance, access of civil society to information on public affairs, and state capture by narrow vested interests’ (World Bank, 2009, p. 301).

Beyond the institutional aspects, the political regime in place may explain the level of tax effort. A growing body of literature suggests that political regime type matters in determining taxation. Garcia and Von Haldenwang (Reference Garcia and Von Haldenwang2016) identify three different causal mechanisms that affect the relation between regime type and taxation: economic growth, redistribution, and legitimacy. First, based on a positive link between democratic rule and economic growth, democracy should lead to higher tax collection because of growing taxable income. Second, based on the median voter theorem (Milanovic, Reference Milanovic2000; Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2006), the expansion of suffrage induced by democracy should lead to higher levels of redistribution and more public services, which may impact the level of taxation. Third, tax contractualism emphasises the importance of legitimacy and credibility in bargaining processes and tax compliance (Moore, Reference Moore, Brautigam, Fjeldstad and Moore2008; Timmons, Reference Timmons2005; Levi and Sacks, Reference Levi and Sacks2007; Bates and Lien, Reference Bates and Lien1985; Mahdavi, Reference Mahdavi2008). In this context, democracy should lead to higher tax collection, as taxpayers can be more confident that fiscal resources are spent for the common good and that the distribution of the tax burden is fair. Empirical research on the relationship of political regimes to taxation yields mixed results and it appears that there is no linear trend in favour of democracy. To test for these potential effects, we use a modified version of the ‘Polity’ variable proposed by the Center for Systemic Peace that allows the use of a regime measure in time-series analyses. This variable captures the political regime authority spectrum on a 21-point scale ranging from −10 (hereditary monarchy) to +10 (consolidated democracy).Footnote 12

Tax effort may also be influenced by political instability. An important literature shows that political stability determines the level of taxation (Cukierman et al., Reference Cukierman, Edwards and Tabellini1992; Aizenmana and Jinjarak, Reference Aizenmana and Jinjarak2008; Melo, Reference Melo2011). A rise in the level of political instability generates a decrease in the resources available and public expenditure in the next period. Moreover, the risk of radical policy changes in the future can have a detrimental effect on the tax behaviour of governments and on tax compliance. We include in the empirical analysis a variable from the World Bank that measures ‘perceptions of the likelihood of political instability and/or politically-motivated violence, including terrorism. The estimate gives the country’s score on the aggregate indicator, in units of a standard normal distribution, i.e. ranging from −2.5 to 2.5’.Footnote 13

Table 6.6 presents the results of the regression of the logistic model. We regress successively each of the interest variables (columns 1 to 5) and then all these variables at the same time (column 6). Aid is associated with a lower probability of belonging to a quartile of high tax effort, while institutional quality (measured by the CPIA index) increases the probability of belonging to an efficient quartile in terms of tax effort. If the effect of the political system is not clear, political stability is strongly and positively associated with a greater likelihood of having a high tax burden. When the model is regressed across all variables, the effects of aid, institutional quality, and the political system appear to be significant.

Table 6.6 Logistic regression results

Quartiles of tax effort(I)(II)(III)(IV)(V)(VI)
ODA−0.001***
(0.000)
−0.001*
(0.000)
Natural resource rent0.048
(0.017)
−0.003
(0.032)
CPIA1.626***
(0.203)
1.030*
(0.770)
Political regime−0.027
(0.022)
−0.060**
(0.026)
Political Stability0.617***
(0.160)
−0.207
(0.386)
Cut 1−2.351***
(0.305)
−1.501***
(0.263)
0.418
(0.966)
−1.891***
(0.489)
−1.833***
(0.258)
1.549
(2.596)
Cut 2−0.554
(0.296)
0.176
(0.258)
2.316**
(0.972)
−0.064
(0.481)
−0.106
(0.251)
3.696
(2.613)
Cut 30.567*
(0.299)
1.286***
(0.262)
3.769***
(0.981)
0.821*
(0.484)
1.093***
(0.255)
5.222**
(2.620)
Var (Const)1.475*
(1.097)
1.474***
(0.203)
1.454***
(0260)
1.465***
(0.345)
1.453***
(0.212)
1.515**
(0.842)
Observations851845684288864216
Number of groups2424198246
Log-likelihood−779.05−795.29−662.16−261.35−801.82−223.43
Source: Authors’ calculations.

* Coefficient significant at 10% level.

IV Tax Policy or Revenue Administration Reforms

In this section, we review some tax policy and tax administrative issues in Benin, and suggest some reforms to improve tax mobilisation.

A Tax Policy and Tax Expenditures

The Beninese government sets the tax policy under the control of the legislative authority and following the WAEMU tax Regulation (Règlement in French), Directives, or Decisions.Footnote 14 WAEMU tax Directives define the rates and bases of the main taxes: VAT, corporate income tax, excises, portfolio incomes, and so on. Therefore, WAEMU member countries share a similar set of tax laws, which are encompassed in their respective national tax codes. However, tax effort analysis highlights the leading role of Senegal, which belongs to WAEMU too. Senegal displays a tax effort above 70 per cent, meaning a tax gap of less than 30 per cent of potential tax revenue over the most recent period (2015).

A potential explanation of this discrepancy between Benin and Senegal (or Togo) is a derogatory tax regime, such as the Investment Code (IC). Indeed, all the WAEMU countries, like almost developing countries, provide some tax incentives through their IC (or Act). Such a policy, sometimes suggested by the World Bank, aims to attract foreign direct investment. The main issue is in the details of these incentive schemes, which may also reflect the effects of lobbying.

The comparison of the Beninese IC, enacted in 1990 and modified in 1998 and 2008, with the Togolese one (in force since 2012) yields the conclusion of a greater generosity towards investors in Benin. Indeed, the Beninese IC offers a complete corporate income tax exemption over a period from five to nine years (even fifteen years if the investment is located in remote areas). Moreover, tax advantages and their duration increase with the investment amount. Meanwhile, the Togolese IC does not provide such a corporate income tax break, but only a 50 per cent rebate on corporate income tax owed. Moreover, this advantage is limited to five years and does not apply to some sectors, such as mobile phone companies, banks, insurance companies, retailers, or firms in charge of seaport and airport infrastructure. Another noticeable difference between the Beninese IC and the Togolese one concerns the importation of second-hand materials necessary for projects: Togo raises a unique 5 per cent tax for VAT and duty purposes, while Benin provides a complete exemption.

If the efficiency of such incentives in attracting foreign direct investment remains uncertain (see Van Parys and James, Reference Van Parys and James2010), tax revenue losses captured through tax expenditure assessment are more obvious.Footnote 15 Consequently, despite similar tax laws between Benin and Togo, tax expenditures such as these provided in ICs may differ significantly, partly explaining the gap in tax effort between these two countries. Yearly tax expenditure assessments and publications contained in the appendices to finance laws, in accordance with the 2015 WAEMU Decision, would contribute to streamlining these incentives, and improving the tax effort by reducing the policy gap.

B Tariff Policy and Informal Trade with Nigeria

Beyond tax policy, an important component for Benin is the tariff policy, which is determined by the WAEMU Commission and, officially since 2015, by the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS) Commission. ECOWAS is a customs union with fifteen members.Footnote 16 The ECOWAS Common External Tariff implementation is still ongoing, but it will impact Benin’s tax revenue, given the weight of the transit activity in this country. Tax revenue collected at the border represented almost half of total tax revenue in 2015: 4.41 per cent of GDP for trade taxes and 2.64 per cent of GDP for VAT collected at the border.

A large part of Beninese imports is not for the domestic market, but for the Nigerian one, and for landlocked countries (Burkina Faso, Mali, and Niger). Indeed, Nigeria has developed a protectionist trade policy by banning the importation of some goods (e.g. poultry meat, beer, used clothes, tyres, used cars, etc.) or raising high tariff rates on some other goods (e.g. 50 per cent on rice or sugar). This trade policy fuels smuggling activity in Benin and Togo. The former manages to extract significant tax revenue from this activity, which is estimated at 14 per cent of total tax revenue, or equivalent to 2.4 per cent of GDP in 2008 (see Golub, Reference Golub2012; IMF, 2012). Despite a geographical advantage for Benin given the common border with Nigeria, there is competition between Benin and Togo to attract this illegal transit activity. This competition may seriously limit efforts to improve domestic revenue mobilisation, at least at the border. For instance, despite or because of the WAEMU Common External Tariff in place in Benin and Togo since 2000, competition takes place on the reported value of imported goods for the Nigerian market. Such competition does not respect the World Trade Organization transaction value principle. Hence, special attention should be given to tariff policy in Benin, taking into account the existence of the informal trade with Nigeria.

C Administration Capacity

Tax effort is closely related to the tax and customs administration capacity. Benin still has a ‘classic’ organisation of these administrations, while Togo implemented a SARA in 2014. While it may be too early to assess the efficiency of such a reform in this particular case, Ebeke et al. (2015) found a significant positive impact of SARA on domestic revenue mobilisation: an increase by 4 percentage points of GDP. A natural question, then, would be whether Benin should switch to a revenue agency.

First implemented in Africa by Ghana in 1985, the SARA is a drastic reform, which can be understood as a strategic delegation of taxation power to an autonomous agent. The autonomy, which differs significantly across countries, is a signal of a more credible audit policy, since control occurs, at least theoretically, without any political interference. Two main advantages of SARAs are advanced in the literature. First, SARAs involve the merger of tax and customs administrations in order to (1) exploit synergies, in particular for VAT on imports (Keen, Reference Keen2008); and (2) save costs by combining operational functions in tax collections (World Bank, 2010). The second advantage is human resource management. Recruitment, promotion, and dismissal do not have to respect civil service rules, allowing a number of flexibilities, such as higher wages (Fjeldstadt and Moore, 2009; Moore, Reference Moore2014). Table 6.7 shows preliminary evidence of a positive correlation between public-sector wages and salariesFootnote 17 and estimated tax effort.

Table 6.7 Correlation between civil service wage bill and tax effort

[1][2][3][4]
Payroll [1]1.0000
Total tax effort [2]0.1766*1.0000
Time-varying tax effort [3]0.1473*0.9697*1.0000
Persistent tax effort [4]0.1423*0.3395*0.10171.0000
Source: Authors’ calculations.

Switching to a SARA is a radical reform and the transition may be costly and risky, as it involves the replacement of a significant share of the staff. Alternative reforms may focus on the payment and incentive mechanisms in place in the Beninese tax and customs administrations. In 2016, the Beninese tax administration numbered less than 500 staffFootnote 18 (there are more than 1,500 in Togo and there are 1,200 in Senegal). These staff receive several premiums in addition to their wage: prime de rendement, prime d’incitation, prime d’impulsion, and potentially a risk premium. A large part of these premiums remains collective, reducing their incentive dimension. Several empirical studies have highlighted the advantage of reviewing such incentives. For instance, Khan et al. (Reference Khan, Khwaja and Olken2016) show that a reward scheme based on collected revenue significantly improved property tax revenue in Pakistan. However, they emphasise also that the revenue gain resulted from a small number of properties, the values of which were reassessed, and that a risk of higher bribes emerged with the increase in collectors’ bargaining power because of this new incentive mechanism. Thus, the introduction of individual performance contracts may be necessary, but is not sufficient to reduce the risk of corruption. As with a SARA, this mechanism should be complemented by extensive and effective monitoring (see Fjeldstad, Reference Fjeldstad2002).

In 2017, Benin carried out a reform of its tax administration through a significant reorganisation,Footnote 19 which follows the segmentation approach of taxpayer population. It introduced a risk analysis for its audit policy and human management based on results. The details of this reform are unknown and the previously described incentive mechanisms seem to remain.

The 2017 tax administration reform also established a tax policy unit. This unit is in charge of defining the tax policy, forecasting expected tax revenue and the effect of tax reforms, and assessing tax expenditure. If the creation of a tax policy unit is an improvement in designing the Beninese tax system, the location of this unit inside the tax administration itself may seriously limit the efficiency of such a reform. First, it reflects a common inconsistency in French-speaking countries, and even in France, in which the tax administration not only collects taxes, but also designs the tax policy. Moreover, given the role of the tax policy unit in forecasting tax revenue, the tax administration seems to have complete control over the goals to be achieved in terms of tax revenue, and the bonuses to be distributed to its staff. Second, customs remains an important tax collector and should be included in any tax reform and tax expenditure assessment. A natural location of the tax policy unit would have been ‘above’ both revenue administrations, headed by the special tax adviser of the Ministry of Finance. There is a need to clarify the role of each stakeholder: the revenue authorities, which collect taxes, and the Ministry of Finance, which designs the tax policy, with parliamentary control.

V Conclusion

Based on a large database covering forty-one SSA countries and the period 1980–2015, we analysed the effort by Benin to raise non-resource tax revenue in light of its structural characteristics. The stochastic frontier analysis, by comparing the non-resource tax-to-GDP ratio in Benin with its peers, identified whether Benin was away from the tax frontier: the tax effort in Benin remained relatively stable during the period, with an average of 65.1 per cent over the period and a rank of thirteen out of forty-two countries. A tax effort of 65.1 per cent means that the level of non-resource tax revenue is at 34.9 per cent of the country’s maximum capacity. Knowing that, on average, Benin collects 11.14 per cent of its GDP in non-resource tax revenue and is at 65.1 per cent of its capacity, it would have raised 17.11 per cent of its GDP as non-resource tax revenue if it had used all its potential, given its characteristics. Hence, Benin has little room – insufficient to reach the WAEMU criterion of 20 per cent of tax revenue to GDP – to increase tax revenues, unless it addresses the reasons for the weak taxable capacity and conducts institutional reforms to expand its tax revenue potential.

In order to study rigorously the determinants of tax effort, an econometric analysis then complemented the previous statistical analysis. Based on an international comparison, we examined the effect of natural resources, ODA, transparency, corruption and accountability (CPIA indicator), and the political regime and stability on tax effort scores. We found that aid is associated with a lower probability of belonging to a quartile of high tax effort, while institutional quality (measured by the CPIA index) seems to increase the probability of belonging to an efficient quartile in terms of tax effort. Political stability appears to be strongly and positively associated with a greater likelihood of having a high tax burden.

Analysing potential policy and administrative sources of these tax gaps, we shed light on the human resource policy of the tax administration and the remuneration mechanisms, which may be obsolete. The payment and incentive mechanisms in place in Beninese tax and customs administrations should be reviewed and associated with extensive and effective monitoring to improve tax effort and limit the risks of corruption. The 2017 tax administration reform may improve tax revenue through a more efficient organisation of departments and divisions. However, it also raises a critical issue of providing the decision-making power in tax policy to the tax administration through the creation of a tax policy unit.

Footnotes

* Coefficient significant at 10% level. GDPPC, gross domestic product per capita.

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2006), Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Aigner, D. J., Lovell, C. A. K., and Schmidt, P. (1977), ‘Formulation and Estimation of Stochastic Frontier Production Function Models’, Journal of Economics, Vol. 6, pp. 21–37.Google Scholar
Aizenmana, J. and Jinjarak, Y. (2008), ‘The Collection Efficiency of the Value Added Tax: Theory and International Evidence’, Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, Vol. 17, No. 3, pp. 391–410.Google Scholar
Anderson, B. (2008), ‘Tax Expenditure in OECD Countries’, 5th Annual Meeting of OECD-Asia SBO Bangkok, 10–11 January. www.oecd.org/gov/budgeting/39944419.pdf.Google Scholar
Anderson, B. and Minarik, J. J. (2006), ‘Design Choices for Fiscal Policy Rules’, OECD Journal on Budgeting, Vol. 5, No. 4, pp. 159–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bahl, R. (2000), ‘Intergovernmental Transfers in Developing and Transition Countries: Principles and Practice’, Discussion Paper 2, Background Series, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Bates, R. H. and Lien, D-HD. (1985), ‘A Note on Taxation, Development, and Representative Government’, Politics & Society, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 53–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battese, G. E. and Coelli, T. J. (1988), ‘Prediction of Firm-Level Technical Efficiencies with a Generalized Frontier Production Function and Panel Data’, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 38, No. 3, pp. 387–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bird, R. M., Martinez-Vazquez, J., and Torgler, B. (2008), ‘Tax Effort in Developing Countries and High Income Countries: The Impact of Corruption, Voice and Accountability’, Economic Analysis and Policy, Vol. 38, No. 1, pp. 55–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bird, R. M. and Smart, M. (2002), ‘Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers: International Lessons for Developing Countries’, World Development, Vol. 30, No. 6, pp. 899–912.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brautigam, D., Fjeldstad, O.-H., and Moore, M. (2009), Taxation and State-Building in Developing Countries: Capacity and Consent, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Caldeira, E. and Rota-Graziosi, G. (2019), ‘The Tax Effort in Benin: How Can Tax Gaps Be Reduced?’, in Bourguignon, F., Houssa, R., Platteau, J.-P., and Reding, P. (eds.), Benin Institutional Diagnostic, WP19/BID03, Oxford: Economic Development and Institutions, ch. 6. https://edi.opml.co.uk/resource/benin-how-can-tax-gaps-be-reduced.Google Scholar
Charnes, A., Cooper, W. W., Lewin, A. Y., and Seiford, L. M. (eds.) (2013), Data Envelopment Analysis: Theory, Methodology, and Applications, New York: Springer Science & Business Media.Google Scholar
Clements, B. (2002), ‘How Efficient Is Education Spending in Europe?European Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 3–26.Google Scholar
Crivelli, E. and Gupta, S. (2014), ‘Resource Blessing, Revenue Curse? Domestic Revenue Effort in Resource-Rich Countries’, IMF Working Paper No. 14/5, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cui, L. Q., Sola, S., Dieterich, C. et al. (2016), ‘Make Investment Scaling-Up Work in Benin: A Macro-Fiscal Analysis’, IMF Departmental Papers/Policy Papers 2016/001, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A., Edwards, S., and Tabellini, G. (1992), ‘Seigniorage and Political Instability’, American Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 3, pp. 537–55.Google Scholar
Deprins, D., Simar, L., Tulkens, H., Marchand, M., Pestieau, P., and Tulkens, H. (1984), ‘The Performance of Public Enterprises: Concepts and Measurement’, in Marchand, M.Pestieau, , P., and Tulkens, H. (eds.), The Performance of Public Enterprises : Concepts and Measurement, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 243–68.Google Scholar
Ebeke, C., Mansour, M., and Rota-Graziosi, G. (2016), ‘The Power to Tax in Sub-Saharan Africa: LTUs, VATs, and SARAs’, CERDI Etudes et Documents 200921, Clermont-Ferrand: CERDI.Google Scholar
Eltony, M. N. (2002), ‘The Determinants of Tax Effort in Arab Countries’, API-Working Paper Series, Safat: Arab Planning Institute – Kuwait, Information Center.Google Scholar
Fjeldstad, O.-H. (2002), ‘Fighting Fiscal Corruption: The Case of the Tanzania Revenue Authority’, CMI Working Paper WP 2002:3, Bergen: Chr. Michelsen Institute.Google Scholar
Fjeldstad, O.-H. and Moore, M. (2009), ‘Revenue Authorities and Public Authorities in Sub-Saharan Africa’, Journal of Modern African Studies, Vol. 47, No. 1, pp. 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankel, J., Vegh, C., and Vuletin, G. (2013), ‘On Graduation from Fiscal Procyclicality’, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 100, No. 1, pp. 32–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garcia, M. and Von Haldenwang, C. (2016) ‘Do Democracies Tax More? Political Regime Type and Taxation’, Journal of International Development, 28, pp. 485–506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golub, S. S. (2012), ‘Entrepôt Trade and Smuggling in West Africa: Benin, Togo and Nigeria’, World Economy, Vol. 35, No. 9, 1139–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, R. and Li, W. (2009), ‘Tax Structures in Developing Countries: Many Puzzles and a Possible Explanation’, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 93, No. 7–8, pp. 855–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hines, J. R. and Thaler, R. H. (1995), ‘Anomalies: The Flypaper Effect’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9, No. 4, pp. 217–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IMF (2012), ‘Sub-Saharan Africa: Maintaining Growth in an Uncertain World, Regional Economic Outlook’, October, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
IMF (2018), ‘Benin, Second Review under the Extended Credit Facility and Request for Modification of Performance’, July, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Keen, M. (2008), ‘VAT, Tariffs, and Withholding: Border Taxes and Informality in Developing Countries’, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 92, No. 10–11, pp. 1892–906.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keen, M. and Perry, V. (2013), ‘Understanding Countries’ Tax Effort’, IMF Working Paper N°/13/244, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khan, A. Q., Khwaja, A. I., and Olken, B. (2016), ‘Tax Farming Redux: Experimental Evidence on Performance Pay for Tax Collectors’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 131, No. 1, pp. 219–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kornai, J., Maskin, E., and Roland, G. (2003), ‘Understanding the Soft Budget Constraint’, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 41, No. 4, pp. 1095–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumbhakar, S. C., Lien, G., and Hardaker, J. B. (2014), ‘Technical Efficiency in Competing Panel Data Models: A Study of Norwegian Grain Farming’, Journal of Productivity Analysis, Vol. 41, No. 2, pp. 321–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumbhakar, S. C., Wang, H. J., and Horncastle, A. P. (2015), A Practitioner’s Guide to Stochastic Frontier Analysis Using Stata, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, G.-M., Wodon, Q., and Carey, K. (eds.) (2018), ‘The Changing Wealth of Nations 2018: Building a Sustainable Future’, Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langford, B. and Ohlenburg, T. (2016), ‘Tax Revenue Potential and Effort: An Empirical Investigation’, Working Paper, London: International Growth Centre.Google Scholar
Levi, M. and Sacks, A. (2007), ‘Legitimating Beliefs: Sources and Indicators’, Afrobarometer Working Paper No. 74, Cape Town: Afrobarometer.Google Scholar
Liu, L. C. and Hedeker, D. (2006), ‘A Mixed-Effects Regression Model for Longitudinal Multivariate Ordinal Data’, Biometrics, Vol. 62, No. 1, pp. 261–68.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lotz, J. and Morss, E. (1967), ‘Measuring “Tax Effort” in Developing Countries’, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 14, 478–99.Google Scholar
Mahdavi, S. (2008), ‘The Level and Composition of Tax Revenue in Developing Countries: Evidence from Unbalanced Panel Data’, International Review of Economics & Finance, Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 607–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansour, M. (2015), ‘A Tax Revenue Dataset for Sub-Saharan Africa: 1980–2010’, Ferdi Working Paper I19, July, Paris: Foundation for Studies and Research on International Development.Google Scholar
Mansour, M. and Rota-Graziosi, M. (2013), ‘Tax Coordination, Tax Competition, and Revenue Mobilization in the West African Economic and Monetary Union’, IMF Working Paper WP/13/163, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melo, M. (2011), ‘Institutional Weakness and the Puzzle of Argentina’s Low Taxation’, Latin American Politics and Society, Vol. 49, No. 4, pp. 115–48.Google Scholar
Melou, M. K., Belinga, T., Paul, V. D., and Nganou, J. P. (2017), ‘Does Oil Revenue Crowd Out Other Tax Revenues? Policy Lessons for Uganda’, Working Paper No. WPS8048, Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milanovic, B. (2000), ‘The Median-Voter Hypothesis, Income Inequality, and Income Redistribution: An Empirical Test with the Required Data’, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 16, No. 3, pp. 367–410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, M. (2008), ‘Between Coercion and Contract: Competing Narratives around Taxation and Governance’, in Brautigam, D., Fjeldstad, O.-H., and Moore, M. (eds.), Taxation and State Building in Developing Countries: Capacity and Consent, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Moore, M. (2014) ‘Revenue Reform and State-Building in Anglophone Africa’, World Development, Vol. 60, pp. 99–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2010) Tax Expenditures in OECD Countries, Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.Google Scholar
Pessino, C. and Fenochietto, R. (2010), ‘Determining Countries’ Tax Effort’, Hacienda Pública Española/Revista de Economía Pública, Vol. 195, No. 4, pp. 61–68.Google Scholar
Pisauro, G. (2001), ‘Intergovernmental Relations and Fiscal Discipline: Between Commons and Soft Budget Constraints’, Working Paper 01/65, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabe-Hesketh, S. and Skrondal, A. (2012), Multilevel and Longitudinal Modeling Using Stata, 3rd ed., College Station, TX: StataCorp.Google Scholar
Sachs, J. D., and Warner, A. M. (2001), ‘The Curse of Natural Resources’, European Economic Review, Vol. 45, pp. 827–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stotsky, J. and WoldeMariam, A. (1997), ‘Tax Effort in Sub-Saharan Africa’, Working Paper 97/107, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svirydzenka, K. (2016), ‘Introducing a New Broad-based Index of Financial Development’, IMF Working Papers 2016/005, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tanzi, V. (1987), ‘Quantitative Characteristics of the Tax Systems of Developing Countries’, in Newbery, D., and Stern, N. (eds.), The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 205–41.Google Scholar
Timmons, J. F. (2005), ‘The Fiscal Contract: States, Taxes and Public Services’, World Politics, Vol. 57, No. 4, pp. 530–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Parys, S. and James, S. (2010), ‘The Effectiveness of Tax Incentives in Attracting Investment: Panel Data Evidence from the CFA Franc Zone’, International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 400–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank (2010), ‘Integration of Revenue Administration. A Comparative Study of International Experience’, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
World Bank (2009), World Development Indicators, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 6.1a Share tax over GDP

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 1

Figure 6.1b Non-resource tax over GDP

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 2

Table 6.1 Pairwise correlation between interest variables

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 3

Table 6.2 Descriptive statistics

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 4

Table 6.3 Three-stage estimates of the tax effort in sub-Saharan African countries

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 5

Table 6.4 Full sample tax effort-based ranking

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 6

Figure 6.2 Tax performance over time

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 7

Figure 6.3 Growth rate of tax effort over the period 2000–2015

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 8

Table 6.5 Tax effort by type of tax

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 9

Table 6.6 Logistic regression results

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 10

Table 6.7 Correlation between civil service wage bill and tax effort

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×