Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T01:12:49.706Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Complexity as an opportunity and challenge for behavioural public policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 August 2018

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper is a response to Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth (2018). The challenges and opportunities of behavioural public policy Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth discuss highlight a conundrum for the field: the impact of behavioural interventions is difficult to measure accurately in complex situations, and yet complexity is inherent in the very areas in most need of impact. Behavioural interventions will be only one tool of many to work towards broader organisational, systems and social change. As a field, we should be looking to other disciplines, inviting them into the fold of discussions on how to achieve these changes. Finally, while the mantra of nudge for good is a useful beacon, intentions are only part of the equation, and a number of questions should be asked when considering a behavioural policy intervention.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2018 

Michael Sanders, Veerle Snijders and Michael Hallsworth (Reference Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth2018; henceforth referred to as SSH) identify what they see as the many challenges and opportunities that the field of behavioural public policy faces. For each category (challenges and opportunities), they provide well-referenced explanations of the individual areas identified. What I believe could add value to the discussion is to articulate the generalisations that can be made in each category. The challenges point to how difficult it can be to evaluate impact, whereas the opportunities lie in scaling up wholesale behaviour change. This brings into focus a conundrum for practitioners of behavioural public policy: on the one hand recognising that the impact of behavioural interventions is difficult to measure accurately in complex situations; and on the other hand acknowledging that complexity is inherent in the very areas in most need of impact.

The majority of this response will discuss this conundrum before briefly discussing the need for the field to be humble enough to recognise when behavioural economics is not the answer, introducing a mindset that may be valuable when approaching a complex policy challenge and probing some of the nuance around nudging for good.

Impact assessment and snowballs

In the ‘Where are we now?’ section, SSH highlight the many advances that the field has made and state both that “[t]here is much for proponents of behavioural science to be pleased with here” and “…there is a danger that behavioural science is seen to offer merely technocratic tweaks, rather than the more wide-ranging reassessment of public administration that could be possible.” Indeed, the rise in activity, awareness and popularity of the field is exciting, but I would caution that while the “wide-ranging reassessment of public administration” could be possible and worth striving for, it is not likely to be easy.

Looking first at the challenges identified in SSH (the long-term effects of interventions; repeated exposure effects; problems with proxy measures; spillovers and general equilibrium effects and unintended consequences; cultural variation; ‘reverse impact’; and the replication crisis), they seem to have a common theme around impact evaluation. Even randomised controlled trials, often referred to as the gold standard of research, have their limitations, and each of SSH's challenges, with the exception of ‘reverse impact’, illustrates a case where it is difficult to extrapolate the actual sustained impact of a particular intervention from the results of the experimentation preceding it. This highlights both how difficult it can be to accurately measure impact and that even if the pilot is promising, rolling out the scaled intervention will not necessarily have proportional effects.

Looking next to the opportunities SSH highlight as available to the field (influencing the behaviour of government itself; scaling interventions; social diffusion; nudging organisations; and dealing with thorny problems), all seem to be about scope and scale and are somewhat self-referential. For example, the scaling interventions and social diffusion ‘opportunities’ will be required for nudging government, nudging organisations and thorny problems.

By ‘thorny problems’, the authors are describing “trickier, more complex problems.” As above, this opportunity seems to describe all of the areas preceding it within the category; that is, nudging government, scaling interventions, social diffusion and nudging organisations all could themselves be described as thorny by SSH's definition. Further, it may be worth stepping beyond calling these problems ‘thorny’ and instead describing them as ‘wicked’, meaning that they are difficult to solve due to incomplete knowledge, the size of the problem or number of people and stakeholders involved, the complexity and interconnectedness of the system or any combination of those factors (Wicked Problems website; Churchman, Reference Churchman1967).

Perhaps a simpler way to describe the opportunity set, then, is to ask: how can behavioural science help to snowball ‘simple’ individual-level behaviour change out to complex population-level shifts?

These challenges and opportunities are therefore not trivial. They will be about moving beyond the tweaks at the margins and towards broader organisational, systems and social change. This is not to undermine the work of the “low-hanging fruit” of binary choices as described by SSH. Not only does improving tax repayment (Hallsworth et al., Reference Hallsworth, J.A., R.D. and I.2017), for example, contribute to the effective functioning of public services that are so fundamentally important for society, but also, successful behaviour change in these “low-hanging fruit” areas served as proof of concept, and therefore has been instrumentally important for the Behavioural Insights Team (BIT) and the field more generally as well. But what about other, bigger, more complex, wicked issues where it is unlikely that the pull of just one lever will be sufficient for change?

Thorny, wicked problems

SSH allude to wicked interconnectedness when they only briefly discuss the Lucas critique, but this is perhaps the crux of the situation. They write: “…since consumption functions are not fixed and can respond to changes in circumstances, they are not ‘policy invariant’, and so may change in response to changes of policy.” Indeed, this is the essence of what makes it so difficult to measure impact directly. Any effect will necessarily change the system, and therefore we cannot assume that the same intervention will have the same effect again, and given this ever-changing environment, we can never perfectly evaluate the impact of any particular behaviour change initiative.

The World Bank's World Development Report (2015) explains that much of our thinking is done automatically, socially and through the frame of mental models. By ‘automatically’, the World Bank authors are referring to our individual cognition and system 1 processing; ‘socially’ explains the weight of our peer group on our behaviour; and ‘mental models’ refers to how our cultural and institutional experiences shape the lenses through which we view the world. Any change to context could influence any one of those levels, not least our mental models. So when SSH discuss the challenges to the field, it seems that the common element is the complex, ever-shifting context.

For example, SSH ask whether repeated exposure leads to diminishing marginal returns (less impact per additional unit of exposure) or reinforcement (more impact per additional unit of exposure) of the message. This is clearly important to understand, but the general point is once again the same and particularly salient in this case: with every intervention – even if it is the same intervention being repeated – the context changes. Therefore, we cannot know for sure that an intervention that worked in the past will ever work again in the future, because the context is forever new.

A similar point can be made for the social diffusion opportunity. Social diffusion has the potential to increase impact exponentially, clearly improving the efficiency of an intervention. As SSH write, “[i]n a world of limited resources, a better understanding of how to harness peer-to-peer transmission of behaviour could mean that the same or better outcomes are achieved at much less cost…” However, while an intervention may be the catalyst, the social diffusion itself would be largely outside of the policy-maker's control. Whether that behavioural intervention would work similarly again, given the changed context with new norms, would be hard to say. Arguably, the efficiency benefits likely outweigh the uncertainty drawbacks.

With respect to nudging government or organisations, SSH write that organisations are made up of a collection of individual people, each of whom could presumably be nudged, while also noting that there are often policies in place to prevent just one single person from making a large decision. What should be emphasised here is that a whole group is different to the sum of its parts; that is, it cannot be taken as given that the same person would act in the same way alone as when in the presence of others. Therefore, there is no guarantee that an intervention introduced in an organisation would produce the same effect as one in the home of a singleton.

For example, consider the case of defensive decision-making, in which a person chooses a course of action not because it necessarily has the highest expected outcome assuming that all goes well, but because it is more easily defensible in the case that all does not go well (Gigerenzer, Reference Gigerenzer2015). Defensive decision-making may be more prevalent for business or organisational decisions than personal decisions because of the difference in stakeholders and clarity of hierarchy. The consequence of not being able to defend your decision may vary: a friend or neighbour might disapprove of a choice you have made, but your boss can fire you.

Being in a group necessarily changes the social context and can affect the mental models – an organisational culture – through which we make sense of the organisation and the world. As with the discussion of repeated exposure effects, providing nudges in an organisation may result in reinforcing feedback (so that there is positive social contagion), diminishing returns (with some people affected less strongly than others) or even balancing feedback (e.g., if someone were to feel licensing effects off the back of one of their colleagues’ good deeds) within the system, making the ultimate impact harder to predict.

Beyond behavioural interventions

SSH admirably accept the challenge of addressing thorny or wicked problems head on: “[a]t first, this can seem something daunting and to be avoided, but it is precisely here that new tools should be used. If we consider that behavioural economics came into existence to explain phenomena that standard economic analysis found inexplicable, perhaps behavioural science can solve problems that standard economic tools have found insoluble” (emphasis added). Yes, perhaps it can, but it is also worth considering that not all interventions are behavioural, and not all impact is from interventions.

Firstly, standard economic tools should not be discarded. A good behaviour change practitioner will recognise that not all interventions should be behavioural (i.e., nudges) and that the appropriate lever for change may be one of the more traditional approaches (behaviourally informed or otherwise), like awareness or regulation (e.g., see Finighan, Reference Finighan2015; Soman, Reference Soman2015; Thaler, Reference Thaler2017). Dilip Soman (Reference Soman2015) uses personas to illustrate the point: sometimes the best method to change behaviour is that of a lawyer, an economist, a marketer or a behavioural scientist. Note that the behavioural scientist is only one of many in this stylised set-up. Similarly, Finighan (Reference Finighan2015) provides examples of behavioural levers that address standard economic problems and, vice versa, standard policy levers that solve behavioural problems. An example of the former would be to “align teacher interests with student learning by providing social rewards, like recognition and thanks,” and an example of the latter would be “to overcome savings myopia, use a mandate (e.g. superannuation) or a financial incentive to increase savings” (Finighan, Reference Finighan2015, p. 5).

Next, and related, is that the benefit of stating this ambition in the present journal could be amplified by extending the discussion beyond the echo chamber of other behavioural public policy practitioners. There is a lot to learn about the opportunities that SSH identified by reaching out to academics and even commercial organisations. For better or for worse, we can be sure that giants like Facebook are researching social diffusion, and there could be much for policy-makers to learn from those insights as they are exploring ‘network nudges’ (Chambers, Reference Chambers2014). Looking towards the newest technology, others are exploring how machine learning could identify different subgroups of people to facilitate targeted and personalised interventions, mitigating the risk of unintended consequences from blanket nudges that do not work on everyone in the population (Risdon, Reference Risdon2017).

Once armed with a full suite of tools, both standard and behavioural, and learning from a range of forward-looking sources, a potentially useful way to approach behaviour change given the limitations on impact assessment discussed above is to follow the Royal Society for the Encouragement of Arts, Manufacture and Commerce's advice to “think like a system, act like an entrepreneur.” What they mean by thinking like a system is to try to understand not only the individual person-level motivations for a given behaviour, but also the social and hierarchical pressures, all while recognising that systems are complex and messy. Acting like an entrepreneur is to appreciate that one will never be able to fully understand or measure everything, but nevertheless should seek opportunities to create change where needed rather than preserving the status quo (Burbidge, Reference Burbidge2017). Although we cannot be completely certain of the isolated impact of each intervention, there is some expectation that small wins accumulate towards making a meaningful dent in wicked problems.

And not all impact is from interventions. Behavioural science, and psychology more generally, is extremely useful for giving people a shared language to talk about common experiences and tendencies. Perhaps this is not directly relevant to shaping policy itself, but it is potentially valuable for some of the opportunities identified by SSH, such as when trying to nudge organisations or government. For example, speaking with colleagues about the ‘planning fallacy’ or ‘present bias’ may help grease a conversation about project timelines and what types of ‘commitment devices’ may be useful for staying on track; it may make the difference between the colleague feeling personally attacked for their self-perceived character flaws and feeling like this is support needed for any ‘normal’ human being.

Clear skies?

When describing the origins of BIT, SSH write about their guiding principles and strategy. These seem to be right and admirable intentions and a pragmatic approach. However, there is still an awkward and open question around the mantra ‘nudge for good’. It is certainly better than ‘nudge for bad’, but, even with good intentions, does the choice architect always know what is in someone else's best interest? What may be good for many might be bad for others. How does one avoid harming a group, especially the most vulnerable among us?Footnote 1 The authors themselves point out that one of the challenges of behavioural public policy is unintended consequences. What happens when an improvement in one outcome measure results in a degradation of another? Or when an intervention results in someone being objectively better off (e.g., by having more saved for retirement) but subjectively worse off (e.g., by increased anxiety juggling lower finances day to day), or vice versa?

These issues of paternalism, population heterogeneity and trade-offs are not unique to behavioural public policy, and are important questions for any policy-maker or any behavioural science practitioner to reflect upon. However, these questions are perhaps especially important for government and other institutional bodies, where issues of both choice and trust come into play. An informed consumer may choose to avoid buying goods or services from a particular company, but one cannot (easily) choose to opt out of participating in civic society.Footnote 2 Therefore, ethical considerations should always be top of the mind because while ‘nudge for good’ can and should be the North Star, the sky is not always cloudless, however good the intentions.

Conclusion

In the American Economic Review, Richard Thaler wrote that, in the best case “…the term ‘behavioral economics’ will eventually disappear from our lexicon. All economics will be as behavioral as the topic requires…” (Reference Thaler2016, p. 1597). The same could be argued about behavioural public policy. We will know that behavioural public policy has reached its height when the word ‘behavioural’ is redundant, when public policy uses behavioural insight as standard alongside its many other tools and is simply seen as ‘public policy done well’.

In terms of the questions in the title of SSH's paper – “where are we now and where are we going?” – some things are clear. More work is needed around understanding and delivering the ideal of long-term, monotonically positive social impact. To help achieve that, there are journals such as this one pushing practitioners, academics and behavioural science enthusiasts to contemplate both the successes and, importantly, the shortcomings of the field. We should be mindful to bring other disciplines into the fold of these discussions in order to collectively seek continuous improvement, always guided by the North Star of ‘nudge for good’.

Acknowledgements

With thanks to William Mailer and Etinosa Agbonlahor for their substantive feedback on an earlier version. Any errors are mine.

Disclosure

This article was written in a personal capacity and does not reflect the views of my employer.

Footnotes

1 The use of machine learning, as described earlier, may help to segment people and provide tailored interventions.

2 Admittedly, it may not be easy for someone to recognise that companies are using behavioural science, and indeed that naïveté may contribute to the ‘success’ of its use in certain contexts.

References

Burbidge, I. (2017), ‘Altered States’, RSA Journal, 5569(1): 1015.Google Scholar
Chambers, C. (July 2014), Facebook fiasco: was Cornell's study of ‘emotional contagion’ an ethics breach? The Guardian. Online. Accessed 02/12/2017 from https://www.theguardian.com/science/head-quarters/2014/jul/01/facebook-cornell-study-emotional-contagion-ethics-breach.Google Scholar
Churchman, C. (1967), ‘Wicked Problems’, Management Science, 14(4): B-141-B-146. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.14.4.B141.Google Scholar
Finighan, R. (2015), Beyond Nudge: The Potential of Behavioural Policy, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, the University of Melbourne.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. (2015), Risk savvy: How to make good decisions, Penguin.Google Scholar
Hallsworth, M., J.A., List, R.D., Metcalfe and I., Vlaev (2017), ‘The behavioralist as tax collector: using natural field experiments to enhance tax compliance’, Journal of Public Economics, 148: 1431.Google Scholar
Risdon, C. (October 2017), Scaling Nudges with Machine Learning. Behavioral Scientist blog. Online. Accessed 02/12/2017 from http://behavioralscientist.org/scaling-nudges-machine-learning/.Google Scholar
Sanders, M., Snijders, V. and Hallsworth, M. (2018), ‘Behavioural science and policy: where are we now and where are we going?Behavioural Public Policy, 2(2): 144167.Google Scholar
Soman, D. (2015), The last mile: Creating social and economic value from behavioral insights, University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. (2016), ‘Behavioral Economics: Past Present and Future’, American Economic Review, 106(7): 15771600.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. (2017), Much Ado About Nudging. Behavioural Public Policy blog. Online. Accessed 25/11/2017 from https://bppblog.com/2017/06/02/much-ado-about-nudging/.Google Scholar
Wicked Problems: problems worth solving. Website. Accessed on 25/11/2017 from https://www.wickedproblems.com/1_wicked_problems.php.Google Scholar
World Bank (2015), World development report 2015: Mind, society, and behavior. World Bank.Google Scholar