Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T16:13:08.204Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part I - Cross-Cutting Foundations and Norms for the Sharing Economy of Tomorrow

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 March 2023

Babak Heydari
Affiliation:
Northeastern University, Boston
Ozlem Ergun
Affiliation:
Northeastern University, Boston
Rashmi Dyal-Chand
Affiliation:
Northeastern University, Boston
Yakov Bart
Affiliation:
Northeastern University, Boston

Summary

Type
Chapter
Information
Reengineering the Sharing Economy
Design, Policy, and Regulation
, pp. 11 - 114
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

2 A Sociotechnical Ecosystem Perspective of Sharing Economy Platforms

Babak Heydari
2.1 Introduction

In barely more than a decade, sharing economy platforms transitioned from venues for true sharing of underused assets by people with social and environmental motivations, to a number of for-profit – although not always profit making – corporations worth tens of billions of dollars each, to a pillar for coping with the COVID-19 pandemic that enabled easier access to essential resources. The short, yet intense, history of the sharing economy is filled with overoptimism about its business potential and social consequences. This history reveals sharp contrasts between the high valuation of sharing companies and concerns about their potential for sustainable profit-making. It also features public debates regarding the consequences of sharing economy business models for the participating labor forces, reports of discrimination and user abuse, and concerns regarding the broader negative social and economic externalities of these platforms.

The debates over the costs and benefits of sharing economy platforms have been vast and have engaged a multitude of disciplines such as business and management science, economics, computer science, and different engineering disciplines, sociology, law, and public policy. Each of these disciplines has naturally focused on a limited set of problems and tried to understand these platforms through levels of abstractions established in those disciplines. For example, for economists, the multisided market has been the dominant level of abstraction by which many platforms’ strategic decisions and market dynamics have been studied, whereas the notion of matching, and efficiency, and equity of various matching algorithms has been the center of attention for operations researchers and management scientists. Much of the social science literature on the subject has focused on the macroeconomic context, the evolution of capitalism, and the potential of sharing platforms to abuse their workers. And the list of disciplines/concerns/levels of abstraction goes on.

These disciplinary approaches are crucial because they not only are rigorous and subject to peers’ scrutiny, but they also provide valuable methodologies to be used in interdisciplinary and system-level studies. However, many important questions that must be addressed in order to understand the underlying trade-offs of sharing economy platforms, and in order to provide useful insights to some of the debates mentioned earlier, fall at the boundaries and intersections of different levels of abstraction and require a system-level approach. Key questions arise at the boundary between multisided markets and the employee/contractor debate, at the intersection of economic externalities and the evolution of social norms, and at the intersection of matching algorithms and regulatory design. A systemic perspective on sharing platforms adds other benefits as well. Such benefits follow from two premises: First, that a holistic approach, which focuses on the relationship between different parts of the system, will provide additional useful insights; and second, that using a systemic perspective enables us to transfer findings, experiences, and insights between contexts that seem different in detail, but have enough system-level commonalities to justify such transfers.

My overarching thesis in this chapter is that many of the fundamental challenges of sharing economy platforms can best be understood and dealt with by considering these platforms embedded in a sociotechnical ecosystem. This perspective, which is the first contribution of this chapter, builds upon the diverse literature on business and industry ecosystems, but it is a departure from a narrow view of ecosystems that is focused mostly on business decisions from the perspective of the platform owner. In justifying this new perspective, I will first make a case for a sociotechnical approach to sharing economy platforms and will describe different lenses that constitute this approach. Then I will argue that many crucial questions about the design, governance, and regulation of sharing economy platforms are best formulated by embedding the platform in a sociotechnical ecosystem, which is a departure from the more common notion of business and industry ecosystems. To further justify this transition, I will provide a few examples of such ecosystem-motivated issues and questions that include a broader consideration of socioeconomic externalities, decisions about modes of platform governance and the relative weight of internal versus external regulations, and public–private partnerships.

My second contribution in this chapter is to provide a set of differentiating dimensions that can help with classifying various sharing economy platforms, guide decisions regarding ecosystem boundaries, and shape more relevant sociotechnical questions and hypotheses for a given sharing economy. These differentiating dimensions intend to serve a middle ground for two schools of thought, one that stipulates that each sharing platform needs to be treated as a separate case and there is little insight that can be transferred from one platform type to another, and the other that seeks to create levels of abstractions for studying the sharing economy platforms that are applicable to all such platforms. Establishing such differentiating dimensions, instead, acknowledges that the answer to many fundamental design, governance, and regulation questions can vary from one platform to another; however, it strives to further pin down those dependencies by identifying various classes of sharing platforms to enable more reliable transfer of insight from one case to another and determine when such transfers make sense. In so doing, it helps to create models and methods that can work for all members of each class.

2.2 The Sociotechnical Approach: Why and What?

Sociotechnical systems and the sociotechnical perspective have been used in different contexts and different applications in the past few decades. The notion is based on the pioneering works by Eric Trist in the 1950s and 1960s at the Tavistock Institute for Social Research in London (Trist Reference Trist1981), and later found its way to other fields and applications such as sustainability (Geels Reference Geels2019), innovation management (Geels Reference Geels2005), energy systems (Li, Trutnevyte, and Strachan Reference Li, Trutnevyte and Strachan2015), and digital ecosystems (Morgan-Thomas, Dessart, and Veloutsou Reference Morgan-Thomas, Dessart and Veloutsou2020). Such applications often involve important changes in the definition, scope, and goals of the approach, which makes it hard, and largely unhelpful, to provide a unifying definition that includes all uses of the term in the academic literature. Suffices to say that while the focus of the first generation of studies using a sociotechnical approach was primarily on guiding the innovation and change process in an industry ecosystem, the notion of sociotechnical has resurfaced in recent years to make a case for an integrated approach towards design, governance, and regulation of modern engineered systems. This recent attention is motivated by recognizing that such systems are increasingly connected, with complex interactions among social and technical aspects, both during the design process and after introduction in the market. Moreover, the technical side of these systems coevolves with the social and institutional sides (Heydari and Pennock Reference Heydari and Pennock2018), a feature with broad implications for design, governance, and regulation.

With this contemporary perspective of sociotechnical systems, I argue that sharing platforms are paradigmatic examples of complex sociotechnical systems (Heydari and Herder Reference Heydari, Herder, Maier, Oehmen and Vermaas2021). They involve multiple classes of social agents (mostly individual humans, but also groups and organizations in some cases) with heterogeneous types on different sides of the platform, whose relationships are dynamically regulated by the structure and behavior of the platform. In a way, sharing platforms also make a great case study for the so-called technological systems approach (Carlsson and Stankiewicz Reference Carlsson and Stankiewicz1991) that looks at “networks of agents interacting in a specific technology area under a particular institutional infrastructure to generate, diffuse, and utilize technology.” The interaction between the social and technical sides, however, goes beyond the usual dynamics seen in most engineering systems where the dynamics are often unidirectional and include adaptation of the social layer to changes in the technical layer (e.g., changes in human travel patterns following the prevalence of commercial airplanes). Instead, in many sharing economy platforms, the social and technical sides often coevolve, where new local or population-level norms are formed on the social side, as a function of the structure of the platform (e.g., basic modules of transactions or spatiotemporal constraints) and the function of platform algorithms (matching criteria, level of transparency, review aggregation methods, and pricing strategies). This combination of platform structure and function can give rise to new social norms or steer the existing ones. Examples of such norms include trust, cooperation, equity and fairness, communication norms among different sides of the market, and how platform users balance some trade-offs such as those between data privacy and match efficiency. These evolutions in norms and collective behavior then result in evolutionary changes in the platforms, either through shifts in the way people prioritize different considerations to balance various trade-offs, or, increasingly, as a result of artificial intelligence algorithms that learn to adjust platform behavior in response to such changes.

This sociotechnical perspective, which is based on recognizing a coevolutionary dynamic between the social and technical side, can be captured by the sociotechnical triangle (Figure 2.1). These three lenses are crucial in many aspects of the sharing economy, informing core questions such as the following: How can we design modular architecture and algorithmic incentives to promote trust between different sides of transactions? How can we balance external regulation and self-regulation, based on platform internal governance mechanisms? How can we think about and measure neighborhood externalities of platforms such as Airbnb in the short term and long term?

Figure 2.1 Three components of a sociotechnical approach to sharing economy platforms.

2.3 The Ecosystem Perspective: Moving from Business to Sociotechnical Ecosystems

The mutual dynamic perspective described earlier goes beyond the interaction of platform design and participants’ behavior and often extends to other areas such as technology and regulation. This extended perspective would then require us to think of sharing economy platforms in a broader ecosystem, the second lens of a systemic perspective. In this section, I will argue that we need to make a transition from the more common notion of business and industrial ecosystems to the more contemporary and expansive notion of sociotechnical ecosystems. The need for such a transition is not restricted to sharing economy platforms, but as I will argue in more detail, it is more crucial for these types of systems due to some of their characteristics that are either unique or are bolder compared to other products’ or services’ ecosystems.

The notion of business ecosystems entered the management-science and product-design literature as an alternative to the more linear supply-chain framework, largely through the influential writings of James F. Moore during the 1990s. The framework was inspired by the notion of biological ecosystems, which capture complexity-related concepts such as self-organization, coevolution, emergence of new forms and behaviors, and complex dynamics of simultaneous competition and cooperation. In one of his first publications to introduce the concept, Moore suggests that, “a company be viewed not as a member of a single industry but as part of a business ecosystem that crosses a variety of industries. In a business ecosystem, companies coevolve capabilities around a new innovation: They work cooperatively and competitively to support new products, satisfy customer needs, and eventually incorporate the next round of innovations” (Moore, Reference Moore1993, p. 76). The concept was then further developed by a number of other scholars in the past two decades and applied to a wide range of cases in different industries (Adner and Kapoor Reference Adner and Kapoor2010; Autio and Thomas Reference Autio, Thomas, Dodgson, Gann and Phillips2014; Iansiti and Levien Reference Iansiti and Levien2004; Pierce Reference Pierce2009). Given the metaphoric nature of the concept, however, not all the studies that use the notion of ecosystem as a framework agree on a common definition (see Tsujimoto et al. [2018] for a review of the literature).

The ecosystem perspective of industry platforms has also been introduced in the past, often in a narrower sense, which includes the combination of a multisided platform, a set of related firms that develop their complementary products and services, and in some cases, the end users (Cusumano, Gawer, and Yoffie Reference Cusumano, Gawer and Yoffie2019). This perspective of platform ecosystems has been used primarily to model and provide recommendations for two different faces of innovation that occur within and outside the platform-owning firm (Gawer and Cusumano Reference Gawer and Cusumano2014), or to inform organization designers to opt for a more suitable organization structure, level of openness, and degrees of product and organizational modularity (Baldwin Reference Baldwin2012, Heydari, Mosleh, and Dalili. 2016). Although various definitions for platform ecosystems are offered in the literature, the majority of these definitions are focused either on the technology or on the markets. In the former, platform ecosystems are considered, as “a set of stable components that supports variety and evolvability in a system by constraining the linkages among the other components” (Baldwin and Woodard Reference Baldwin, Woodard and Gawer2009), while in the latter, they focus on issues such as network externalities across different platform sides, market competition among different platforms, and the complementary roles of firms whose products are designed based on one or more platforms (e.g., smartphone platforms or cloud computing platforms). Although different in their components, both these approaches have focused on the perspectives of platform owners (Schreieck, Wiesche, and Krcmar Reference Schreieck, Wiesche and Krcmar2016) to inform their business decisions.

Here, I argue that we need a broader sense of ecosystems for sharing economy platforms that goes beyond innovation modeling and business complementors and extends the ecosystem boundary to include a broader range of stakeholders. This extended notion of platform ecosystem helps with formulating more relevant questions regarding analysis, design, governance, and regulation of sharing economy platforms. It also helps in creating shared value between the platform owner and the societal stakeholders (Porter and Kramer 2011, Rong et al. Reference Rong, Li, Peng, Zhou and Shi2021), which then can be addressed using the sociotechnical perspective mentioned earlier.

The need for a more expansive view of ecosystems isn’t limited to sharing economy platforms. In fact, it can be applied to a wide range of products and services. Having said that, this need is particularly bold for certain platform-based companies and sharing economy platforms in particular for a at least three interrelated reasons. For one thing, many of these platforms are taking up parts of the roles of public infrastructures, making them essential for the socioeconomic wellbeing of many regions. Moreover, there are many potential negative and positive externalities that touch various corners of the social fabric, especially in urban environments, because these platforms change the meaning of ownership and blur the line between what is business and what is personal use. Finally, these platforms are one of the key contributors to a rapidly evolving notion of work, both for those who directly use these platforms and those whose previous forms of work are being disrupted by sharing platforms. In what follows, I will elaborate more on the components (Figure 2.2) and benefits of this expansive view of the sharing-platforms ecosystem.

Figure 2.2 Sharing economy platforms ecosystem components

A. A Broader Perspective of Externalities: The literature on platform systems has always been cognizant of externalities, with most of the attention being focused on network externalities, also known as network effect. The discussion thus has focused on how additional agents who use the platform affect the utility of other agents who are on the platform. In addition to this – often positive – externality, critiques of sharing economy platforms sometimes point to potential negative externalities of such platforms based on their negative impact on others who do not use the platform. One example of such indirectly affected people are neighborhood residents who might be negatively affected by Airbnb (Gurran and Phibbs Reference Gurran and Phibbs2017), or who might be affected by increased congestion caused by ride sharing (Schaller Reference Schaller2021). Other examples are workers and owners of incumbent industries, such as hotels owners and employees who might be affected by Airbnb (Roma, Panniello, and Lo Nigro Reference Roma, Panniello and Lo Nigro2019; Zervas, Proserpio, and Byers Reference Zervas, Proserpio and Byers2017), or Medallion owners and cab drivers who might be affected by Uber (Angrist, Caldwell, and Hall Reference Angrist, Caldwell and Hall2017; Rogers Reference Rogers2015). The ecosystem view of sharing platforms leads us to think more broadly about externalities, especially when it comes to their regulation and the evaluation of their overall effect on social welfare.

First, the scope of platform externalities should be expanded in the range of stakeholders who are affected. Importantly, the scope should also include efforts to understand the mechanisms by which externalities affect certain stakeholders. For example, on the supplier side, in addition to the dyad of platform and incumbent workers, sharing platforms could trigger creation of a number of complementary businesses whose owners and employees are not technically platform users, but they provide facilitating services to platform users. Airbnb, for example, resulted in the emergence of a series of start-up companies and local businesses that help the hosts by providing them with cleaning services (Flycleaners), management (Beyond stay, Keycafe), guest communications (Guesty), marketing (Renting your place), and pricing analytics (Pricelabs, Beyond Pricing). Airbnb also helped stimulate local businesses such as professional photographers and property managers. Moreover, the penetration of sharing economy platforms into urban neighborhoods can stimulate local businesses by bringing visitors to otherwise residential neighborhoods, which in turn can result in potential positive externalities for neighborhood residents because of improvements in service quality, or negative externalities due to potential increase in prices. Measuring the relative magnitude of these two factors requires comprehensive empirical studies, something that the research community of sharing platforms could consider in the future.

We also need to consider the interplatform interactions as a particular instance of broadening the scope of externalities. Such interplatform interactions could happen across different platforms that provide similar services whose interactions go beyond the widely studied competition (Armstrong Reference Armstrong2006; Rochet and Tirole Reference Rochet and Tirole2003) and in some cases can involve cross-platform positive network effects that can become more complex than the usual single-platform network effect often discussed in the literature. For example, growing an initial group of drivers is often easier for a new ride-hailing company that enters a city with an existing base of drivers who work with a competing company. It might also be easier to attract the first group of customers who already have gone through the learning curve of a similar concept with a competing platform. More important, however, is the interaction of complementary platforms, as happens for example in the case of ride-sharing and short-term rental platforms (Zhang et al. Reference Zhang, Lee, Singh and Mukhopadhyay2020), where easier and more affordable access to transportation into residential neighborhoods enabled by ride-sharing platforms makes short-term rentals more attractive for prospective visitors, which in turn results in more use of ride-sharing services, once those visitors decide to stay in the residential neighborhoods. Other examples include interaction of short-term rental companies with travel and hospitality platforms such as TripAdvisor, Yelp, and Urbanspoon. Although much of the discussions in these areas are anecdotal, we can expect that in the coming years, new network externality models with the goal of formulating and quantifying a more general notion of network effect will emerge in the academic literature of sharing economy platforms.

Beside the expansion in scope, one needs to differentiate between the short- versus longer-term externalities, with special attention to the latter, which are often more difficult to identify and measure. The longer-term view is crucial, primarily for two reasons. First, the prevalence of sharing platforms can change the structure of social interactions and impact local norms, sense of belonging, and social capital, a rather slow process in nature. Such changes, in turn, can result in changes in collective behavior, with possible negative consequences for local residents. For example, a recent study by (Ke, O’Brien, and Heydari Reference Ke, O’Brien and Heydari2021) demonstrates that spatial penetration of Airbnb (as opposed to merely the number of Airbnb visitors) in a neighborhood can result in an increase in criminal activities in subsequent years, presumably due to its negative effect on the overall sense of belonging by removing a set of long-term resident nodes from the neighborhood social interaction network.

B. Regulation and Governance in Platform Ecosystems: Regulating sharing economy platforms has been a controversial issue (See the Chapter 7 in this volume), with some scholars going so far as to conclude that successful regulatory avoidance is one of the main driving forces behind the rapid growth of sharing platforms (Stemler Reference Stemler2017). Various categories of regulations include platform-user protections, competition and antitrust concerns, taxes, privacy concerns, discrimination, and other forms of market failures. Here, I briefly emphasize two points, related to the ecosystem perspective.

B. 1. Public–Private Partnership: First, the relationship between governments and platform owners needs to include public–private partnerships. Public–private collaborations have largely been discussed in the context of urban mobility as a way to make urban transportation more accessible, affordable, and efficient. They can be implemented at various levels, such as dynamic trip-planning, on-demand minibuses, and first- and last-mile ride sharing (Bouton, Canales, and Trimble, Reference Bouton, Canales and Trimblen.d.); Also see (Chapters 8 and 9 in this volume.). More recently and with the goal of establishing trust between the platform and local governments, Airbnb has introduced City Portal in fifteen pilot cities in North America, which claims to streamline information about various travel-related trends to provide cities with more information about their Airbnb businesses, share with them detailed data that they can use for their urban resource-management activities, and provide easy-to-use tools for city officials to design and implement short-term rental policies (Airbnb n.d.). Although it is likely that sharing economy companies enter such partnerships as a public-relations activity to avoid strict regulations down the road, successful public–private partnership can have a wide range of public benefits by increasing access to financial resources for public infrastructures, contributing to efficient dynamic resource allocation using analytics collected by sharing platforms, and offering efficient solutions for the last-mile problem in many transportation and logistics services. However, not all public–private partnerships based on sharing economy platforms are successful, and it remains a crucial area of research to identify determinants of success and failure based on the differentiating characteristics of sharing economy platforms (see Part IV).

B.2. Public Mediated Governance: Even when we restrict our attention to the regulatory role of governments, we need to think beyond restrictions that are implemented to limit negative externalities and avoid different forms of market failures. Although such regulations are needed in some cases, they often tend to be static, responding to yesterday’s problems. The interaction of such static, reactive rules with dynamic, adaptive algorithms used by platforms and some of their users could result in undesirable (game-theoretic) equilibria. Meanwhile, platform owners often argue that regulatory frameworks that were designed for incumbent industries (e.g., hotels or taxi cabs) do not apply to them, in part because they can self-regulate by leveraging a wide range of algorithmic platform governance mechanisms that are available to them. In a way, this argument tries to extrapolate from the success of marketplace platforms in efficient dynamic matching of market sides (thereby shaping supply and demand via dynamic pricing) to make a case for the efficacy of self-regulation. This claim holds that those adaptable, dynamic algorithms can be extended to other areas where the sociotechnical behaviors in the ecosystem need to be steered, based on the objectives that the regulator has in mind. Such a solution could draw elements from both the market and regulatory perspectives. Much of the concerns of regulators can still be addressed using internal algorithmic governance that can be embedded into the design of the platform; however, the design specifications, objectives, prioritization of conflicting goals, and the verification processes cannot be left solely in the hands of the platform owners and must be determined by what I refer to as public-mediated platform governance. Given the complexity of platform regulation and the increasing prevalence of platforms, I expect that questions on the relative role of external regulation versus public-mediated governance, the implementation mechanisms for the latter, and the role of citizens in providing inputs to some of the key decisions of platform governance will be key areas of research and public discussion in the coming decade.

2.4 Building a Taxonomy for Sharing Economy Ecosystems

The ecosystem perspective of sharing economy platforms is useful in formulating a number of important questions, some of them related to the discussions offered in this section. For example, how many of the goals of the regulator can be achieved using external regulation as opposed to platform-mediated governance? How widely should regulators look in capturing the effects of positive and negative externalities in order to make regulatory decisions? Or when it comes to internal platform design and governance: How much control does the platform owner need to exert on transaction details, pricing, and active matching of different sides of the market? How much transparency, modularity, and openness are optimal for platforms in order to balance the trade-off between competition and growing their ecosystem? How actively does the platform owner need to intervene to establish trust between different sides of platform transactions and how can the platform owner balance this need with the privacy concerns of users? How much should platform owners and public agencies pursue public–private partnerships?

The short answer to all these questions is that it depends, and the answer varies for different types of platforms and different characteristics of the ecosystem in which they are embedded. But can we go further than this short answer? How can we know, more specifically, what drives the answer to these questions? In this section, I take the first steps in digging beyond that short answer by providing a number of key dimensions that amount to a taxonomy of sharing economy systems that can help us answer different ecosystem-related questions. In addition to setting forth some important differentiating dimensions, I explain why those dimensions are important and provide a few examples of how those dimensions affect some of the key questions related to platform control or governance. I intend in this section to use broad brush strokes in describing the driving forces active in each dimension. A comprehensive description for any given platform will require a more thorough mapping of the ecosystem, more precise formulation of the questions using the sociotechnical approach, and further modeling and empirical work.

The taxonomy I provide here differs from other taxonomies of sharing economy platforms. Although some comprehensive classification studies have been conducted in recent years (Acquier, Daudigeos, and Pinkse Reference Acquier, Daudigeos and Pinkse2017; Benoit et al. Reference Benoit, Baker, Bolton, Gruber and Kandampully2017), the majority of these classification efforts have focused on making sense of the variety of business models used by sharing platforms, either as a whole (Muñoz and Cohen Reference Muñoz and Cohen2017; Sanasi et al. Reference Sanasi, Ghezzi, Cavallo and Rangone2020), or in a particular sector or essential component such as mobility (Cohen and Kietzmann Reference Cohen and Kietzmann2014), hospitality (Kuhzady et al. Reference Kuhzady, Olya, Farmaki and Ertaş2021), and logistics (Carbone, Rouquet, and Roussat Reference Carbone, Rouquet and Roussat2018). However, my goal is to introduce a number of dimensions that could be used to better approach the ecosystem-driven questions, some of which I presented in the previous section. Furthermore, these dimensions can be used in conjunction with the sociotechnical approach that brings together the engineering design, business models, and regulatory and governance aspects of sharing economy platforms.

2.4.1 Key Differentiating Dimensions of Sharing Economy Platforms

A. What is shared: Sharing economy platforms are used to share resources among different platform participants; yet it is not often immediately obvious what is shared on these platforms. Here I divide the shareable object into three categories: Information, physical assets, and labor. Although many platforms share a combination of these objects, for most of them, one of these objects is more distinct, which in turn determines some important characteristics of the platform.

A.1. Information: Given the digital nature of modern sharing economy platforms, information sharing is often at the heart of how these platforms operate. In fact, the information intensity of a service or product is a strong predictor of its propensity to become a successful platform. We need, however, to distinguish between cases in which information is shared between the platform and its users, and those where platform-enabled information exchange among users is the main function of the platform. The first type of information sharing is ubiquitous among multisided platforms and serves two intertwined functions. Information shared with the platform by the users reduces various forms of transaction costs for other types of transactions; for example, data about users’ locations, preferences, past transactions, and social networks can facilitate the search and matching process. This high-resolution data, provided voluntarily by the users to serve such functions, can then be used by platform owners to generate additional revenue, often in the form of direct or indirect advertisements.

Apart from this ubiquitous form of user–platform information sharing, information can be the main object of exchange in many multisided platforms such as LinkedIn (job-related information between employers and jobseekers), Yelp and Angie’s List (information about business quality), and StackExchange (questions and answers [Q&A]). Whether all these companies can be classified as sharing economy platforms is not fully clear and depends on the breadth of the definition one uses for the sharing economy. I would argue that Q&A services such as StackExchange better satisfy the narrower definition of the sharing economy, compared to companies such as LinkedIn or Yelp. This is because, unlike Yelp or LinkedIn where information exchange is not targeted, transactions on StackExchange are targeted sharing that happens between two parties (questioner and responder) and are driven by differences in the ownership level of a resource (expertise in this case). In my classification, while I recognize the ubiquitous role of information sharing in all digital platforms, I only consider information as the main transaction object when platforms can be classified as sharing economy systems and are used primarily for exchange of information among users.Footnote 1

A.2. Physical Assets and Labor: Although information can be the main article of exchange for some sharing platforms, the majority of these platforms are founded to facilitate the sharing of either physical assets or human labor, and some of the key characteristics of sharing platforms can be linked to the relative importance of these two different types of sharing articles.

The first generation of sharing platforms was mostly based on sharing unused physical assets, primarily in transportation (unused car seats in the early days of BlaBlaCar) and lodging (Couchsurfing and the early version of Airbnb). The choice of physical assets (as opposed to digital assets) to identify the first generation of sharing economy is a conscious choice – to satisfy the standard definition of sharing economy platforms mentioned earlier. However, I acknowledge that virtual mechanisms such as digital right management or non-fungible tokens that can artificially introduce scarcity in digital assets can in theory enable forms of platform-based sharing of digital assets that are closer to how we define sharing economy platforms here.

B. Transaction Heterogeneity (and Uncertainty): Heterogeneity, also known as diversity in some contexts, is an important common feature of complex systems that creates a fundamental system-level trade-off, enabling adaptability, evolution, and resilience on the one hand, and making it harder to predict, manage, and change the systems on the other. Moreover, higher heterogeneity may result in higher uncertainty, making it more challenging to manage resources and predict their supply and demand. Much of the complexity management in complex engineering systems revolves around implementing an appropriate level of heterogeneity at various layers (e.g., products, agents, modes, and rules of interactions) to balance this trade-off. The dominant system design mechanism uses the principle of modularity, which works in two steps. It first maps a large number of possible realizations of heterogeneous attributes to a smaller set of modules. It then creates standard interfaces that facilitate interaction between different modules.

Managing transaction heterogeneity is a key differentiating attribute among various sharing economy platforms. These platforms face at least two layers of heterogeneity when it comes to transactions they enable: Spatiotemporal heterogeneity, and agent’s type diversity. As I will discuss, while managing the former type has been instrumental in the success of most sharing platforms, the latter plays a major role in the governance schemes of the platforms.

B.1. Spatiotemporal Heterogeneity is the very basic form of heterogeneity and refers to the diversity relating to when and where the demand or supply for articles of transactions occur. Traditionally this type of heterogeneity was managed by creating spatiotemporal modules, for example, by creating stations and timetables for public transportation systems. This form of spatiotemporal heterogeneity was in fact a major barrier for peer-to-peer (P2P) platforms until recently, and a key value for on-demand platforms such as Uber and Lyft is their successful management of this aspect of heterogeneity, thanks to the prevalence of smartphone devices, accurate supply and demand prediction, and demand and supply shaping through different incentive mechanisms. These mechanisms make it possible to modularize the unit of transaction to a more or less standard product, such as a ride to the airport, or a standard bedroom on a second floor in the Alfama neighborhood in Lisbon in the second week of June. As we will see, such modularization becomes challenging as other forms of heterogeneity are added.

B.2. Agents Heterogeneity: Besides differences in the time and location of supply and demand, participating agents on a platform can be different in other aspects such as preferences, skills, and reliability. I refer to all these other aspects as agent type. Although this dimension of heterogeneity is also present in most sharing platforms, the associated complexity of this dimension and the consequent governance mechanisms can vary substantially across different platforms. On one end of the spectrum lie platforms such as Uber and Lyft for which differences in agents’ types are either not large (e.g., driving skills), not of primary importance (e.g., make and model of the car, within a given vehicle category, or the personality of the driver), or can be ranked on a single dimension (e.g., safety and reliability). Mechanisms such as review help with standardizing the last group, since it is often expected that the reviews are not affected by heterogeneous, multidimensional preferences of platform users, and thus that much of the information about these attributes can be encapsulated in standardized review scores. As we move to the other end of the spectrum, agents’ differences become wider (e.g., skill level of professionals on Upwork), preferences become more heterogeneous on a wide range of dimensions (e.g., preferences of Airbnb users for the type of a $150/night apartment in Berlin), and the weights they assign to those preferences increase (e.g., Airbnb host personality).

What are the consequences of this dimension on platform governance? Using principles of modularity in complex systems, I argue that smaller heterogeneity range, significance, and dimension, enables creation of more standardized modules, which in turn opens the door for a higher level of control by the platform owner over different aspects of transactions. Standardized modules can enable control over pricing, where, for example, a “6:00am ride from downtown to the airport in a sedan” can be considered as a standard transaction module that can be priced. Lower dimensions of complexity also eliminate the need for direct exchange of information between different sides of the transaction, which in turn can enable algorithmic matching between them, further leaving transaction control in the hands of the platform owner. This contrasts with a platform like Airbnb that falls towards the middle of the spectrum, where heterogeneity, especially on the demand side inhibits automated matching, allows direct communication and negotiations between different sides, and leads the way to delegate much of the pricing decisions to the landlord. An example of a platform that resides close to the other end of the spectrum is ebay in which both sides of the platform (sellers and buyers) experience large multidimensional heterogeneities, which in turn push the platform owner to delegate a large portion of control to the users and to market mechanisms such as auctions.

C. Transaction Stakes: Sharing platforms can have different levels of transaction stakes as a function of various forms of risks associated with those transactions. Besides financial and safety risks, higher stakes can be the result of concerns about opportunity cost, poor experience, reputation, discrimination, and privacy. I also expect that, everything being equal, transactions with longer time commitments show higher stakes (a few minutes of an Uber ride, compared to a few days of Airbnb stay). The difference in the level of transaction stakes is crucial for platform governance, since it directly affects trust, which is central to the success of sharing platforms. In general, platforms with higher transaction stakes need stronger governance mechanisms to ensure a sufficient level of trust between different sides of the platform. These mechanisms include prescreening of users, mechanisms to ensure participation and quality of reviews, mechanisms to promote trust as an emergent collective norm among platform users, and transparent, punitive measures to deal with special cases. This is why Airbnb, which exercises less governance control compared to Uber in pricing and matching dimensions, demonstrates stronger control when it comes to trust mechanisms.

D. Time Urgency: I define time urgency as the average time between the availability of supply and demand and the execution of the actual transaction. Based on this definition, ride hailing applications often have a high level of time urgency, on the order of minutes, due to their on-demand nature, although the time urgency is generally lower for long distance carpooling platforms such as BlaBlacar. Lodging platforms such as Airbnb and Homeaway have a medium level of time urgency on the order of days to weeks. Labor matching platforms such as TaskRabbit and Upwork, on the other hand, are highly heterogeneous in their time-urgencies, which can range from hours to months depending on the nature of the service.

As for the impact of time urgency on platform values and their governance, it interacts with the two types of heterogeneity mentioned earlier – spatiotemporal and agent type – in two different ways. Higher time urgency increases the role of platforms in managing spatiotemporal heterogeneities for the reasons described earlier, thus adding to their value from their users’ perspective, while making it more possible for platforms to exert their control over on-demand transactions. As time urgency decreases, the overall value of the platform might decrease. This is because lower time urgency makes room for higher competition and creates the possibility of multi-homing where users simultaneously evaluate multiple platforms for the same type of transaction. Lower time urgency also increases the relative importance of agent type heterogeneities, which in turn forces the platform to relinquish some of its control.

E. Network Effect: Most sharing platforms owe most of their value to some form of network effect, at least in the earlier phases of their operation. In platform-mediated P2P markets, this network effect is often cross-sided, which means that users on one side are the source of value for users on the other sides, which in turn will increase the number of users on those sides, resulting in a positive feedback of constantly adding users – and value – to the platform. This increase in value as a result of positive cross-sided network effects manifests itself in the form of lower wait-time (e.g., for ride hailing passengers), lower idle time (e.g., for ride hailing drivers), wider geographical coverage (e.g., for Uber and Airbnb), and a more diverse set of choices. The network effect can be local or global, depending on the nature of what is shared on the platform and time urgency. In general, the network effect becomes more localized when transactions include physical assets and have higher time urgency. The scope of network effect is a key determinant of market competition forces and subsequent policy and regulations.

Although cross-sided network effect is often considered as one of the main reasons for the near-monopolistic behavior of sharing economy platforms, one needs to be cautious about its role as a barrier to entry in the long-run. One reason is that ironically, cross-sided network effect is technically not a network effect, since it often has little to do with the social network of users. This is in stark contrast to how network effect works for social media platforms where much of the value of the platform for users depends on the presence of the members of their social network on the platform. Switching to a different platform then requires a coordinated decision of social networks clusters, which is difficult to achieve in most cases. On the other hand, it is theoretically possible for a new ride-hailing platform to enter the market and establish the initial network by subsidizing rides and paying more to the drivers, similar to how Uber grew in its early days. Cross-sided network effects, however, can create barriers to entry for new platforms in the long run by enabling the economy of scale that is required to build certain physical and logistical infrastructures, favorable terms with other corporate partners, and public–private partnerships.

Sharing platforms can also demonstrate various degrees of same-sided network effect, where the value of the platform for users of one side is modulated by the number of other users on the same side. Some forms of same-sided network effects are more or less universal among most sharing platforms. For example, many platforms demonstrate negative effects related to short-term issues like congestion and competition (e.g., more passengers drive up the price and wait time on a Friday night). Other forms of same-sided network effects, however, can vary substantially across different platforms, depending on some of the characteristics discussed earlier. Reviews are one of the main mechanisms that create this same-sided network effect, where both the quantity and quality of reviews by other users can improve the choice quality for a user on the same side of the platform. Whether this type of same-sided network effect benefits from the social networks of users depends largely on the level of agent type heterogeneity. When agents are heterogeneous in type and in multiple dimensions, as discussed earlier, we can expect users to benefit more from structured same-sided network effect. For example, most people care little about who reviewed the Uber driver who is being matched to them, while learning that their friend enjoyed staying with a family-owned Airbnb in Barcelona would carry great weight. Consequently, platforms with higher agent-type heterogeneity could be more successful in establishing mechanisms for structured same-sided network effects as an additional barrier to entry. Regulators need to take on this often-neglected lens in addition to the commonly discussed cross-sided network effect.

2.5 Conclusion

Platform systems are touching various corners of our socioeconomic lives and are creating gray areas in many traditional dichotomies: Employees versus independent contractors, ownership versus access, external regulation versus self-regulation, public versus private, and competitive versus monopolistic markets. We can only benefit from the promise of sharing economy platforms, while addressing valid concerns about some of their negative consequences, by increasing our understanding of these grey areas, making choices among them, and understanding and quantifying the trade-offs between these choices. This chapter argued that this can best be achieved by establishing a sociotechnical ecosystem framework that includes a set of lenses borrowed from the sociotechnical approach towards complex systems, an ecosystem perspective that builds upon previous work on business and industry ecosystems, and a set of differentiating dimensions that can help with building classes of sharing economy platforms to create useful levels of modeling abstractions and enable transfer of insights across different platforms. However, more research and case-based studies must be conducted to take this framework to the next level, that is to fully operationalize it and better show its power vis-à-vis other existing frameworks in the literature. I leave this challenge for future research by the interdisciplinary community active in this area.

3 The Sharing Economy and Environmental Sustainability

Matthew J. Eckelman and Yuliya Kalmykova
3.1 Introduction

Sharing economy organizations advertise many types of benefits to users and society, including advancing environmental sustainability. A basic premise of sharing economy services is that they convert private, under-utilized assets into resources that are shared among a pool of users. From an environmental perspective, sharing is assumed to reduce private consumption and attendant energy use, resource demands, and emissions, thus allowing people to live ‘low-impact’ lifestyles. These benefits are influential, and the promise of efficient use of resources and environmental sustainability have been identified as important motivators for consumers’ participation in the sharing economy (Bocker and Meelen Reference Bocker and Meelen2017).

Meanwhile, the sustainability orientation of sharing economy companies varies dramatically. As manifested by the companies’ taglines and branding, housing and mobility platforms have typically framed themselves in terms of economic opportunity: ‘Airbnb: Earn money from your extra space’, ‘Uber: Get behind the wheel and get paid’. Among mobility platforms, Lyft stands out by investing in environmental sustainability through promoting hybrid and electric car rides and buying carbon offsets: ‘Every Lyft ride is fully carbon neutral’. Interviews of free home-sharing companies such as ‘Couchsurfing’, ‘Trustroots’ and ‘BeWelcome’, Voytenko Palgan, Zvolska, and Mont (Reference Voytenko Palgan, Zvolska and Mont2017) found that environmental sustainability is a core value for these businesses, but that there was no explicit message of environmental sustainability motivation on these companies’ websites. Instead, trust was emphasized as the core value.

On the other hand, goods sharing platforms are more often grounded in environmental sustainability, with taglines such as: ‘Our mission: save the world and enjoy delicious food in the meantime’ (https://medium.com/resq-club), ‘OLIO can help create a world in which nothing of value goes to waste’, ‘Rent instead of buying. Hygglo is good for environment’ (hygglo.se). These general observations have recently been confirmed by a systematic analysis of sustainability claims in the online and social media content of 121 sharing platforms (Geissinger et al. Reference Geissinger, Laurell, Oberg and Sandstrom2019), which found that all of the thirty-five identified sustainability-oriented platforms were focusing on goods sharing. In another study, 61 per cent of the food-sharing platforms in 100 cities made statements about environmental benefits. Yet, even in the goods-sharing sector, only a few platforms provided any evidence to substantiate achievement of these benefits (Davies et al. Reference Davies, Edwards, Marovelli, Morrow, Rut and Weymes2017).

As with many efforts related to environmental sustainability, in practice the reality is much more complicated than these straightforward claims suggest. The predicted environmental benefits are by no means assured and need to be researched carefully (Frenken Reference Frenken2017, Frenken and Schor Reference Frenken and Schor2019). Several observed consequences involve trade-offs between avoided consumption (e.g., from resources and pollution avoided in manufacturing) and increased use (e.g., energy use and emissions from traffic congestion). In some cases, preliminary estimates have been made to quantify such environmental sustainability trade-offs using tools such as life-cycle assessment (LCA) combined with real data from sharing economy platforms (Mi and Coffman Reference Mi and Coffman2019). Some estimates have also considered the rebound effect, where savings due to avoided purchases are actually applied to more consumption, which can be either less or more emissions-intensive than the original environmental savings (Plepys and Singh Reference Plepys, Singh and Mont2019).

This chapter will document the types of unintended consequences that have been observed for different sharing platforms, including for mobility, housing, and second-hand goods, many of which are mediated by the economic rebound effect. This chapter will also present the arguments and evidence to date on the question of how and whether the sharing economy is environmentally beneficial in its current manifestation, and what might be done to improve environmental outcomes. Section 3.2 will describe how sharing systems affect the environment, both directly and indirectly. Sharing systems are often characterized in economic terms; here the focus will instead be on physical consequences, such as shifts in consumption of materials and energy. Section 3.3 will review the nascent literature assessing the environmental sustainability of different sharing systems and identify patterns, both in terms of the methodologies underlying the studies as well as their findings. Based on past results and lessons learned from cases around the world, Section 3.4 will highlight further research opportunities and suggestions that have mitigated some unintended consequences and helped to advance environmental sustainability. Environmental sustainability is multi-factorial, encompassing many types of earth and environmental systems and resources. For simplicity, we will restrict the discussion of environmental sustainability to four aspects: material use and waste, energy use, and emissions.

3.2 The Physical Sharing Economy

One way to assess the environmental impact of sharing systems is to describe sharing transactions in physical terms by mapping their associated material and energy flows, to quantify unintended consequences and avoided emissions of manufacturing additional products, and to compare against conventional private consumption. The field of industrial ecology (IE) has long been applied to investigate these types of problems. From its founding, IE has used natural ecology as a metaphor for inspiring human systems of production and consumption, including the features of community, connectedness, and cooperation that describe many sharing economy activities (Ehrenfeld Reference Ehrenfeld2000). IE research is well developed in its investigation of shared production, particularly the inter-firm sharing of by-products or collective services, called ‘industrial symbiosis’ (Chertow Reference Chertow2000). Using by-products such as fly ash, for example, as a substitute for cement in concrete, avoids the need to dispose of the by-product and simultaneously reduces the amount of virgin production of cement. In physical terms, this means avoiding resources, energy, and emissions from quarrying, transportation of raw materials, cement production, transportation to the disposal site, as well as reducing burden on infrastructure such as roads, landfills, industrial equipment, and so on. Quantifying resource and emissions savings through avoided materials and energy is often done using the systems modelling tool of LCA, which is designed to capture environmental burdens of goods and services over their ‘life cycles’, that is including their production, use, and end-of-life (Eckelman and Chertow Reference Eckelman and Chertow2013). With the advent of large-scale, technology-enabled sharing economy platforms, IE and LCA are now being used increasingly to analyse shared consumption, again starting from the first principle of quantifying material and energy flows.

In transportation, the major physical flows associated with human mobility are the energy needed to move vehicles and the materials in the vehicles themselves. Shared transportation services can directly reduce these resource requirements in a number of ways. In terms of material resources, the availability and convenience of sharing services allows some people to forego the purchase of their own individual vehicles, which in turn avoids energy, water, and emissions associated with materials production and vehicle manufacturing. Shared transportation increases vehicle intensity of use and may cause vehicles to deteriorate faster. This can have both negative effects (physical vehicle must be replaced) as well as positive (new vehicle may be more efficient). For fuel, if each passenger is alone in a ride share vehicle all the way from origin to destination, then there is no clear energy advantage over using a private vehicle, assuming the two vehicles have comparable fuel economies; there may instead be a disadvantage due to additional driving in between hired rides. But, if the rideshare picks up or drops off additional passengers en route (as with UberPool), or if using a rideshare eliminates the need to search for parking at the destination, then some fuel use, associated emissions, and congestion may be avoided.

These shifts may have indirect benefits for health, particularly through reduced emissions and congestion that will be felt predominantly in urban areas, where the majority of ridesharing is occurring. Reduced emissions lower levels of hazardous urban air pollution, especially ozone to which automobile emissions are important precursors, with attendant health benefits from cleaner air. Reduced congestion has beneficial implications for pedestrian and bicycle safety, urban noise, road maintenance, worker productivity, and stress. However, unintended consequences may offset some or all of these direct and indirect benefits. Most notably, rideshare drivers who stay on the roads while waiting to respond to ride requests will contribute to fuel use, emissions, congestion, and ageing of their vehicles. This phenomenon would be the same compared to taxis trolling for fares but would not take place compared to private vehicles that remain in parking places when not in use. This raises the vital question of what transportation mode is actually being substituted by ridesharing. Is it taxi or private vehicle? Or (where available) is it public transit, bicycling, walking, or not taking the trip at all? When utilized at high capacity, buses and trains are much more energy efficient modes of transportation per passenger than private vehicles on a life-cycle basis (Chester and Horvath Reference Chester and Horvath2009), so a shift away from public transit toward ridesharing will likely increase energy use, in addition to reducing fare-based funding for infrastructure improvements.

Shared housing presents different physical flows and different types of direct and indirect consequences of sharing. Platforms such as Airbnb allow people to rent out a spare room or an entire apartment or home on a short-term basis, presumably substituting for staying in a hotel. In theory, this could lead to direct substitution of hotel goods and services, such as room air conditioning and lighting energy, consumables, and services associated with cleaning and turning over the room. However, these goods and services would be used in the shared housing instead, perhaps with lower efficiency due to smaller economies of scale. On a macro scale, shared housing could shift the market for hotels, leading to fewer being constructed, but the land parcels in question would presumably be used for other productive developments. Another potential direct physical effect relates to energy use: Hotels are frequently located in central, convenient locations, whereas shared housing is more spatially distributed, potentially leading to more transportation energy used when travelling to and from the shared housing site. Indirect environmental concerns are also primarily related to shifts in transportation. When many centrally located properties are used primarily for shared housing rather than residences, the people who previously lived there may move to locations outside of the city and become commuters, potentially increasing fuel use and congestion.

Finally, shared goods such as surplus food and materials represent another type of implicit environmental trade-off between direct and indirect benefits and costs. Surplus food or materials are themselves a physical flow whose sharing prevents their collection, saving fuel energy, and disposal in landfills or waste incinerators, saving valuable space and energy and avoiding landfill leachate and other types of waste management pollution. Goods sharing could contribute to the 3Rs (Reduce, Reuse, Recycle) principles of waste prevention by reducing packaging waste of new products and reusing products that are in good condition. Sharing is also a strategy under the Circular Economy concept that aims to maximize utility and value of the resources in use (Kalmykova, Sadagopan, and Rosado Reference Kalmykova, Sadagopan and Rosado2018). In addition, their sharing means that receivers do not have to purchase as much new food or materials, with savings of resources all the way up the supply chains of those goods. As with shared housing, the locations of the substituted and shared goods are a critical consideration. If the sharing location is closer than the primary store where goods would ordinarily be bought, then transportation energy could be saved. However, for food in particular, the variety that is available through sharing may not be adequate to cover dietary needs, and participants may end up making trips to primary stores anyway. So, while food and materials sharing appears to have clear avoided materials and waste management emissions benefits, the trade-offs associated with transportation are unclear and likely to depend on origin–destination locations, travel modes, and consumer shopping behaviour.

3.3 Evidence of Environmental Benefits or Disadvantages

A bevy of new data-driven research has emerged recently on the environmental implications of sharing economy practices, supplementing the mostly small-scale, anecdotal or model-based studies in the existing literature. This Section will review findings to date that have been published in open literature (as opposed to studies conducted or commissioned by companies themselves) and how they incorporate (or don’t) the relevant physical considerations outlined in Section 3.2.

3.3.1 Transportation

The most active research area on the sustainability of the sharing economy has been shared transportation. An early life-cycle impact study of car sharing (business-to-consumer, with fixed parking locations, as opposed to ride sharing) in the United States by Chen and Kockelman (Reference Chen and Kockelman2016) reported reduced car ownership, a decrease of vehicle-kilometres travelled (VKT) of 30–70 per cent, and reduction in greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions of approximately 50 per cent when compared to the car-sharing members’ travel before joining the sharing service or in comparison to their non-sharing neighbours. Among other environmental benefits were reduction in parking space demand and increase in use of public transit and non-motorized modes of travel, such as walking and bicycling. The greater intensities of use of the shared vehicles also led to a faster turnover, and subsequently to better fleet fuel economy as more efficient models are adopted. Similar results were found in a study of hundreds of car-sharing participants in the Netherlands (Nijland and van Meerkerk Reference Nijland and van Meerkerk2017). Importantly, the US study also examined rebound effects, which offset approximately 40 per cent of the environmental benefits as household cost savings were spent on other energy- and emissions-intensive goods and services (Chen and Kockelman Reference Chen and Kockelman2016).

In contrast, studies of ride sharing have mostly found environmental costs rather than benefits. Ride sharing has been connected to the decline in public transit system ridership (Graehler, Mucci, and Erhardt Reference Graehler, Mucci and Erhardt2019) and increased congestion in cities (Erhardt et al. Reference Erhardt, Roy, Cooper, Sana, Chen and Castiglione2019). A major study of ride sharing by the Union of Concerned Scientists (UCS 2020) found an average increase in emissions of 70 per cent compared to the trips that ride sharing is replacing, mostly due to excess driving between hired rides. Pooled ride sharing was found to have approximately the same emissions as private vehicle use, but when pooled ride sharing is paired with public transit use, this option was found to decrease emissions to less than half that of private vehicle use. The report also notes that transitioning to electric vehicles will have major benefits for ride sharing and should be a priority. Ride sharing now greatly exceeds taxi ridership in the United States, but because of their decentralized ownership, ride-sharing systems cannot directly take the same fuel efficiency-oriented purchasing decisions as taxi companies or car-sharing systems. However, ride-sharing companies can incentivize their drivers to invest in high-efficiency or electric vehicles, through cash incentives, preferential pricing, and partnerships for vehicle charging. For their part, some governments have taken action through differential fees for pooled rides or rides in downtown areas that compete with public transit, or through direct regulation of ride-sharing emissions, such as California’s Clean Miles Standard and Incentive Program (UCS 2020).

Sharing systems for other transportation modes such as bicycles and e-scooters have also been studied. Bike sharing is present in many urban areas around the world, and can include fixed station locations, demarcated parking areas, or no fixed locations at all. Bike sharing in the United States was found to decrease ridership on buses (for which bike trips substitute) but increase ridership on light and heavy rail, as commuters combine bicycling and trains in order to address the ‘last-mile’ problem often associated with public transit (Graehler et al. Reference Graehler, Mucci and Erhardt2019). In terms of energy use and emissions, Zhang and Mi (Reference Zhang and Mi2018) examined a large dataset from bike share trips in Shanghai and concluded that sharing programmes resulted in savings in fuel use and decreases in harmful air pollutant emissions in the city. Similar studies have investigated health benefits, both directly from increased exercise but more significantly indirectly from a decrease in vehicle emissions and pollution that benefits all surrounding residents (Mueller et al. Reference Mueller, Rojas-Rueda, Salmon, Martinez, Ambros, Brand, De Nazelle, Dons, Gaupp-Berghausen and Gerike2018; Woodcock et al. Reference Woodcock, Tainio, Cheshire, O’Brien and Goodman2014, ). On the other hand, these sharing systems require collection and re-distribution or balancing of where bicycles and e-scooters are located, which is typically done with vans or trucks running on conventional fuel. Poor operational management or sprawling low-density systems have the potential to lead to overall increases in emissions which can occur when vehicle use from redistribution exceeds that which is being substituted by bike or e-scooter use (Fishman, Washington, and Haworth Reference Fishman, Washington and Haworth2014, Hollingsworth, Copeland, and Johnson. 2019). Environmental and health benefits are largely predicated on the fact that users are switching away from driving, rather than from public transit, private bike use, or walking; benefits of bike or e-scooter sharing may then not materialize in cities where the share of car trips is already low, as was found for London (Fishman et al. Reference Fishman, Washington and Haworth2014).

3.3.2 Housing

Home-sharing platforms are the least researched in terms of environmental impact, despite their popularity. Among different vacation housing options, home sharing has been assumed to cause no additional environmental impact in comparison to the option of staying at home, while an average of 20 kg additional carbon dioxide (CO2) per person per night at a hotel room was estimated in several studies (Chenoweth Reference Chenoweth2009). The hotels impact is in part because hotel premises continue to be heated, cooled, and air-conditioned regardless of whether they are occupied or not, and these energy demands are higher than those of a typical home, which may or may not have mechanical ventilation. Airbnb produced a report claiming substantial energy and water savings, as well as reductions in CO2 emissions and waste due to Airbnb stays instead of staying in hotels (Airbnb 2017), building on an earlier comparison commissioned from the Cleantech Group. The report found that Airbnb stays require substantially less energy (~80 per cent) and generate lower GHG emissions (~90 per cent) than conventional hotel stays. However, the full methodology with which environmental benefits were calculated has not been made available and the results have not been independently verified. Nevertheless, a subsequent report by the Nordic Council of Ministers used the same percentage reductions to approximate potential emissions reductions from home sharing in their region (Skjelvik, Erlandsen, and Haavardsholm Reference Skjelvik, Erlandsen and Haavardsholm2017). These results are only meaningful if home sharing is substituting directly for hotel stays.

The other consideration is whether the convenience, choice, and typically lower costs of home-sharing platforms induce additional travel. Studies of the direct rebound effect of home sharing, namely whether it promotes more travel (including longer stays) entailing corresponding emissions, showed disparate results. A survey of 450 respondents with experience of using home sharing showed that use of peer-to-peer (P2P) accommodation expands destination selection (65 per cent positive responses) and may increase travel frequency (40 per cent positive responses) (Tussyadiah and Pesonen Reference Tussyadiah and Pesonen2016). It should be noted that over 30 per cent of the respondents used home sharing only once, while 40 per cent of respondents have experience of up to five visits. In another questionnaire involving twenty-four users of a home-sharing platform, all but one user responded that they would conduct their travels independently of access to a home-sharing option (Voytenko Palgan et al. Reference Voytenko Palgan, Zvolska and Mont2017).

3.3.3 Goods

It is often assumed that, as a consequence of using a sharing platform, the purchase of new products may be avoided or replaced by the sharing of products with the same functionality, thereby avoiding the environmental impacts of virgin production. Again, this simplistic assumption needs to be tested, as avoided production may not be the driving contributor and rebound effects may negate any potential savings. However, at the time of this review, there were few publications with comprehensive assessments of the environmental benefits of sharing goods such as surplus food, products, or building materials.

One of the most comprehensive was that of Martin, Lazarevic, and Gullstrom (Reference Martin, Lazarevic and Gullstrom2019), who assessed CO2 emissions of durable-goods sharing and potential savings in emissions, compared to the baseline (no sharing) scenario, based on transactions from the sharing platform Hygglo.se. Hygglo.se facilitates transactions between the user and provider for P2P sharing of about 7,000 listed products and services. In order to investigate the benefits of this sharing platform, three scenarios were analysed for an urban district with a population of 25,000 in Stockholm, Sweden: (1) a baseline scenario that assumed that no sharing service was available and all products were purchased new by the residents; (2) a scenario of products sharing assuming patterns of Hygglo.se transactions during 2017; and (3) the same sharing scenario as (2) but supplemented with a lockers-and-delivery system in order to reduce transport emissions of transactions. The analysis considered environmental impacts of goods production (due to raw materials extraction and manufacturing), distribution (for example, transportation, retail operations, energy use, and impacts from digital infrastructure), and use (for example, energy consumption) but excluding impacts of goods disposal. The study found that sharing scenarios reduced GHG emissions by about 77–85 per cent, with the results varying according to the average roundtrip travel required to complete the transaction. In this case, environmental impacts associated with avoided goods production were in fact the dominant factor in reducing emissions, since there were fewer products circulating in the district through sharing, providing the same level of service that newly purchased products would have provided. The study also showed how introducing a system with lockers and delivery could additionally reduce the transportation emissions of sharing transactions, though other work has shown that such reductions depend on characteristics of the logistics system, demand, and locker locations.

The garment industry is another sector that has received recent criticism for its environmental impacts, particularly from the rise ‘fast fashion’, where garment use is extremely short-lived (Niinimäki et al. Reference Niinimäki, Peters, Dahlbo, Perry, Rissanen and Gwilt2020). There have been calls to transform the industry toward a circular economy model, including mechanisms for sharing via platforms (Ellen MacArthur Foundation 2017), with the implicit assumption that such sharing will lead to environmental benefits such as reduced emissions. To test this hypothesis, Son et al. investigated different scenarios for garments, in which both second-hand purchases and sharing in the community were found to cause similar GHG emissions (1 kg CO2/garment usage), lower than a new purchase or online/offline rental (2.5–4 kg CO2/garment usage) (Son et al. Reference Son, Kurisu, Nakatani, Phuphisith and Moriguchi2019). In the case of rental, however, the impacts of cleaning and transportation brought the CO2/usage above that of owning an item. Another study focused on waste reduction found that, operated under favourable conditions, sharing could potentially reduce household waste by 20 per cent overall (Demailly and Novel Reference Demailly and Novel2014).

In general, transportation mode and distance are critical considerations for assessing the emissions associated with product-sharing transactions. For example, for food products, which can have relatively low embodied emissions compared to durable goods, the transport emissions from travelling to and from the point of sharing may offset the environmental benefits of avoiding new food, but the balance depends on how and how far individuals must travel. Proximity and access to low-emission transport options led to favourable results for sharing models. In a study in the United Kingdom, based on records from the OLIO food-sharing app, it has been found that 92 per cent of transactions occur within 10 km and 76 per cent of transactions occur within 5 km (Harvey et al. Reference Harvey, Smith, Goulding and Branco Illodo2019). For the Greater London area, with high population density and proximity of sharing pairs, Makov et al. found that food sharing through OLIO led to net environmental benefits for all transportation options, though the benefits were greatly reduced when a two-way dedicated car trip was used (Makov et al. Reference Makov, Shepon, Krones, Gupta and Chertow2020).

Emissions are just one measure of environmental performance. For many studies describing the environmental benefits of goods sharing, another common metric is quantity (mass) of the avoided waste. This trend is especially evident in the literature on food waste (Davies and Legg Reference Davies and Legg2018). Two studies involving Craigslist, a popular US-based P2P sharing platform for second-hand goods, found an estimated mass reduction in solid waste generation by 2–6 per cent per capita annually (Dhanorkar Reference Dhanorkar2019; Fremstad Reference Fremstad2017). But in these studies, neither the benefits of saved methane emissions, landfill space, and transport for waste collection have been assessed, nor has the alternative of anaerobic digestion of food waste to produce fuel and fertilizer been considered. This indicates that the use of different environmental metrics to assess environmental benefits of goods sharing is far from comprehensive and there is significant scope for expansion in research in this area, as few studies take a life-cycle approach.

Goods sharing is also potentially susceptible to the rebound effects, where savings from avoided purchases are applied to more consumption. For example, usage of second-hand P2P platforms has been connected to buying unnecessary items, both new (due to the ability to easily resell them later) and used (because of the low price). In addition, the results of an empirical study on consumer behaviour pointed out that consumers with materialistic traits and environmental consciousness were both more likely to engage in impulse buying of unnecessary items on P2P platforms (Parguel, Lunardo, and Benoit-Moreau Reference Parguel, Lunardo and Benoit-Moreau2017). The suggested mechanism of such behaviour is moral self-licensing, since platforms offer numerous justifications for purchases, including the common belief that buying second-hand is virtuous in terms of savings and environmental benefits. It has also been shown that consumers’ propensity to replace goods that are still in working condition has increased due to consumer participation in P2P platforms, thus potentially increasing the consumption of new goods. Unnecessary consumption of products shared for free may be even larger, leading to acquisition of products that are ultimately not used, but disposed of, negating any potential environmental benefits of their sharing.

3.4 Opportunities and Conclusions

The overall message of the research to date is that sharing is not an environmental panacea and should not be used as a heuristic for sustainability. Whether sharing produces environmental benefits or not depends on many factors, especially the quality of the item or service being shared, its intensity of use, the distances involved, and the severity of rebound effects. As seen in Section 3.3, research on the environmental sustainability of sharing platforms is uneven and there is much we don’t know. Transportation continues to receive significant attention, in part because of the public data infrastructure available from detailed travel surveys. On the other hand, there is relatively little research to date on P2P sharing of accommodation and goods, and therefore ample opportunities for improving our understanding of potential benefits and disadvantages.

For all three sharing types considered in this chapter, research has identified opportunities for improvements, regardless of whether the baseline comparison was positive or negative. Such research has also made clear that pursuing these opportunities changes the overall calculus of whether sharing is environmentally beneficial. In general, recommendations have fallen into four major themes:

  1. 1. Design algorithms to emphasize proximity. For goods especially, the benefits or disadvantages of sharing were found to be highly sensitive to transportation considerations. This suggests that grouping or even restricting sharing to the neighbourhood level, as many platforms already do, may be an effective way to avoid unintended environmental emissions.

  2. 2. Encourage low-carbon transportation options for sharing transactions. In general, ride sharing was generally found to have higher GHG emissions than personal vehicles, but it could be lower if pooling and vehicle electrification were pursued aggressively (UCS 2020). For accommodation, home sharing was generally found to have lower GHG emissions than hotel stays, and especially so if located in public transit areas where additional car transportation could be avoided, such as city centres. For food, relying on bus travel or trip chaining with a personal vehicle greatly increased the environmental benefits of sharing (Makov et al. Reference Makov, Shepon, Krones, Gupta and Chertow2020).

  3. 3. Model the system and mitigate unintended effects. Sharing has large-scale implications for both private consumption and public infrastructure, with many knock-on effects that are poorly understood. For example, the emergence of home sharing in some city centres has caused rents to become unaffordable and forced long-time residents to move out of the city. These people must then commute back into the city for work, inducing additional emissions that can eclipse any environmental benefit of the home sharing itself. In response to turmoil in local housing and rental markets from home sharing, major cities such as Los Angeles have passed ordinances regulating home sharing, including by requiring registration of allowed locations, which may enable the cities to shape where and what types of home sharing are allowed. Such policies could also include environmental motivations. Environmental economics and consequential LCA provide tools for examining the extent of rebound effects and the unequal distribution of benefits and costs.

  4. 4. Focus sharing on transactions with the highest environmental benefit. Items that are energy- or emissions-intensive to produce, such as like high-end tools or machinery, have a large benefit for avoided production when they are shared. If they are durable items and can be shared among a large group, these benefits will compound. Transactions can also have a large benefit because they avoid the environmental impacts associated with disposal, such as shared food avoiding the emissions from decomposition of food waste in a landfill. Estimating a ranking of sharing benefits by item type using tools such as LCA would be a useful area of future research.

While this chapter has focused on environmental benefits in physical terms, perhaps the most important sustainability opportunities afforded by sharing economy platforms are indirect, through the data that they can provide for consumption-related research and policymaking. For example, shared-ride information can be analysed by municipal transportation departments to identify demand for last-mile transportation, with the purpose of designing public infrastructure and services that operate synergistically with ride-sharing and can satisfy demand in an environmentally sound and safe way (Fishman and Schepers Reference Fishman and Schepers2016). The levying of occupancy taxes on home-sharing by municipalities allows them to collect data on P2P supply and demand for accommodation that can be useful for urban zoning and development planning (Coles et al. Reference Coles, Egesdal, Ellen, Li, Sundararajan, Davidson, Finck and Infranca2018). Identifying the most commonly shared foods may help develop information campaigns for residents on best management practices as well as design of municipal organic waste management systems. Also, areas with food shortages may be identified and assisted. Knowledge about popular items for goods sharing and their end-of-life can inform design of more robust shareable goods by manufacturers (Wastling, Charnley, and Moreno Reference Wastling, Charnley and Moreno2018), thus further reducing demand for manufacturing through product lifetime extension. One example is high-quality durable clothing. The sharing economy may help in reaching several United Nations Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs), including SDG #11 (Sustainable Cities and Communities) and SDG #12 (Sustainable Consumption and Production). Enabled by collaborative consumption, reductions in emissions from goods production, long-range transport, and waste management could also contribute to achieving climate goals. If these potentials are found to be considerable, it may warrant political and legislative support of sharing initiatives.

As sharing economy platforms continue to evolve, there are numerous opportunities to improve their back- and front-end design in order to incentivize beneficial environmental outcomes. Thanks to their digital basis, sharing platforms are well suited for evaluation of their environmental costs and benefits at a transaction level using tools like LCA, though this opportunity that has been underutilized so far. Just as some airlines now show passengers the carbon footprint of their trips (and offer the opportunity to purchase carbon offsets), sharing platform algorithms can estimate the environmental benefits due to the avoided manufacturing and transportation, using positioning services or customers’ addresses (Martin et al. Reference Martin, Lazarevic and Gullstrom2019). Such a feature will allow users to make informed decisions on transactions, such as choosing a pool ride, instead of a single-person ride, or avoiding food pick-up that entails generating high transport emissions. Environmental characteristics of shared items could be communicated to users, such as embodied carbon or product durability. Encouraging sharing of the most robust goods will extend the lifetime of these products while further reducing demand for new goods manufacturing. Sharing economy platforms can also be engineered for the entire user base such that the objectives of the optimization routines they use include minimization of environmental impacts.

Finally, we can think of the design of the physical systems within which sharing economy companies operate, most notably by promoting urban design that enables the sharing economy. For example, what would an effective ‘sharing district’ look like? Is there a bundle of shared services that can be provided to the residents that would allow them to forego private consumption entirely? Several examples are already common, such as subscriptions to a shared ride service in lieu of private parking spaces, or shared appliances and tools instead of private storage spaces. Safety and security will always be important concerns for consumers; for some sensitive items, can a system of lockers for exchanged goods make transactions more trusted?

In conclusion, the rise of sharing economy platforms has upended many markets for goods and services. From an environmental perspective, there is growing quantitative evidence about the consequences of these shifts, both positive and negative. Many sharing economy participants cite environmental sustainability as a motivator for engagement, but as this chapter has shown, the scale of environmental benefits depends on operational circumstances such as travel distance, substitution, and rebound. This is still an emerging area of investigation, particularly for accommodation and goods, using LCA and other assessment techniques. Harnessing data collected by or in response to sharing economy platforms will enable a clearer picture of environmental benefits and disadvantages, which can in turn inform actions that the platforms and public authorities can take to incentivize more environmentally sustainable outcomes.

4 Sharing Economy and Privacy

Laetitia Lambillotte and Yakov Bart
4.1 Introduction

Information privacy has long been at the center of policy debates focusing on design and operations of online platforms (e.g., Karwatzki et al. Reference Karwatzki, Dytynko, Trenz and Veit2017). According to the Centre for International Governance Innovation-Ipsos report (2018), nearly half of North American Internet users report that their privacy-related concerns have been increasing over time. Better understanding of the antecedents and elements of information privacy is particularly important in the context of sharing economy platforms, as participating in the services they facilitate often involves exchanging highly personal and intimate information, such as addresses, photos, personal items, phone numbers, and individual preferences (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019).

Previous examinations of privacy considerations in sharing economy platforms have been primarily focused on rights and regulations by legal scholars, resulting market power and competition outcomes by economists, privacy-centered systems design by engineers and underlying cognitive and emotion-based mechanisms by psychologists. Following the central theme of this book, the goal of this chapter is to provide a common comprehensive framework that would allow scholars and scientists coming from different backgrounds to bridge disciplinary silos and advance research on information privacy issues arising in sharing economy platforms.

The framework we propose consists of two conceptual models. The first model is concerned with exchange of information. We focus on describing various types of information exchange that arise on sharing economy platforms across different purchase stages. As the platforms serve as intermediary between providers and consumers (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017), leading to a triadic relationship between the three types of actors (providers, consumers, platforms), it is important to understand how the dyadic information exchanges underlying this dynamically evolving relationship may vary, depending on which particular dyad is involved. Put differently, the first part of this chapter focuses on classifying all possible information exchanges on sharing economy platforms. Such complex information exchange is crucial for any functioning sharing economy platform (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017).

However, this exchange of information may raise privacy concerns among platform providers and consumers (Eckhardt et al. Reference Eckhardt, Houston, Jiang, Lamberton, Rindfleisch and Zervas2019; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). Consequently, possible information exchanges we describe in the next section may occur only if the platform users (individual providers and consumers) accept the risk that they may lose a certain degree of privacy in exchange for receiving certain benefits (Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006; Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018). But how do the users trade off the relevant risks and benefits? In the second part of this chapter, we examine how platform users decide which of the possible information exchanges they choose to participate in (i.e., accepted information exchanges), using the privacy calculus framework.

4.2 Exchange of Information

In this section, we discuss three types of information exchange. First, we examine the exchange of information between platform users and the intermediating sharing economy platform. Then, we consider the exchange of information between providers and consumers. Finally, we discuss the exchange of information between platforms.

4.2.1 Exchange of Information Between Platform Users and the Intermediating Platform

The exchange of information between platform users and an intermediating platform includes the exchange of mandatory data, voluntary data, and behavioral data (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). Platform users exchange such data with the intermediating platform to participate in the sharing economy. The exact nature of the information exchanges can be different for providers and consumers, depending on the platform context (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018).

Mandatory data refer to information that platform users must provide to sign up on the sharing economy online platform such as real names, email address, and phone number. Such data are mainly collected through online forms (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017) accompanying account registrations, or by asking new users to verify their identities by linking with existing Facebook or Google accounts. Providers and consumers may be asked to share different data (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018). On TaskRabbit, for instance, service providers are required to fill in quite a broad range of information fields necessary to create an account on the platform, including their name, email address, phone number, address, photo, and description of their applicable skills. By contrast, individuals seeking to onboard TaskRabbit platform as service consumers, are only required to share their name, email address, and zip code to create an account.

Voluntary data refer to information that platform users may provide to develop their profile further on the platform. Platform users may choose to share such information to appear more trustworthy and likeable, hoping to increase the likelihood of getting engaged in more transactions facilitated by the sharing economy platform (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). For this data type, providers and consumers may also choose to share different information items with the platform. On Airbnb, for instance, providers (hosts) can enrich their profile with more personal description and enhanced textual and visual descriptions of the property they would like to rent. Such information can make their profile (and their property) more appealing for potential consumers (guests). As for consumers, they can also choose to share more personal details, both in textual and visual (through their photo) formats, hoping that such additional information may enhance their likeability in the eyes of potential hosts (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017).

One of the key considerations related to the exchange of mandatory and voluntary data is that it is always explicit, meaning that platform users deliberately provide such information to access and engage with sharing economy platforms (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). The third type of shared information, comprising behavioral data, is fundamentally different in this respect. Specifically, sharing economy platforms often collect behavioral data implicitly, by tracking platform users’ behavior (Fay et al. Reference Fay, Mitra and Wang2009). There are multiple purposes that such information can serve. First, platforms may use it to assess the effectiveness of the platform user interface by analyzing bounce rates (the percentage of website visitors who navigate away after viewing only one page) and mapping user journeys from the initial onboarding to submitting posttransaction feedbacks (Fay et al. Reference Fay, Mitra and Wang2009). Second, such data enable platforms to learn more about their users’ preferences and personalize the user experiences on the platform accordingly (Bleier and Eisenbeiss Reference Bleier and Eisenbeiss2015). Personalization refers to the ability to adapt content to individuals automatically, based on their inferred preferences (Chellappa and Sin Reference Chellappa and Sin2005; Karwatzki et al. Reference Karwatzki, Dytynko, Trenz and Veit2017). Personalization helps sharing economy platforms to recommend tailored content to platform users (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). While both platform providers and consumers may find some of these adaptations appealing, such data-driven personalization at scale may also backfire. Prior studies have shown that excessive personalization may result in platform users finding it too intrusive (e.g., Karwatzki et al. Reference Karwatzki, Dytynko, Trenz and Veit2017).

Table 4.1 summarizes these three types of information exchange between platform users and the intermediating platform. In the next subsection, we discuss the information exchanges between platform providers and consumers.

Table 4.1 Types of shared information

Mandatory data

Voluntary data

Behavioral data

Aim: Getting access to the platform

Means of collection: forms, linking with existing Facebook or Google accounts

Examples: real names, email address

Aim: Increase likelihood of participation

Means of collection: forms

Examples: personal description, photos

Aim: Analyze users’ behavior on the platform

Means of collection: cookies, pixels

Examples: visit frequency, bounce rates

4.2.2 Exchange of Information Between Platform Consumers and Providers

Once platform users establish their relationship with the platform (either by registering or subscribing), they can start interacting with other platform users. Following a commonly used classification of the different stages of the customer journey, in this subsection we use it to discuss information exchanges between platform consumers and providers that frequently occur at such stages: prepurchase stage, purchase stage and the postpurchase stage (Lemon and Verhoef Reference Lemon and Verhoef2016).

The prepurchase stage encompasses all interactions between consumers and providers that take place before the transaction or purchase occurs (Lemon and Verhoef Reference Lemon and Verhoef2016). Following registering or subscribing to the platform, consumers and providers typically exchange product information, related to the good or the service characteristics and delivery terms (Lemon and Verhoef Reference Lemon and Verhoef2016). For instance, consumers may have questions about products and may want to learn more details before deciding to book a service or purchase a good. On Airbnb, for instance, potential guests may contact hosts through the intermediating platform to obtain more information about the price or the amenities of the offered property before deciding to book a short-term stay. Providers typically respond to such requests by providing necessary information.

The purchase stage refers to all the interactions between consumers and providers that are directly related to the transactions (goods purchase or services booking) (Lemon and Verhoef Reference Lemon and Verhoef2016). At this stage, a typical information exchange is focused on payments and fulfillments. For example, Airbnb guests can exchange information with selected hosts to secure the property booking.

Finally, consumers and providers may exchange information during the postpurchase stage, which typically encompasses all posttransactional interactions (Lemon and Verhoef Reference Lemon and Verhoef2016). At this stage, they can exchange information related to exchanging or repairing the good or fixing service access issues (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). On TaskRabbit, for example, consumers and providers may contact each other through the platform to arrange their meeting place and time, and exchange information about required tools and job access. On Uber, drivers may call riders on their way through the platform if there is traffic, an accident or if they have trouble finding the rider at the requested location.

While consumers and providers exchange information mainly through the intermediating sharing economy platform, they can also do that outside the platform (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017) if platform users are comfortable exchanging the contact means (typically their email addresses or phone numbers) necessary for such nonplatform information exchange. On Airbnb platform, for instance, hosts may share their private phone numbers so guests can contact hosts if there is any issue with the property during their stays.

4.2.3 Exchange of Information Between Platforms

In our current information-driven economy, data generate economic value for online platforms and offers a competitive advantage (Awad and Krishnan Reference Awad and Krishnan2006). Online platforms always look to acquire new data to learn more about their current users or to identify and attract promising new ones. The access to such data helps them improve their targeting and personalization.

Unbeknownst to many platform stakeholders, many platforms share detailed information about their users with other online platforms to help them enrich their data and profit in the process (Kim et al. Reference Kim, Barasz and John2018). Moreover, online platforms may choose to share their users’ data with some (but not all) of the partnering platforms strategically, to strengthen their strategic competitive advantage. For example, Facebook gave access to some of its data to Airbnb, Lyft, and Netflix (Satariano and Isaac Reference Satariano and Isaac2018).

In sum, the advances in digital transformation enable sharing economy platforms and their key stakeholders (consumers and providers) to exchange rich data across different dyads through several consumer journey stages and for multiple purposes – we summarize these information flows in Figure 4.1. However, the sheer possibility of such information flows and its pervasiveness today may not necessarily indicate the expansion (or even existence) of such flows in the future, as this would require acceptance of such information flows by key platform stakeholders. Over past several years, many journalists and scholars have emphasized how the invasiveness of such information exchange could raise serious privacy concerns among platform providers and consumers (e.g., Kim et al. Reference Kim, Barasz and John2018). In the next section, we examine the privacy calculus framework and discuss its implications for the acceptance of various information exchanges in the sharing economy.

Figure 4.1 Exchange of information in the sharing economy.

4.3 Privacy Calculus

The information exchanges discussed in Section 4.2 may occur only if the platform users accept the risk that they may lose a certain degree of privacy in exchange for receiving certain benefits (Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006; Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018). But how do the users trade off the relevant risks and benefits? We adopt the privacy calculus framework to shed light on these tradeoffs (Dienlin and Metzger Reference Dienlin and Metzger2016; Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006).

The privacy calculus is a rational analysis that focuses on the relative benefits and risks of disclosing information (Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006). In the context of the sharing economy, the privacy calculus implies an assessment of the risks of disclosing information versus an evaluation of the potential benefits derived from participation in the sharing economy. In this perspective, platform users accept losing a certain degree of information privacy if expected outcomes are worth the risks (Dienlin and Metzger Reference Dienlin and Metzger2016).

In the following subsections, we will explore the benefits and risks that could be potentially derived from participation in the sharing economy.

4.3.1 Risks of Disclosing Information

Yates and Stone (Reference Yates, Stone and Yates1992) define risk as “the possibility of loss.” In the context of sharing economy platforms, users may decide against pursuing an access to a good or service due to the uncertainty associated with the required personal data disclosing (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). Such uncertainty generates concerns among platform users about information privacy practices (Bart et al. Reference Bart, Shankar, Sultan and Urban2005).

Privacy concerns refer to the extent to which individuals are concerned about online platforms’ collection and use of their data and worry about potential misuse (Hong and Thong Reference Hong and Thong2013; Karwatzki et al. Reference Karwatzki, Dytynko, Trenz and Veit2017). Such concerns relate to data collection, unauthorized secondary use of data, improper access, and errors (Malhotra et al. Reference Malhotra, Kim and Agarwal2004; Smith et al. Reference Smith, Milberg and Burke1996). In the case of sharing economy, privacy concerns may also include considering potential physical privacy threats (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). In the following discussion, we examine each of these risk dimensions.

4.3.1.1 Data Collection

Concerns about data collection are defined as “the degree to which a person is concerned about the amount of individual-specific data possessed by others relative to the value of benefits received” (Malhotra et al. Reference Malhotra, Kim and Agarwal2004, p. 338). In the sharing economy context, the amount of data relates to the number of pieces of information that pass through the intermediating platform. Not only does it include the information that is required to access the sharing economy platform but also encompasses the information the users share on the platform afterwards. Sharing economy platforms where consumers and providers typically share a large amount of information are likely to generate such concerns (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018).

Let us illustrate the intrinsic data collection using TaskRabbit as an example. Platform providers are required to share their name, email address, phone number, physical address, photo, and skills description when they sign up. For their part, platform consumers are required to share their name, email address, and zip code to create an account. Then, service providers need to further detail their skills and price ranges, while service consumers need to describe the task that needs to be completed and the task options. Consumers and providers may also contact each other to organize their meeting. After the task is completed, consumers may post reviews on the platform and assess the reliability of the provider.

On other sharing economy platforms, the number of stages at which the information needs to be disclosed could be lower, but the information context could be potentially more invasive, such as geolocation information, necessary for facilitating real-time matching on sharing economy platforms. For example, on Uber, besides sharing basic personal information when registering to access the platform (such as name, email address, and phone number) and rating their experiences after each transaction, drivers and riders must also disclose to the platform their exact location, as it is required to connect and match drivers and users in real time (Thelen Reference Thelen2018).

As these examples illustrate, the amount of exchanged data may vary across intermediating platforms, depending on the sector in which they operate. For instance, the travel sector that requires the exchange of more personal information may generate more privacy concerns than in other sectors (Bart et al. Reference Bart, Shankar, Sultan and Urban2005).

Moreover, the amount of exchanged information may vary across different types of platform users; for example, consumers and providers may need to share substantially different volumes of information. On Airbnb, for instance, while both hosts and guests are required to exchange information about themselves to sign up such as names, email addresses, dates of birth, and photos, hosts also need to post detailed information about their property such as location and amenities to attract potential guests (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). After booking, hosts may also need to share their personal contact details (such as phone number or email address) and information to access the rented property (such as key or door code) either through or outside the platform (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). Overall, the amount of information expected to be shared by hosts is much greater, and the disclosure of information is more intimate and prejudicial for them (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). Such asymmetry against hosts who must take on more risks when disclosing information may discourage some of them to participate in the sharing economy.

4.3.1.2 Unauthorized Secondary Use

Concerns about unauthorized secondary use refer to platform users’ concerns that data collected for a defined purpose may also be used for another purpose without their consent. Secondary use of data may be internal or external (Malhotra et al. Reference Malhotra, Kim and Agarwal2004; Smith et al. Reference Smith, Milberg and Burke1996).

Internally, the unauthorized secondary use may occur within the organization that initiated the data collection. For instance, the user data that was initially collected for research purposes may be used afterwards for marketing purposes (Cespedes and Smith Reference Cespedes and Smith1993; Smith et al. Reference Smith, Milberg and Burke1996).

Externally, the secondary use of data is often associated with unauthorized sharing of the user data with other platforms. A typical example is the external sale or rental of data (Smith et al. Reference Smith, Milberg and Burke1996). As mentioned earlier, the exchange of data with external parties like other platforms is particularly perceived as unacceptable among platform users (Kim et al. Reference Kim, Barasz and John2018).

Overall, platform users that may share highly personal information (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018) may be particularly concerned about unauthorized secondary use.

4.3.1.3 Improper Access

Concern about improper access refers to the “concern that data about individuals are readily available to people not properly authorized to view or work with this data” (Smith et al. Reference Smith, Milberg and Burke1996, p. 172). Users may be concerned that intermediating platforms do not spend enough time and effort to prevent improper access and protect personal information (Malhotra et al. Reference Malhotra, Kim and Agarwal2004). Sharing economy platforms that let platform members comment on their experience interacting with other members are particularly susceptible to such concerns.

4.3.1.4 Errors

Platform users may also be concerned that the protection implemented by the platforms against deliberate and accidental errors is not adequate (Smith et al. Reference Smith, Milberg and Burke1996). For instance, data coding in databases and files could be inaccurate (Malhotra et al. Reference Malhotra, Kim and Agarwal2004). Such concern raises the question about the responsibility of the platform in spotting errors (Smith et al. Reference Smith, Milberg and Burke1996).

4.3.1.5 Physical Privacy Threats

Physical privacy refers to “individuals’ sense of having a private space that others cannot enter against their will” (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018, p. 1475). In the sharing economy context, platform users often allow other users temporary access to their personal property (such as cars on Uber or homes on Airbnb), which can raise serious concerns about potential physical privacy threats. Such threats may include surveillance, discomfort, and intrusion through the sharing of physical spaces (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019).

4.3.2 Individual Benefits of Disclosing Information

We turn now to examining how platforms users may account for various potential benefits derived from the participation in the sharing economy in their privacy calculus. We focus on three main benefits for platform users: Economic, reputation and social capital benefits (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017).

4.3.2.1 Economic Benefits

Participating in the sharing economy may provide multiple economic benefits to platform users (Belk Reference Belk2014; Bucher et al. Reference Bucher, Fieseler and Lutz2016; Hamari et al. Reference Hamari, Sjoklint and Ukkonen2016). Economic benefits represent not only earnings for the platform providers who can offer access to their goods or services to a large potential audience, but also savings for platform consumers who can benefit from accessing such services or goods at a much lower price point compared with prices for alternative options associated with the similar consumption experience (Lutz and Newlands Reference Lutz and Newlands2018; Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). For example, providers on ride-sharing platform earn money by driving local riders around cities, while consumers gain by obtaining a ride at a comparatively low price.

The economic benefits may extend beyond the pure financial considerations. Besides the tangible value component based on the core consumption experience (e.g., getting from point A to point B), consumers may derive additional value associated with the speed and convenience of obtaining the experience.

Another important aspect of evaluating economic benefits, especially on the provider side, is related to perceived audience size, which represents platform users’ perception of the potential reach of the platform (Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). The possibility of reaching a larger number of potential consumers is particularly important for providers who may derive higher economic benefits from the greater demand or higher prices associated with the higher number of potential consumers on the platform (Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019).

4.3.2.2 Reputation

Platform users may also benefit from interacting with reputational mechanisms embedded in many sharing economy platforms (Park et al. Reference Park, Gu, Leung and Konana2014; Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). Reputation enables individuals to obtain and maintain a higher status within a community (Wasko and Faraj Reference Wasko and Faraj2005). In essence, these mechanisms allow platform users to obtain greater value in the future (through attracting more demand and/or charging higher prices) from their better past behavior on the platform.

Disclosing certain mandatory personal information is essential for proper functioning of such reputation-based systems, as they require unambiguous and longitudinal (over time) platform users’ identification based on such information. In addition, users may gain a better reputation by voluntarily disclosing more information. On sharing economy platforms, a more developed user profile (containing more information about the user and/or their platform-related assets and services) may signal higher trustworthiness (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). On Airbnb, for instance, guests tend to trust hosts with more developed and accurate profiles (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017).

4.3.2.3 Social Capital

The possibility to connect with other individuals in a meaningful way is another important motivation to participate in online communities (Hamari et al. Reference Hamari, Sjoklint and Ukkonen2016; Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017; Wasko and Faraj Reference Wasko and Faraj2005), such as sharing economy platforms. However, social interactions between users in the sharing community inside and outside the platform (Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017) typically involve informal information exchanges above and beyond the level of individual data disclosure required by the platform.

4.3.3 Operating the Calculus

As we posited at the beginning of this section, participation in the sharing economy involves a mental process called the privacy calculus (Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). In the sharing economy context, it involves analyzing trade-offs between the perceived risks related to information disclosure, namely data collection, unauthorized secondary use, improper access, errors, and physical privacy threats (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Malhotra et al. Reference Malhotra, Kim and Agarwal2004; Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017; Smith et al. Reference Smith, Milberg and Burke1996) and its main perceived benefits namely economic, social capital, and reputation derived from participation in the sharing economy (Hamari et al. Reference Hamari, Sjoklint and Ukkonen2016; Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019).

This privacy calculus typically involves two stages: before and during interacting with the platform. In the first stage, potential platform users assess expected benefits and risks based on what they know about the sharing economy platform under consideration. If expected benefits are greater than expected risks, users would start engaging with the platform. Conversely, if risks are expected to overweigh benefits, users may decide that accessing the sharing economy platform is not worth it (Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006; Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019). For instance, users may learn that the amount or sensitivity of information required to access the platform is too high and decide that the expected platform benefits are not high enough to overweigh expected risks associated with sharing such information. It is no coincidence that sharing economy platforms primarily focus on explaining benefits to potential users, rather than discussing various risks associated with the required information exchanges. For example, at the recruiting stage, Uber focuses on showing potential drivers how they can increase their earnings by subscribing and participating in the platform, rather than explaining potential risks associated with mandatory and continuous geolocation data disclosure while on the job.

Figure 4.2 presents the privacy calculus and the intention to access the sharing economy platform. In the second stage, platform users assess benefits and risks during the use of the sharing economy platform. While platform users could only rely on their expectations about perceived benefits and risks associated with engaging with the sharing economy platform in the first stage, now they can evaluate their actual experience with the platform. Based on that evaluation, they decide whether perceived risks from the completed and ongoing information disclosures outweigh the perceived benefits associated with using the platform. If so, the users might decide to decrease their engagement or even to stop interacting with the platform (Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006; Trepte et al. Reference Trepte, Reinecke, Ellison, Quiring, Yao and Ziegele2017). Consequently, sharing economy platforms often emphasize and communicate to current users how they may gain more benefits by increasing their platform engagement, which is often accompanied by additional information disclosures by the users. Such a strategy often features new, higher tiers to entice the users to follow that path. For example, Airbnb advertises an opportunity for hosts to receive the superhost title when they meet four requirements: Host at least ten stays a year, have an average rating at or above 4.8, maintain a 90 percent response rate and not allow their cancellation rate to exceed 1 percent (Airbnb, 2019).

Figure 4.2 Privacy calculus before accessing the sharing economy platform.

Privacy calculus in both stages depends on trust, as it is an important internal factor behind overcoming uncertainty and increasing the likelihood of participating in the sharing economy (Ranzini et al, Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017). Moorman et al. (Reference Moorman, Deshpande and Zaltman1993, p. 82) define trust as “a willingness to rely on an exchange partner in whom one has confidence.” Trust includes three dimensions: Competence, reliability, and safety (Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006). Competence represents “the ability of the trustee to have the necessary expertise to perform the behavior expected by the trustor” (Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006, p. 66). Reliability reflects a trustor’s perception that the trustee is honest and sincere, and safety refers to the trustors’ belief that the trustee won’t disclose their personal information to a third party (Dinev and Hart Reference Dinev and Hart2006).

In the context of triadic relationships underlying sharing economy platforms, it is important to distinguish between trust beliefs between platform users (providers and consumers), and trust toward the intermediating platform. Trust between platform users within a community is essential in a context where members share personal information with other platform users (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018). For instance, Uber explains on its platform how respect between drivers and riders is essential to build trustworthy social dynamics and provides practical tips. Trust toward the intermediating platform is also important. Platform users need to be sure that the intermediating platform will protect their data (Lutz et al. Reference Lutz, Hoffmann, Bucher and Fieseler2018; Ranzini et al. Reference Ranzini, Etter, Lutz and Vermeulen2017) and will not disclose it to external parties without their explicit permission (Kim et al. Reference Kim, Barasz and John2018). Towards this goal, intermediating platforms may implement trust-building cues and submit to independent external data audits to signal to their users that their data is protected and will not get misused.

Finally, elements of individual’s privacy calculus may get influenced by one’s culture (Trepte et al. Reference Trepte, Reinecke, Ellison, Quiring, Yao and Ziegele2017). Privacy is a right that is shared all over the world but that is perceived differently depending on the culture (Altman Reference Altman1977; Trepte et al. Reference Trepte, Reinecke, Ellison, Quiring, Yao and Ziegele2017). In their study, Trepte et al. (Reference Trepte, Reinecke, Ellison, Quiring, Yao and Ziegele2017) show how cultural dimensions influence one’s avoidance of privacy risks. Individuals from a collective culture appear to give more importance to privacy risks and tend to avoid them, compared to individuals from individualist cultures. In addition, cultures presenting higher uncertainty avoidance (such as in Germany or the Netherlands) tend to avoid privacy risks.

4.4 Roles of Information Transparency and Privacy Literacy

While the framework we have outlined in this chapter describes models of both possible and acceptable information flows, many researchers and policymakers have been questioning the assumptions underlying these models: Information transparency (ensuring that all sharing economy participants can observe all possible information flows) and privacy literacy (ensuring that platforms users are able to make informed trade-offs inherent in operating the privacy calculus that determines all acceptable information flows).

Although the concept of information transparency has been studied in the general context of information privacy, the role of transparency in the sharing economy has been relatively understudied. Information transparency refers to “the extent to which an online firm provides features that allow consumers to access the data collected about them and informs them about how and for what purposes the acquired information is used” (Karwatzki et al. Reference Karwatzki, Dytynko, Trenz and Veit2017, p. 372). Amidst growing privacy concerns, governments enact policies to protect online users’ data. For instance, the European General Data Protection Regulation (GDPR) aims at delineating data protection for European individuals. It defines rules about the type of data companies can process, the time data can be stored and the way to communicate data collection and use to individuals (Kumar, Reference Kumar2018). This regulation renders data collection more difficult for online platforms and may have stronger overall impact on the sharing economy platforms that are more dependent on collecting personally identifiable information. For example, the more information Airbnb and Uber obtain about their users, the more efficient the matching is between hosts and guests, or drivers and riders (Teubner and Flath Reference Teubner and Flath2019).

Although prior research has shown how higher information transparency may reduce perceived consumer vulnerability in e-commerce and advertising contexts (Aguirre et al. Reference Aguirre, Mahr, Grewal, de Ruyter and Wetzels2015; Martin et al. Reference Martin, Borah and Palmatier2017), further research is needed to understand potential positive and negative impacts of information transparency on different types of sharing economy platform users. On the one hand, the presence of information transparency cues may provide platforms users with more control about the way their data are collected and used. However, higher platform transparency may also potentially negatively bias the individual private calculus outcomes, and this effect is likely to be moderated by privacy literacy.

Trepte et al. (Reference Trepte, Teutsch, Masur, Eicher, Fischer, Hennhofer, Lind, Gutwirth, Leenes and de Hert2015, p. 339) define online privacy literacy as “a combination of factual or declarative (‘knowing that’) and procedural (‘knowing how’) knowledge about online privacy.” In terms of declarative knowledge, online privacy literacy refers to the users’ knowledge about technical aspects of online data protection, related laws and directives, as well as institutional practices. In terms of procedural knowledge, online privacy literacy refers to the users’ ability to apply strategies for individual privacy regulation and data protection. It helps empower individuals engaging in practices that may affect their online privacy (Trepte et al. Reference Trepte, Teutsch, Masur, Eicher, Fischer, Hennhofer, Lind, Gutwirth, Leenes and de Hert2015). Prior research has shown the importance of online privacy literacy as a mediator to spending more time on social network sites (Bartsch and Dienlin Reference Bartsch and Dienlin2016). However, since knowledge is an important dimension of perceived control, consumers who are high in online privacy literacy also have a higher willingness to control their online privacy and lower desire to disclose information (Awad and Krishnan Reference Awad and Krishnan2006). From this perspective, educating and empowering users of sharing economy platforms to raise their privacy literacy may also lead to a higher sense of control of the way their data are collected and used, but, at the same time, could also reduce their willingness to disclose personal information on these platforms.

Finally, we encourage future research to examine both prevalence and impact of dark patterns in the context of sharing economy. In the online context, dark patterns are defined as “interface design choices that benefit an online service by coercing, steering, or deceiving users into making decisions that, if fully informed and capable of selecting alternatives, they might not make” (Mathur et al. Reference Mathur, Acar, Friedman, Lucherini, Mayer, Chetty and Narayanan2019). Prior studies have documented how dark patterns may lead e-commerce consumers and mobile app users to share personal information when they ordinarily would not and described the mechanisms through which such patterns may influence user actions and perceptions (e.g., Hartzog Reference Hartzog2018). It is important to understand how the potential presence of such dark patterns on sharing economy platforms may affect accepted information flows.

Overall, despite this high complexity and variety of factors underlying privacy considerations, we expect that future research bridging the disciplinary silos studying different aspects of privacy and sharing will deepen our understanding of how sharing economy platforms could optimally balance operational efficiencies against privacy concerns and rights of their users. We hope the framework detailing both possible and accepted information flows and related classifications we have introduced in this chapter would be helpful in these future endeavors.

5 Reputation, Feedback, and Trust in Online Platforms

Steven Tadelis
5.1 Introduction

As a recent McKinsey article (Briedis et al. Reference Briedis, Choi, Huang and Kohli2020) states, “digital marketplaces have been the buzz of the consumer industry for the past several years.” Indeed, online marketplaces have grown dramatically over the past two decades and bring value across many areas of our lives. The recent forced lockdowns caused by the COVID-19 pandemic have accelerated the use of online marketplaces even further. Platforms such as eBay, Taobao, Flipkart, Amazon Marketplaces, Airbnb, Uber, Upwork, and many more match consumers and businesses to businesses and individuals and create gains from trade in efficient and effective ways by: (i) allowing businesses to market their goods or get rid of excess inventory; (ii) saving businesses the costs needed to establish their own e-commerce website to generate online consumer traffic; (iii) allowing individuals to get rid of items they no longer need and transform these into cash; (iv) allowing individuals to share their time or assets across different productive activities; and (v) allowing businesses to hire short- and longer-term contractors and employees to perform a variety of remote tasks.

Looking back at the success of these platforms, especially the sharing economy platforms where asset owners allow temporary asset usage by other users, a natural question arises: How is it that strangers who have never transacted with one another, and who may be thousands of miles apart, are willing to trust each other? Unlike a physical transaction in a store, where the buyer can touch and feel the good he or she is buying, this close contact is absent at the matching stage at multiple sharing economy platforms, which means that users may not be able to verify each other’s identities in person when they commit to a transaction. Hence, to many, the rise of multisided online marketplaces, and sharing economy platforms in particular, was not foreseen.

Indeed, basic economic theory would predict that these platforms should face an uphill battle. In his seminal article “The Market for ‘Lemons’”, Akerlof (Reference Akerlof1970) showed how hidden information in the hands of sellers causes markets to fail despite gains from trade. Intuitively, two sources of uncertainty can prevent markets from operating efficiently. First, uncertainty about the quality of a transaction may be inherent to the good or service provided like in Akerlof’s adverse selection model, which means that users should be wary of purchasing access to assets they cannot inspect. For example, some hosts on Airbnb may know that the apartments they are offering for a short-term rent are defective, yet they may choose not to reveal the defect and misrepresent their items. Second, quality uncertainty may be a result of unobserved actions that determine the quality of the good or service, what is often referred to as “moral hazard.” For example, a host on Airbnb may choose to skimp on cleaning between guest stays and increase the likelihood that the apartment will be in a bad shape when next guest arrives. Of course, both hidden information and unobserved actions might be present simultaneously.

It is therefore necessary that both sides of the market feel comfortable trusting each other, and for that, they need to have safeguards that alleviate the problems caused by asymmetric information. This is where new-world online platforms took a page out of an old-world playbook by creating feedback and reputation systems that became central to their operations. The need for reputation-based incentives to foster trust and guarantee successful market operation is an old idea that has been part of commerce for centuries. Just as digital transformation made possible instantaneous matching of users in modern sharing economy markets, the need to coordinate where and when market transactions took place was an important historical innovation. Take, for example, the introduction of trade fairs in medieval Europe (see Grief 2006) in which the successful trade between parties who had never met was supported by governance and reputation mechanisms that gave traders the faith to trade with strangers (see Milgrom, North, and Weingast Reference Milgrom, North and Weingast1990).

In this chapter, I explain how feedback and reputation systems work in practice, and how they support online markets. While most of the examples I use refer to the e-commerce marketplaces context, the key mechanisms behind interactions between buyers and sellers are similar to the mechanisms driving sharing economy markets (for example, interactions between hosts and guests on Airbnb or between drivers and riders on Uber). Section 5.2 presents the theory behind reputation mechanisms and how they support more efficient trade. Section 5.3 describes the actual working of typical online feedback and reputation systems while Section 5.4 presents findings from a host of empirical papers that explore how reputation works in actual online marketplaces. Section 5.5 highlights some shortcomings of reputation systems and Section 5.6 suggests some considerations for the future design of feedback and reputation systems that can augment their effectiveness. Section 5.7 offers some closing thoughts.

5.2 Reputation and Feedback: Theory

The difficulty in supporting anonymous online trade can be explained using a relatively simple game-theoretic example.Footnote 1 Consider a buyer who finds an online product sold by an anonymous seller. The buyer values the product at $25, the purchase price is $15, and the seller has no use for the good, so the seller receives a net value of $0 if it does not sell the good. The seller’s costs of shipping and handling are $5, so at a price of $15 the seller will make $10, and the buyer, paying $15 for what he values at $25, is left with a net surplus (or dollar-value utility) of $10.Footnote 2 Further imagine that the buyer must first send money to the seller (as in clicking “buy” online) and then the seller can send the good to the buyer.

The standard assumption in economics is that people are selfish utility maximizers. This would imply that if the buyer clicks “buy” and pays, then the seller is better off just keeping the $15 and sending nothing, thus saving the $5 of shipping fees. But we know that many people care about being honest, and hence we need to capture a world where this is the case. To do this, imagine that the seller can be one of two types: one is an honest seller who makes good on promises, and the other is an opportunistic seller who only cares about their own profits. The buyer does not know the type of the seller but does believe that a seller is honest with some well-defined probability p0,1.Footnote 3 This simple game is shown in Figure 5.1.

Figure 5.1 Trade game with asymmetric information.

Figure 5.1 describes the story above as follows: “Nature” determines whether the seller that the buyer faces is honest or opportunistic; the reason that both nodes are circled in a dashed ellipse is to indicate that the buyer does not know which type of seller they face, but they do know that the seller is honest with probability p. Hence, the buyer assigns probability p to being on the right side of the ellipse. If the buyer chooses not to trust the seller and not engage in trade, then regardless of the type of seller, there is no trade and both parties get zero. If instead the buyer chooses to trust, then if the seller is honest the game will end in a successful trade, while if the seller is opportunistic then it may go either way, depending on the choice of the opportunistic seller. In the jargon of economics, this game includes both “hidden information” (the type of seller is not known to the buyer) and “hidden action” (the opportunistic type has agency to act in a way that can harm the buyer).

Now ask yourself what would happen if this game is played only once? Naturally, the opportunistic seller would choose to abuse trust because it saves money and offers a higher profit. In turn, a rational buyer would anticipate this behavior and will choose to trust the seller if and only if the risk is worthwhile. Assuming that the buyer is risk neutral (i.e., maximizes expected value), the risk is worthwhile if and only if the expected value from trusting the seller is larger than zero (the value of not trading), i.e., 10p+151p0 or p0.6. Intuitively, if the likelihood of an honest seller is high enough (greater than 60 percent) then the risk is worth taking.

Now assume that most people are known to be honest so that p>0.6 and any buyer would be happy to transact, and risk being cheated because the likelihood of successfully completing a trade is high enough. Imagine now that our seller will be able to transact with the buyer twice consecutively, across two periods – say in month 1 and month 2. An honest seller will always act honestly, while an opportunistic seller wishes to maximize its expected profits. Being forward looking, assume that at the beginning of month 1 the opportunistic seller discounts future profits in month 2 at a discount factor of δ0,1. This means that $1 in month 2 is worth $δat the beginning of month 1.Footnote 4

It is clear that in month 2, when the opportunistic seller is facing its last transaction (there are no future trade opportunities), then it will choose to abuse trust just as it would when there is only one opportunity to trade as shown previously. The question is, what would an opportunistic seller do in month 1 when there is a future trade opportunity? As we will now show, if δis not too small (the future is important enough), then an opportunistic seller will no longer choose to abuse trust in the first transaction and instead will want to “build a reputation” of being honest.

The argument is a bit subtle. Imagine that the buyer in month 1 believes that an opportunistic seller will abuse trust in the first transaction. The buyer is still willing to trust the seller because p>0.6, but in month 2 the buyer will expect to update beliefs about the type of seller they face. If the buyer believes that an opportunistic seller always abuses trust, it follows that in month 2, the buyer can use the seller’s performance in the first month to form updated beliefs about the type of the seller: If the first month’s transaction was honored then the seller must be honest, and should be trusted again; if the first transaction failed then the buyer infers that the seller must be opportunistic, and hence would choose to not trust the seller in month 2. With these beliefs in place, however, if the future is important enough then an opportunistic seller would not find it beneficial to abuse trust in the first month. To see this, first note that abusing trust would result in a payoff of $15 for the opportunistic seller because they will receive $15 in month 1 from abusing trust once, and they will not be trusted a second time and receive $0 in month 2. If instead the opportunistic seller chooses to honor trust, then they receive $10 in the first month, and because the buyer will (incorrectly) infer that the seller is honest, then the buyer will trust the seller in month 2 allowing the seller to then abuse trust in the second transaction and acquire another $15. If the added value of $15 in the future transaction outweighs the loss of $5 in the first transaction, then pretending to be honest will pay off. This happens if and only if $10+$15δ>$15 or δ >13. Hence, if honesty is common enough (p>0.6) and the future is important enough (δ >13), then the opportunistic seller will choose to honor trust in order to get access to the money he can obtain from the second transaction.Footnote 5

What is more interesting is that with such a two-period game, where early behavior of the seller influences future buyers to update their beliefs, trade can occur even when buyers are less optimistic about the seller’s honesty (p<0.6). To see this, imagine that the buyer believes that an opportunistic seller will abuse trust always, which are the most pessimistic beliefs a buyer can have. If the buyer trusts the seller in the first month, then with probability p, the buyer faces an honest seller and will obtain a payoff of $10, and then will know for sure that the seller is honest, and she’ll obtain another payoff of $10 in the second month. If instead trust is abused in the first month, then the buyer will opt out of transacting again. Assuming that the buyer also uses δas their discount factor, then with these beliefs the buyer will choose to trust in month 1 if and only if,

p10 + 10δ+ 1  p15 0p 1525+10δ 

Note that if δbecomes infinitesimally small, then for the buyer to trust the seller it is necessary that p0.6 because it effectively becomes a one-time game for the buyer (as δbecomes infinitesimally small, it means that the payoffs from the second month become insignificant and can be ignored). If, on the other hand, the buyer is extremely patient so that δapproaches 1, then the buyer will trust the seller if p37. The analysis performed earlier implies that the opportunistic seller would rather imitate the honest type and cooperate in the first month of trade. Hence, with a high enough discount factor we get “more trade” in the sense that trust is supported for lower values of p (a lower propensity of honest sellers). And if we add more potential trade periods in the future, then trade will occur for even lower likelihoods of the seller being honest.Footnote 6

The key idea is that a seller’s actions today will lead to future consequences, which keep him in check. This mechanism even works if the seller does not interact repeatedly with the same buyer as long as the seller understands that his current actions will be revealed to all future buyers and that his good behavior today will be rewarded by future business just as bad behavior will be penalized by a lack of future business. What’s more, the value of the business itself will depend on the seller’s past performance (see Kreps Reference Kreps, Alt and Shepsle1990; Tadelis Reference Tadelis1999), an insight that sheds light on the powerful role that reputation and feedback systems play in fostering trust. A public reputation repository allows all future potential buyers to track a seller’s past performance, and reputation becomes an important incentive mechanism that facilitates trust in anonymous markets.

There is a vast theoretical literature on the economics of seller reputation (see Bar-Isaac and Tadelis Reference Bar-Isaac and Tadelis2008 for a survey) with empirical implications that are rather intuitive. First, sellers with better reputations should attract more potential buyers, and command higher prices for their goods and services. Second, as sellers’ reputations get better (or worse), their economic returns and growth will also get better (or worse). These simple yet powerful implications of reputation models can be put to empirical scrutiny and tested using market-level data. In fact, the recent rise of online platforms with “big data” on buyer and seller behavior have proven to be a fertile ground to test these implications.

5.3 Reputation and Feedback: Practice

Many have attributed the success of eBay, the very first online marketplace that grew rapidly to mediate the trade of scores of transactions, to its reputation and feedback mechanism (see, e.g., Resnick et al. Reference Resnick, Zeckhauser, Kuwabara and Friedman2000 and Dellarocas Reference Dellarocas2003). Indeed, eBay exists as a successful business despite the complete anonymity of the marketplace. Following eBay’s lead, practically every online marketplace, including modern sharing economy markets, has adopted some form of a reputation or feedback system. Herein I will describe in detail how eBay’s feedback system works, which should give the reader an idea of how these kinds of systems work elsewhere.

A well-functioning reputation system provides future buyers with information about each seller’s past behavior, information that is generally produced by the voluntary input of buyers. After completing a transaction on eBay, a buyer has sixty days to leave either a positive, negative, or neutral feedback score for the seller. On the Chinese marketplace Taobao.com, if a seller leaves positive feedback for a buyer but the buyer leaves no feedback then the platform’s algorithm leaves automatic positive feedback under the assumption that silence is most likely a sign of buyer satisfaction.Footnote 7 As I explain in Section 5.5, this may be far from the truth. Also note that leaving feedback requires some time, so a buyer may selfishly choose to leave no feedback at all. Interestingly, back in 2016 about 65 percent of buyers left feedback on eBay, and an even higher fraction (more than 80 percent) left feedback in eBay’s earlier days.Footnote 8

Figure 5.2 shows how a seller’s feedback, which I refer to as the reputation measure of the seller, is calculated and displayed on eBay. A new Apple MacBook is being sold by a seller with the username “electronicsvalley” with a Feedback Score of 21,814, which is the summed value of the number of positive feedbacks minus the number of negative feedbacks. The page also shows that 99.2% of this seller’s feedback was positive, defined as the seller’s number of positive feedbacks divided by the sum of his number of positive and negative feedbacks.Footnote 9

Figure 5.2 eBay’s view item page displaying feedback.

To learn more about the seller’s history, buyers can click on the feedback score (the number 21,814 in Figure 5.2), which directs them to a detailed feedback profile page that is shown in Figure 5.3, which displays how many positive, neutral, or negative feedback reviews the seller received in the past month, six months, or twelve months.Footnote 10 At the bottom of the page there is a rolling list of verbal comments left by buyers, and to the right there are stars that indicate the Detailed seller ratings (DSRs), which buyers can leave only if they choose to leave feedback first.

Figure 5.3 eBay’s display of a seller’s feedback profile.

Many ecommerce platforms use a star system (typically one through five stars). It is important to note that reviews may be about the product rather than the seller, a well-known example being the product reviews on Amazon. Platforms must be careful about distinguishing between product reviews and seller reviews in order to avoid confusion. Many online platforms offer at least one side of the market the ability to make choices that depend on the reputation of the other side of the market.

Before 2008, buyers and sellers on eBay could leave each other positive, negative or neutral feedback with comments. In 2008 eBay changed the feedback system limiting sellers to leave either positive feedback or no feedback at all. On Amazon’s marketplace, sellers leave no feedback at all; on Airbnb both owners and renters leave feedback; on Uber both drivers and riders leave feedback, which is not made public, yet drivers see a rider’s feedback before accepting a ride and riders see the driver’s feedback after the ride was confirmed.

Whether reputation should be “two-sided,” like it is currently on Airbnb, or practically “one-sided,” like it is currently on eBay and on Amazon’s marketplace, is an important design question. In essence, the platform benefits when feedback is informative and does not cause unnecessary friction as part of the user experience. For example, before eBay acquired PayPal’s online payment system, buyers would send checks or money orders to sellers, meaning that buyers can abuse trust by not sending payment, just as sellers can abuse trust by not shipping the product. As a result, both buyers and sellers needed some guidance about which counterpart is trustworthy. After eBay acquired PayPal, however, it encouraged sellers to use PayPal as the only form of payment. By doing this, gone were the problems of buyers not sending checks and, for the most part, the problem of buyer abuse was solved, which in turn means that feedback left by sellers for buyers became a lot less valuable.Footnote 11

Still, for some time eBay kept the two-sided feedback system, only to later learn that there is a weakness to two-sided feedback. In collaboration with eBay, Bolton, Greiner, and Ockenfels (Reference Bolton, Greiner and Ockenfels2013) used data from eBay during the period when the reputation system was two-sided, and convincingly showed that sellers retaliated against buyers with their feedback. To illustrate their findings, consider pairs of feedback scores, FBi,FSj left by a pair consisting of buyer Biand seller Sjwho constituted a transaction. For example, a transaction in which both buyer and seller left each other positive feedback is denoted +,+, while if the buyer left positive feedback and the seller negative feedback, it is denoted +,. The data first showed that practically all transactions are either +,+ or ,. They then showed that a vast majority of , transactions are characterized by the seller leaving feedback on the same day or the day after the buyer does, while the +,+ transactions happen with less correlation between the buyer’s and seller’s day of leaving feedback. Hence, sellers’ negative feedback scores were primarily retaliatory, which in turn made it painful for buyers to leave negative feedback (a point to which I return later).

This fear of retaliation was most likely a central cause behind the fact that almost all buyers left positive feedback on eBay, which in turn caused eBay to switch from the two-sided reputation system to a one-sided reputation system. This is not, however, a good prescription for all online marketplaces. Take the lodging marketplace Airbnb as an example. Even if payment is mediated by the site, as it is now, there is still a concern that abuse may occur from either side of the market. The dwelling owners can cause harm to renters in many forms, such as misrepresenting the dwelling, leaving it dirty, not giving the renters a key at the prespecified time, and more. At the same time, the renter’s role on Airbnb is not just to pay like they do on eBay and wait for an item to arrive: they too can harm the dwelling owner by leaving the space dirty, causing damage, being very noisy, causing the owner trouble, and more. As such, it is imperative that Airbnb continues to keep a two-sided reputation system for trust to prevail in their marketplace. In fact, Airbnb even verifies the identity of all parties given the high stakes involved. Each marketplace, therefore, must weigh the relative costs and benefits of one- versus two-sided feedback systems.

5.4 How Well Does Reputation Work?

The data made available by online marketplaces have enabled scholars to study how online feedback and reputation mechanisms work in practice.Footnote 12 Most studies used “scraped” data from marketplace webpages and explored whether sellers with higher reputation scores and more transactions receive higher prices and whether reputation seems to matter more for higher priced goods than for lower priced goods.

Early studies collected what are now considered tiny datasets. For example, McDonald and Slawson (Reference McDonald and Slawson2002) collected data from 460 auctions completed in 1998 of collector-quality Harley Davidson Barbie dolls. Because the closing price and the number of bids is bound to be correlated, they used an approach known as Seemingly Unrelated Regressions to simultaneously estimate the effect of reputation on both the number of bids and the closing price. Their results suggest that eBay’s reputation score is positively correlated with both the closing price and the number of bids. However, the interpretation of McDonald and Slawson (Reference McDonald and Slawson2002), as well as similar studies, raises some concerns. First, good reputation may be correlated with a variety of omitted variables influencing the dependent variables. The authors themselves acknowledge unclear language and grammar as possibly confounding factors. Second, though statistically significant, the results are economically very small: for example, a one-point increase in reputation corresponds to four cents increase in final price. With a median sample reputation score of twenty-one points, this means that increasing reputation from none at all to the median increases price by less than $1, a fraction of a percent of the median price of $275.

Jin and Kato (Reference Jin and Kato2006) took a different approach and studied the relationship between price, claimed quality, reputation, and true quality, using observational data of baseball card auctions on eBay. The true quality of cards was determined by purchasing actual cards from online auctions and having them examined by professional rating agencies. Jin and Kato (Reference Jin and Kato2006) collected data of the five most traded baseball cards on eBay for seven months, resulting in 1,124 auctions, of which 67 percent were graded. Of the full sample, 81 percent of auctions sold with at least one offer above the reserve price. Buyers in their sample have two signals for the quality of an ungraded card: the rating and claims made by the seller. The data indicate that claims of quality for ungraded cards seem suspiciously high, both when observing their distribution and when considering sellers’ expected payoffs. The data also show that sellers who claimed extremely high quality had significantly lower ratings, but buyers were still willing to pay more for cards with higher claimed quality. Furthermore, an increase in claimed quality significantly raises the probability of an auction ending with a sale, but ratings do not seem to create a reputation premium, consistent with Livingston (Reference Livingston2005). Perhaps the most interesting result in Jin and Kato (Reference Jin and Kato2006) is that reputable sellers (using eBay’s ratings) are less likely to make extreme claims about their cards’ quality. Moreover, reputable sellers are less likely to default or provide counterfeit cards. However, conditional on authentic delivery, higher reputation ratings are not correlated with higher true quality. This may explain why buyers are more willing to trade with reputable sellers but are not willing to pay more.

Cabral and Hortaçsu (Reference Cabral and Hortaçsu2010) used a different strategy by collecting a series of seller feedback histories, thus creating a panel of seller histories, and proceed to estimate the effect of changes in reputation on a seller’s sales rate. They find that when a seller receives his first negative feedback rating, his weekly sales growth rate drops from a positive rate of 5 percent to a negative rate of 8 percent. To overcome the fact that eBay does not provide information on how many past transactions a seller completed, Cabral and Hortaçsu (Reference Cabral and Hortaçsu2010) make two assumptions and provide evidence that they are reasonable. First, they assume that a seller’s frequency of feedback is a good proxy for the frequency of actual transactions, and second, that feedback correlates with buyer satisfaction.

An interesting question is what the impact would be of introducing a reputation system into a marketplace that did not have one. To answer this question, Cai et al. (Reference Cai, Zhe Jin, Liu and Zhou2014) study the case of Eachnet, a Chinese auction cite that had about a 90 percent share of the Chinese market during its years of operation (1999–2003). Unlike eBay, exchange of products and money was done offline, and this face-to-face exchange may create less uncertainty at the time of the transaction. In 2001 Eachnet introduced a feedback system that enabled buyers to rate sellers after each transaction. Cai et al. (Reference Cai, Zhe Jin, Liu and Zhou2014) received a large amount of data from the platform, containing a random sample of 125,135 sellers who posted almost two million listings throughout Eachnet’s years of operation. Because sellers’ feedback scores are obviously not available prior to the introduction of centralized feedback, their prefeedback reputation is approximated with the cumulative number of successful listings each seller had since joining Eachnet. Cai et al. (Reference Cai, Zhe Jin, Liu and Zhou2014) examined how a seller’s reputation, as approximated by cumulative success rates, affects the seller’s behavior and outcomes, and how things changed after feedback was made available. First, an increase in the cumulative success rate of a seller is correlated with a larger fraction of repeating buyers, but the effect weakens after making feedback available. This is intuitive: centralized feedback is a substitute to the trust built in relationships. Second, centralized feedback leads sellers with higher cumulative success rates to sell more products in more regions, suggesting that formal feedback helps reputable sellers expand into new markets. Last, a higher cumulative success rate is generally correlated with a lower hazard rate of exiting the market, an effect that diminishes after feedback centralization. Though prices appear to be lower for reputable sellers, they do enjoy more listings and higher success rates, in line with the results of Cabral and Hortaçsu (Reference Cabral and Hortaçsu2010).

A shortcoming of observational studies, like those just described, is the possible “endogeneity” concern from potential selection or omitted-variables biases. In other words, it is possible that sellers with higher reputation scores exhibit other information that causes buyers to be more interested in their products, so that it is not the reputation score per se that is accountable for the observed outcomes. Two ways around this are either a randomized controlled experiment, where similar goods and experiences are sold by sellers that are the same but for their reputation, or some source of exogenous variation in reputation scores that are not correlated with other important drivers of outcomes.Footnote 13 Resnick et al. (Reference Resnick, Zeckhauser, Swanson and Lockwood2006) ran a controlled field experiment by offering a series of sales of identical items (collector’s postcards) where they vary reputation by randomly assigning items to either an established seller’s account with a good reputation, or to a new account with little reputation history. They estimated an 8 percent price premium to having 2,000 positive and 1 negative feedback over a reputation of 10 positive and no negative feedbacks, which is quite sizable.

Klein, Lambertz, and Stahl (Reference Klein, Lambertz and Stahl2013) cleverly took advantage of a change in the way that eBay reported feedback, together with the fact that feedback for sellers has two components: the nonanonymous simple feedback of positive, negative, and neutral ratings, and the anonymous feedback of Detailed Seller Ratings (or DSRs, as seen in Figure 5.3). In May 2008, after realizing the problem of seller retaliation (recall the discussion of retaliation in Section 5.3), eBay removed a seller’s ability to leave the buyer negative or neutral feedback. The belief was that this change will encourage buyers to report negative feedback following a poor experience, which can cause sellers to respond in two ways. First, some really bad sellers may leave eBay following a series of negative ratings. Second, sellers may work harder to improve buyer satisfaction. Klein et al. (Reference Klein, Lambertz and Stahl2013) scraped data containing monthly information on feedback from about 15,000 eBay users between July 2006 and July 2009, a period that included both the introduction of anonymous DSR ratings (May 2007) and of one-sided feedback (May 2008). They found that the change to one-sided feedback led to a significant increase in buyer satisfaction using the DSR reviews but did not lead to a change in the exit rate of sellers from the market.

5.5 Biases in Online Feedback Systems

The studies just discussed suggest that reputational forces are at work in online marketplaces, but a question remains: How accurately does feedback capture variation in performance? As suggested earlier, retaliation on eBay may have caused feedback to be biased, as buyers chose to refrain from leaving negative feedback for sellers. A recent literature has demonstrated that user-generated feedback mechanisms suffer from bias. Dellarocas and Wood (Reference Dellarocas and Wood2008) conjectured that the extremely high percent-positive reputation measures on eBay may be because many buyers who suffered poor experiences chose not to leave feedback at all.Footnote 14 They derive implications from the fact that eBay’s reputation system was two-sided (buyers and sellers leave each other feedback) and use these implications to develop an econometric technique that uncovers the true percent of positive transactions. However, because eBay switched to one-sided feedback after 2008, their proposed approach no longer works.

Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) use internal eBay data to directly show how biased reputation measures really are. Their data show that the percent-positive measure has a mean of 99.3% and a median of 100%. The distribution of feedback from their study is described in Figure 5.4, which displays the histogram of seller percent-positive measures from a dataset containing close to two million sellers who completed over fifteen million transactions between June 2011 and May 2014. One naive conclusion is that the reputation system works exceptionally well because bad sellers (below the high 90s) leave the platform. This is not the case: the data show that there are three times as many complaints to customer service as there are negative feedback scores.

Figure 5.4 Percent positive of sellers on eBay.

The findings in Bolton et al. (Reference Bolton, Greiner and Ockenfels2013) described in Section 5.3, that sellers retaliated towards buyers who left them negative feedback, and the evidence described in the study, suggest that for buyers, leaving different types of feedback entails different consequences. In particular, buyers find it more “expensive” to leave a negative review than a positive one, which in turn means that with a given propensity to leave feedback, this asymmetry between leaving positive versus negative feedback inherently creates upward bias. Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) suggest a new quality measure, “effective percent positive” (EPP), which is calculated by dividing the number of positive feedback transactions by the total number of transactions. This penalizes sellers who are associated with more transactions for which the buyers left no feedback, based on the insight that no feedback includes in it a measure of negative outcomes.

The distribution of the EPP measure is described in Figure 5.5 using the same set of sellers for which the percent-positive scores were described in Figure 5.4. EPP has a mean of 64 percent, a median of 67 percent, and exhibits significantly more variation than percent positive. But can this be verified as a better measure of quality?

Figure 5.5 Histogram of sellers’ effective percent-positive scores.

To demonstrate this, Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) use a “revealed preference” approach to study the effect of a seller’s EPP on a buyer’s propensity to continue buying on eBay after that transaction. This distinguishes their paper from the papers that collect scraped data and cannot track the behavior of buyers on the site and allows them to get to the heart of the question of whether reputation mechanisms help buyers avoid low quality sellers. Importantly, eBay does not display the total number of transactions a seller has completed, and buyers cannot therefore compute a seller’s EPP score.

Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) show that a buyer who buys from a seller with a higher EPP score is more likely to continue to transact on eBay again in the future, which by revealed preference suggests a better experience. They also report results from a randomized controlled experiment on eBay that incorporated EPP into eBay’s search-ranking algorithm. The treated group was a random sample of eBay buyers who, when searching for goods on eBay, were shown a list that prioritized products from sellers with a higher EPP score compared to a control group. The results show that treated buyers who were exposed to higher EPP sellers were significantly more likely to return and purchase again on eBay compared to the control group. Jaffe et al. (Reference Jaffe, Coles, Levitt and Popov2019) use data from Airbnb to further explore the revealed preference approach of Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) and find similar results. Further implications about the design and engineering of feedback systems are discussed in Section 5.6.

Mayzlin, Dover, and Chevalier (Reference Mayzlin, Dover and Chevalier2014) exploit different policies about who can leave feedback across several travel sites and show biases in ratings for hotels from the online travel sites that are consistent with strategic feedback manipulation by sellers. What makes that paper particularly clever is that they do not attempt to categorize which reviews are fake reviews versus those that are not, which on the face of it is impossible because fake reviews are designed to mimic real reviews. Instead, they take advantage of a key difference in website rating systems where some websites accept reviews from anyone while others require that reviews be posted by consumers who have purchased a room through the website. If posting a review requires an actual purchase, the cost of a fake review is much higher. The upshot is then that they measure the differences in the distribution of reviews for a given hotel between a website where faking a review is expensive and a website where faking a review is cheap. The results in Mazylin et al. (2014) indeed show greater bunching at the extreme ratings for hotels on the sites where posting reviews is cheaper, and this is exacerbated by local competition (more local hotels). Hence, for reviews to be less biased it is critical to impose some kind of cost to prohibit fake reviews by nonpurchasers.

Fradkin et al. (Reference Fradkin, Grewal, Holtz and Pearson2015) study the bias in online reviews by using internal data from Airbnb, and like Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) report results from field experiments conducted by the online marketplace. In one experiment they offer users a coupon to leave feedback and show the users who were induced to leave feedback report more negative experiences than reviewers in the control group, suggesting that otherwise they would have probably been silent. In a second experiment they disable retaliation in reviews, similar to what eBay did in 2008, and find that retaliation (or rewards for positive feedback) causes a bias, but that the magnitude of this bias is smaller than that caused by a lack of incentives to leave truthful feedback. Interestingly, using data on social interactions between buyers and sellers on the site, they show that such interactions result in less negative reviews. This result suggests that a challenge for online marketplaces is the potential loss of information following the social interaction of buyers and sellers on the site.

Another form of bias is grade inflation. Horton and Golden (Reference Horton and Golden2015) document substantial levels of “reputation inflation” on the online labor marketplace, oDesk, that uses a five-star feedback system for freelance employees who bid on jobs that are posted by potential employers. The data show that from the start of 2007 to the middle of 2014, average feedback scores increased by one star. Like Bolton et al. (Reference Bolton, Greiner and Ockenfels2013), Horton and Golden (Reference Horton and Golden2015) conjecture that giving negative feedback is more costly than giving positive feedback due to retaliation. They further argue that what constitutes harmful feedback depends on the market penalty associated with that feedback. The paper argues that these two factors together can create a race of ever-increasing reputations. Zervas, Proserpio, and Byers (Reference Zervas, Proserpio and Byers2015) demonstrate that grade inflation is also severe on Airbnb, where ratings are overwhelmingly positive, averaged at 4.7 out of 5 stars with 94 percent of property ratings with 4.5 or 5 stars.

One more channel through which bias in reputation may occur is by sellers trying to fraudulently “buy” a reputation that they do not deserve. Brown and Morgan (Reference Brown and Morgan2006) show some cases in which this practice happened on eBay’s marketplace. Xu et al. (Reference Xu, Liu, Wang and Stavrou2015) document and explain the rise of a centralized marketplace for fake reputations for sellers on the Alibaba marketplace in China. Hence, it may be possible for sellers to fraudulently acquire a reputation that they do not deserve, and marketplace designers must be aware of such practices and make every effort to detect and punish this kind of behavior.Footnote 15

5.6 Engineering Reputation Systems

Economic theory takes the view that market participants understand the equilibrium they are playing, and correctly infer information from signals and actions. In practice, however, buyers may not correctly interpret the feedback information they are presented with. Naively, in some sort of absolute scale, a score of 98 percent is considered excellent. But, as Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) show, on eBay this score places a seller below the tenth percentile of seller feedback, and it is unclear whether the more informative EPP measure constructed by Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) would be interpreted correctly by buyers. For this reason, Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) propose not to reveal effective measures to buyers, but instead choose to run a controlled experiment that incorporated the EPP measure into eBay’s search-ranking algorithm.

This approach offers a new direction for improved marketplace performance. Instead of showing buyers information on seller quality, platforms can benefit from a more paternalistic, or regulator-like approach, that does not rely on participants correctly deciphering information. In this sense I very much advocate for the view expressed in Roth (Reference Roth2002) that market designers “cannot work only with the simple conceptual models used for theoretical insights into the general working of markets. Instead, market design calls for an engineering approach” (p. 1341). Trust can therefore be engineered by way of a process in which recommendations rely on underlying data that is not made visible to buyers. Of course, this requires buyers to trust that the platform is operating in their best interest, a trust that I believe is justified. Just as the motivation of repeat business is at the heart of the value of a good reputation, so does future business motivate platforms to offer buyers a positive experience every time they purchase on a marketplace platform.

Marketplaces can rely on a variety of internal data to infer the quality of sellers. For example, many marketplaces allow buyers and sellers to exchange messages before and after a transaction occurs. Masterov, Mayer, and Tadelis (Reference Masterov, Mayer and Tadelis2015) showed that text-mining these messages could reveal unhappy buyers even if they chose not to leave negative feedback. This information could also be used to rank sellers by quality, and manipulate the consideration sets of buyers. More advanced implementation of Natural Language Processing can offer deeper insights into how messages translate to experience and buyer satisfaction. Marketplace platforms can then create engineered measures of seller performance that aggregate both what is seen publicly (past feedback) and what is not (messages or customer service complaints), to create better measures of seller quality. Search algorithms can be engineered to promote better quality sellers for the continued health of the marketplace, alleviating buyers from deciphering what a certain rating means.

User-generated feedback will continue to be an important signal that marketplaces will use to match buyers with high quality sellers, and the challenge of engineering ways to procure more accurate feedback remains. The experiments described in Fradkin et al. (Reference Fradkin, Grewal, Holtz and Pearson2015) suggest that a challenge for online marketplaces is the potential loss of information following any social interaction of buyers and sellers on the site. As such, marketplaces may choose some sort of incentives to motivate more truthful feedback from buyers, such as the use of coupons to motivate feedback as described in Fradkin et al. (Reference Fradkin, Grewal, Holtz and Pearson2015) and similarly, the use of rebates for feedback described in Li, Tadelis, and Zhou (2020).

One last issue warrants discussion, especially because of tension it raises with the common belief that a drive for transparency is likely to be central to any regulatory oversight, as well the discomfort it creates for the fundamental approach of game theory. As mentioned earlier, Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015) propose not to reveal effective measures to buyers to remove the burden to interpret what feedback really means. However, they discuss a second reason not to make new measures of reputation transparent: transparency can reduce the quality of information that the platform can generate from these measures. Take for example the effective percent-positive score developed by Nosko and Tadelis (Reference Nosko and Tadelis2015), which counts silence as a negative mark against a seller. If sellers learn that this is part of the way they are evaluated, then they would harass buyers who do not leave them feedback, which in turn can both generate positive feedback when it is not warranted, as well as drive buyers to abandon the platform. This suggests that transparency is not necessarily the best policy. Indeed, Google’s famous “Quality Score” is used by the company to rank sponsored search links, and though the company does give guidance on ways to improve the score, they do not reveal the exact way in which it is estimated. This allows them to control the user experience for quality of ads because, after all, the main reason so many people use Google is because of the quality of the search engine and the relevance of ads.

As for the discomfort with game theory, note that at the heart of “equilibrium” analysis is that every player has correct beliefs about everything relevant to their environment. But in the case of platform quality, it may be in the best interest of the platform (and its buyer-side) that sellers are left in the dark about some aspects of how they are evaluated, and only given coarse feedback about how to improve. If the exact formula of evaluation relies on hidden biases in the data, then revealing these hidden biases may cause behavior that will undermine the value of the current formulas, effectively causing the platform designers to play a cat-and-mouse game with abusive sellers. Even though I agree with eBay’s founder, Pierre Omidyar, who was famously quoted saying that “People are basically good,” platforms need to safeguard against the few who try to take advantage of others, and this seems to require making sure that bad actors do not have insight into the ways they are being detected.

5.7 Concluding Remarks

Reputation and feedback systems are critical to foster trust and trustworthiness in online marketplaces. The rise of these platforms and their penetration to practically every household owes much of its success to reputation and feedback systems.

In the past few years there has been a lot of scrutiny by regulators who question whether and how to protect customers from a variety of hazards on sharing economy platforms. The rapid growth of such platforms suggests that feedback and reputation systems do a reasonably good job at policing bad behavior, possibly eliminating the need for onerous rules and regulations. At the same time, several studies described in this chapter document biases in feedback and reputation systems that can be improved upon.

There is still much to explore in order to deepen our understanding of how feedback and reputation systems can be improved. It is clear that the design and engineering of feedback and reputation systems will continue to play an important role in the broader area of market design as it applies to sharing economy platforms.

6 Labor and the Platform Economy

Juliet B. Schor and Steven P. Vallas
6.1 Introduction

A defining feature of twenty-first century capitalism has been the rapid growth of platform work, which allows firms to use digital technology (websites or apps) to mediate economic transactions between service providers and customers. Though platform work as yet accounts for a small proportion of the labor force – estimates typically lie in the low single digits (Collins et al. Reference Collins, Garin, Jackson, Koustas and Payne2019) – many scholars are convinced that the ranks of the platform labor force will grow significantly in coming years (Sundararajan Reference Sundararajan2016), exercising potentially far-reaching effects on the nature of work and employment, perhaps even reconfiguring what is conventionally meant by a “job.” Mindful of the stakes, academic researchers have generated a flood of studies of platform work (Calo and Rosenblat Reference Calo and Rosenblat2017; Ravenelle Reference Ravenelle2019; Schor et al. Reference Schor, Attwood-Charles, Cansoy, Carfagna, Eddy, Fitzmaurice, Ladegaard and Wengronowitz2020b; Wood et al. Reference Wood, Graham, Lehdonvirta and Hjorth2019). Yet this research has provided little clarity or consensus on any number of important questions. How does “algorithmic management” reshape the exercise of power and authority over labor? How will firms in the conventional economy be affected by the rise of platform work? What adjustments are needed in regulatory policy and welfare-state provisions, given the disruptive power that platform firms have shown? Will the availability of crowd-working sites such as Upwork and Mechanical Turk encourage firms to outsource their staffing systems? Or will platforms instead foster a more inclusive economy, enabling workers in marginalized regions or those with disabilities to gain greater access to income earning opportunities? Finally, how are legal and political struggles over platform workers’ rights likely to evolve? Which groups will succeed in shaping the narrative that defines platform work in the years to come?

In this chapter we can hardly aim to resolve these questions. Our goals are more modest, aiming to outline the main lines of contention in the literature, to identify major gaps in our knowledge, and to suggest some of the most important areas for future research as nations struggle with the structural upheavals unfolding across the contemporary capitalist landscape.

The chapter begins by sketching three dominant lines of analysis that have opened up in recent years: First, a hopeful view, in which platforms help to expand the range of freedom and autonomy that income earners enjoy; second, a technology-centered approach, in which algorithms and systems of digital surveillance and evaluation are used to establish greater company control over labor; and third, a view in which platforms accelerate a trend toward more precarious forms of work, with workers classified as independent contractors who are ineligible for statutory protections and welfare-state benefits. The chapter then points to one source of complexity in the field, which helps account for the continuing contention: Heterogeneity in the platform workforce itself, with varying segments of labor differentially positioned with respect to the platforms themselves. We end by briefly alluding to the regulatory struggles and forms of worker mobilization that platforms have provoked and then speculate about possible paths that might lead toward more humane yet innovative uses of the platform paradigm.

6.2 Dominant Approaches in the Literature

The rise of digitally mediated economic transactions has generated tremendous interest from scholars in a wide range of fields – from economics, sociology, and geography to law, management, engineering, and computer science. In part as a result of this range, as well as differences within disciplines, the literature on labor and the sharing sector is quite diverse. Indeed, even the terms scholars use to capture this phenomenon differ, with such terms as the sharing, on-demand, or platform economy competing for attention.Footnote 1 Here we focus on three of the main approaches that have dominated the literature – those emphasizing how the digital technologies of the sharing economy yield efficiencies and enhanced opportunities for entrepreneurship for workers; those that focus on how these technologies are used to surveil and control workers; and the third, largest group, which emphasizes the precarity of sharing labor as a result of platform policies and workers’ employment status. We discuss them in turn.

The first approach is mainly found in economics, management, engineering, and related fields, as well as some sociological accounts. It centers on the ways in which the major technological affordances of the sharing sector enable new efficiencies and economic relationships. These come from two major innovations – the use of matching and search algorithms to pair buyers and sellers and the crowdsourcing of reputational information and ratings from users. These technologies are at the heart of most platforms, or what economists have termed “two-sided markets,” (Rochet and Tirole Reference Rochet and Tirole2003), as they facilitate transactions among unknown users by reducing search costs and providing some reputational security. As a result the sharing economy is thought to reduce transaction costs and make self-employment more feasible for individuals (Einav, Farronato, and Levin Reference Einav, Farronato and Levin2016). Some scholars also emphasize the freedom to set schedules and working hours that is typical of platform work (Sundararajan Reference Sundararajan2016). Equally important are claims that digitally mediated work (especially crowd-working sites) can include members of the workforce who might otherwise be excluded, owing to geographic barriers, caregiving obligations, or ethno-racial bias (Bennhold Reference Bennhold2017; Mays 2018; Zanoni Reference Zanoni, Vallas and Kovalainen2019). This perspective focuses on the new opportunities created by the sector and the benefits it can provide. In contrast to the two other approaches, it does not recognize issues of power between labor and sharing companies, nor does it acknowledge the possibility of negative outcomes for platform workers, especially as firms initially devoted to peer-to-peer sharing among users evolve into giant firms with operations across the globe.

The second perspective also views digital technologies as the central and unique feature of sharing platforms, but emphasizes their dark side, in particular their ability to control workers using digital means such as algorithms. While the particulars vary across services, nearly all for-profit sharing apps include certain core elements that these scholars argue expand corporate control over the performance of service providers. One such element is the use of surveillance technologies, whether they are locational, as in driving and delivery, or visual observation and accounting in the case of digital tasks. In addition, the use of customers to rate worker performance – a phenomenon Maffie (Reference Maffie2020) describes as the “laundering of managerial control” – provides another type of surveillance, and one that may create what has been termed “algorithmic insecurity” (Curchod et al. Reference Curchod, Patriotta, Cohen and Neysen2019; Wood and Lehdonvirta Reference Wood and Lehdonvirta2021). In this view, ratings metrics that are visible to all customers and are used to shape workers’ job prospects impose a disciplinary effect on workers that far transcends what predigital forms of supervision are able to achieve. Moreover, because they typically individualize the workforce, foregoing socially shared workplaces, platforms reduce the opportunity for labor to informally negotiate the terms and conditions of employment, as was long true of traditional work organizations. Hence, “algorithmic control” scholars see a digital panopticon in which workers cannot escape the discipline and punishment of the app. In contrast to the efficiencies approach, scholars in this tradition emphasize the superior informational position of the platform and its ability to exercise power over workers (Calo and Rosenblat Reference Calo and Rosenblat2017; Rosenblat and Stark Reference Rosenblat and Stark2016). Examples of information asymmetry include withholding destination information or the prices paid by customers from drivers or delivery couriers. Another theme in this literature is gamification – the ability of the platform to offer bonuses and incentives in order to keep earners on the app, and to seamlessly change those conditions in order to achieve the objectives of the platform, rather than satisfy the desires of the worker – a power that is established in legally binding terms of service that all users must accept (Bearson, Kenney, and Zysman Reference Bearson, Kenney and Zysman2020; van Doorn and Chen Reference van Doorn and Chen2021). Another theme is the use of algorithms to dispense discipline and punishment, including “deactivation,” that is, worker termination. While it is important to recognize the control dimensions of these technologies as well as the power imbalance between platforms and their workers, this approach can at times display a similar, albeit inverse, weakness to the efficiency approach, which is that it can overstate the ability of the technology to control labor. There is growing evidence of the ability of workers to evade, outsmart, and resist algorithmic control (Chen Reference Chen2018; Cameron Reference Cameron2018; Shapiro Reference Shapiro2018; Wood et al. Reference Wood, Graham, Lehdonvirta and Hjorth2019). Strategies are commonly shared on social forums uniting platform workers on Uber, Lyft, and many delivery apps, which may help foster collective actions aimed at pressuring firms to alter the workings of the app. The algorithmic control perspective can also exaggerate the novelty of this type of control, given that technology, and even algorithms have been used to structure the labor process long before the advent of the current platform model.

The third perspective emphasizes the precarity of this type of work. Virtually all platforms engage their workers as independent contractors, rather than employees. However, while independent contractors do nominally retain control over many aspects of their work, some precarity scholars argue that financial need obviates de facto control as these workers are either forced into very long hours or to work whenever there is customer demand (Ravenelle Reference Ravenelle2019). The precarity approach also calls attention to the risk shift associated with platform work. These earners are responsible for providing the capital goods necessary to do the work, and responsible when customers engage in malfeasance or nonpayment. Furthermore, they are denied the standard protections and benefits of employment such as a minimum hourly wage, unemployment benefits, and compensation for workplace injuries (Dubal Reference Dubal2017; Vallas Reference Vallas2019). Legal scholars have argued that most platform workers are misclassified as independent contractors, since key decisions concerning prices, work rules, and other practices are set unilaterally by the platform. As a result, there are ongoing judicial, regulatory, and legislative challenges to these platform policies. The precarity perspective departs from the previous two in that it sees precarious platform labor as part of a trend that predates the sharing economy by decades (Kalleberg Reference Kalleberg2011; Kalleberg and Vallas Reference Kalleberg and Vallas2018), and which is propelled by policy choices of employers rather than the exigencies of technology. In addition, because precarity is a larger trend throughout the economy, these scholars tend not to focus on the novelty or uniqueness of the sharing economy, in contrast to the previous two approaches. The major weakness of the precarity approach, in our view, is that it pays insufficient attention to the technological innovations of the sharing sector, while also ignoring the heterogeneous composition of the platform workforce, (significant portions of which may view platform work as a solution to precarity rather than a source of it). As we discuss in the next section, the platform workforce is uniquely diverse in ways that do not always support the precarity narrative.

This overview raises a number of issues that warrant discussion. First, although we have emphasized the differences among the three approaches, there are important instances in which scholars have combined elements from each approach. For example, Davis (Reference Davis2016) suggests that platforms use digital technology to control labor algorithmically while also transforming the employment relationship in far-reaching ways. In this view, platforms enable for-profit companies to reconfigure employment, completing a trajectory that leads work from the career, to the job, to the “task.” This view essentially combines the second and third approaches sketched earlier. A second example is that of Schor et al (Reference Schor, Attwood-Charles, Cansoy, Carfagna, Eddy, Fitzmaurice, Ladegaard and Wengronowitz2020b), who argues that the “sharing” feature of the platform economy has largely been coopted (“hijacked”) by large corporations, but that social movements and progressive policies make it possible to reclaim the logic of reciprocity that informed the sharing economy at its birth.

A second point concerns recent efforts to transcend the three approaches we have sketched earlier, developing frameworks that better capture the distinctive features of labor platforms. One example is that of Vallas and Schor (Reference Vallas and Schor2020), who see platforms as heralding a new organizational form, in addition to that of markets, hierarchies, and networks. The argument here is that platforms combine elements of these prior economic structures but do so in ways that achieve an institutional form that is qualitatively distinct. In this view, two key features that platforms exhibit are their reduced barriers to entry (which generates greater heterogeneity in their workforces) and a general “retreat from control” (which delegates practical decisions and the labor of evaluation to platform participants). In this view, platforms achieve their power precisely by relaxing elements that had figured prominently during industrial capitalism. A similar formulation is that of Watkins and Stark (Reference Watkins and Stark2018, see also Stark and Pais Reference Stark and Pais2021), who also see platforms as a distinct organizational form that operates by coopting the resources and assets of the entities that surround them. Both these views emphasize the instability of the platform economy, whose reproduction rests on political and regulatory inputs to manage the tensions and conflicts that platforms themselves create. We discuss these tensions in our concluding section.

6.3 Recent Trends in Platform Labor

An important issue that has emerged in research on labor platforms concerns the heterogeneity that characterizes the platform work experience. Though the tendency in early studies was to generalize about the work situations that platform activity fosters, scholars have acknowledged important variations in the experience of platform working conditions. While many workers do appreciate the scheduling flexibility and relative autonomy from supervision that much app-based work provides, other workers bemoan the job’s inability to provide a living wage or other sources of security. We contend that this difference issue is not merely a matter of contrasting orientations toward platform work but is instead a structural attribute, rooted in both labor market institutions and the platforms, the consequence of which is to stratify the platform workforce in socially and politically significant ways. This phenomenon holds obvious importance for any effort to support worker mobilization or platform regulation, but it remains poorly understood.

One question that has bedeviled researchers is how best to categorize the differing positions that platform workers occupy. The most common approach is to distinguish platform workers on the basis of their temporal engagement with the work – a simple approach that typically distinguishes between part-time and full-time platform workers (Robinson Reference Robinson2017; Rosenblat Reference Rosenblat2018). Though virtually all studies report that part-timers constitute the majority of platform workers on apps such as Uber, they also indicate that longer hour workers perform a disproportionate amount of the work (Parrott and Reich Reference Parrott and Reich2018, Reference Parrott and Reich2020). To better understand this division, researchers have begun to characterize workers in more differentiated ways, hoping to better understand the context in which platform work is done. In her multiplatform study, for example, Ravenelle (Reference Ravenelle2019) develops a threefold typology that distinguishes between “strugglers,” who try to make a living entirely from their platform earnings; “strivers,” who use their platform earnings to supplement income from their primary jobs; and “success stories,” who use their app-based experience to accumulate wealth, forming small businesses in catering or real estate management. The thrust of Ravenelle’s argument – platforms have multiplied the precarity of platform workers – is based only on the first of these types, overlooking the complexity she herself reports.

One effort to capture the stratified nature of the platform workforce emerges in the multiplatform study conducted by Schor and her colleagues (2020a), which emphasizes the degree to which workers depend on their platform earnings to pay their basic expenses. At one end of this continuum are “dependent earners,” who primarily or fully rely on the platform for their livelihoods. At the other end are “supplemental earners,” who can rely on their primary jobs for income, and whose platform work is largely discretionary. In between are “partially dependent” earners, who either work on multiple platforms or who have several jobs. Because the most dependent earners are compelled to accept whatever tasks that are thrown their way, they face a harsher and more coercive work situation. By contrast, supplemental earners can afford to be more selective, accepting only tasks that offer relatively generous returns. Such disparities become all the more pronounced in light of the income inequalities evident across different platforms, in which some platforms (those requiring higher levels of capital goods or skill) provide higher earnings and greater autonomy than do others. Lower income individuals are more likely to participate in labor or gig platforms, while those with higher income are increasingly able to participate on more lucrative capital platforms, such as short-term accommodation sites. The implication, supported by survey research recently conducted in Denmark (Ilsøe, Larsen, and Bach Reference Ilsøe, Larsen and Bach2021) is that the platform economy reproduces preexisting tendencies toward segmentation rooted in the conventional economy. Moreover, the emergence of platform work may help privileged workers claim income-earning opportunities previously accessed by working-class earners, in effect crowding out the most vulnerable members of the workforce (Schor Reference Schor2017). Overlapping these sources of inequality are racial and ethnic dynamics, which scholars are only beginning to explore. Dubal (Reference Dubal2021) has argued that the disproportionate presence of Black and Latinx earners in the platform economy amounts to a new racial wage code, as platforms have attempted to create a third, implicitly racialized employment status between independent contractor and employee, with lower wages, fewer benefits, and substandard protections. Her analysis shows that platform firms have invoked racial justice language (i.e., the inclusion of ethnic and racial minorities), but have acted in ways that reduce these workers’ access to equal employment opportunity. Whether, where, and how gig work becomes racialized is an important matter that labor market analysts must address.

Two issues emerge at this juncture, both centering on the relations that exist among the disparate strata of platform workers. The first concerns the ability of platforms to evade the provision of benefits and other job rewards that conventional firms must offer. The notion here, emphasized by Schor et al. (Reference Schor, Attwood-Charles, Cansoy, Ladegaard and Wengronowitz2020a), is that labor platforms function as “free riders” –that is, when they grow, they do so partly by operating parasitically, avoiding the employer contributions to unemployment insurance, social security, and health insurance that conventional firms must pay. This issue has become more visible in the United States during the COVID pandemic. Because platform workers were not covered by unemployment insurance, providing them with income support during COVID required the federal government to subsidize costs that would normally have been paid by employers. Here the costs of operation were socialized, but the profits (where firms were profitable) remained in private hands. Pressure on the companies to treat their workers better has also led the companies to respond with the creation of a “third category” of worker, between independent contractor and employee. This category offers some workers small monetary benefits for healthcare, and the illusion of a statutory minimum wage, but also permanently bars them from employee status (Dubal Reference Dubal2021). Such a category was created in California in 2020 via the passage of Proposition 22 and Uber, Lyft, and Doordash are currently trying to expand this model throughout the United States.

A second issue that has emerged again concerns relations among the various strata making up the platform workforce. The argument here, as developed by Rosenblat Reference Rosenblat2018 (see also Robinson Reference Robinson2017; Robinson and Vallas Reference Robinson and Vallas2020), is that the stratification of the platform workforce is a vital element in the labor control systems on which labor platforms rely. In this view, the ready availability of occasional workers – those who have alternative sources of income – “reduces pressure on employers to create more sustainable earning opportunities” (Rosenblat Reference Rosenblat2018: 52–53). In other words, part time or supplemental earners serve as an industrial reserve army in modern dress, providing platforms with a workforce that is “tolerant of working conditions that are anathema to occupational drivers trying to support their families” (Rosenblat Reference Rosenblat2018: 54). Supporting this view is Robinson’s study of Uber drivers in Boston (Robinson Reference Robinson2017), which found that occasional drivers were significantly less aware of their actual costs of operation than longer hour or full-time drivers, and thus were more easily exploited by the platform. However, this view stands at odds with the logic of Schor et al.’s argument (2020a), in which occasional or supplemental earners are able to enjoy higher wages than their fully dependent counterparts. If this were true, it would be hard to see how supplemental earners could undermine the labor market position of more dependent workers. Clearly, much more research is needed on the origins and consequences of labor market stratification among the platform workforce, especially as platform companies face investor demands for profitability, or at least smaller quarterly losses. The latter pressures have seemed to generate a downward trajectory in platform working conditions, though it remains unclear which sectors exhibit this trend, and whether regional or institutional influences mediate its effects.

Beyond the question of stratification among platform workers, a host of broader questions have emerged regarding the relation between the platform economy and the work structures it seems to disrupt. A key question here concerns the relation between platform work and the professions. Research has suggested that the “golden age” of the professions has long since passed (Gorman and Sandefur Reference Gorman and Sandefur2011), as autonomous professional occupations have tended to splinter into more specialized forms of “knowledge work,” supplying expertise via arrangements that are shaped more powerfully by the demands of markets and firms than by professional norms. Though this pattern unfolds in varying ways across the different sectors of professional work, the question is how the platform economy will affect the work and employment situations that professionals face in such fields as health care, journalism, legal services, and other traditionally autonomous occupations. In many of these fields, task-based, independent contracting arrangements have grown, ratings metrics have assumed a newfound importance, and an emphasis on commercialism increasingly conflicts with professional autonomy. A kindred issue here concerns the relation between crowd-working sites such as Upwork and Fiverr and the conventional bureaucratic contexts in which professionals have often been employed. Does the availability of crowd working encourage organizations to outsource professional work through digital means, as seems to have unfolded in journalism, legal services, and computer science (Christin Reference Christin2020; Osnowitz Reference Osnowitz2010)? In her study of crowd-working sites, Berg (Reference Berg2016) notes that the single largest user of Amazon mTurk is an editing and publishing firm that relies on Turkers for its entire workforce. Though some have envisioned the growth of such a trend (Scholz Reference Scholz2016), little systematic research on these substitution dynamics has yet been conducted. Arguably, the pandemic, which has fostered much wider acceptance of “working from home” arrangements, may encourage firms to explore new forms of work organization, not only reversing the historical trend toward spatial agglomeration but also fostering a greater reliance on the crowdsourcing of projects and task-based compensation. This raises the prospect of the degradation of pay and conditions, long-recognized attributes of piece-rate systems (Dubal Reference Dubal2020), for middle-class work.

One of the characteristic features of many platforms has been their strategic emphasis on growth, rather than profitability. In effect, platforms have sought to use first-mover advantages and/or network effects – in which the value of the firm’s services grows in proportion to its adoption – as a glide path to monopoly status, capturing markets that will only later support profits. The best example of such a strategy is of course that of Uber, which has incurred massive losses in its effort to establish market dominance. As Srnicek (Reference Srnicek2016) has noted, such a strategy presupposes the ready availability of patient capital from investors. Yet as firms go public, pressures to turn a profit are likely to rise, leading unprofitable firms to tighten their labor and compensation practices, generating a downward trajectory in working conditions (Vallas Reference Vallas2019; Schor et al Reference Schor, Attwood-Charles, Cansoy, Carfagna, Eddy, Fitzmaurice, Ladegaard and Wengronowitz2020b). We have already seen this from a number of platforms, particularly in ride-hail and delivery. Without embracing a mechanistic approach linking austerity to resistance, it seems that this downward trajectory has exacerbated the labor relations tensions that platforms often provoke, prompting regulatory agencies, legislators, and courts to reexamine the practices in which platform firms engage, potentially reconfiguring their treatment of workers as independent contractors (Dubal and Schor Reference Dubal and Schor2021).

6.4 Conclusion: The Future for Platform Labor?

Not surprisingly, then, tensions between platforms and their workers have intensified in the past few years. The deterioration of earnings in ride-hail and food delivery (Farrell, Greig, and Hamoudi Reference Farrell, Greig and Hamoudi2018) has led to increased union organizing and periodic flash strikes. Contestation continued through the 2020–2021 lockdown, spurred by questions of protective personal equipment, exposure to the virus, and over-hiring on some platforms. The pandemic itself scrambled demand across platforms, with ride-hail collapsing and package, food, and grocery delivery all growing dramatically. At the same time, regulatory activity has accelerated, raising many questions about the future of labor in the platform economy. Beginning in 2018, municipalities began more serious attempts to control the platforms (Schor et al. Reference Schor, Attwood-Charles, Cansoy, Carfagna, Eddy, Fitzmaurice, Ladegaard and Wengronowitz2020b). In San Francisco, new regulations to reduce Airbnb activity began. New York City instituted a minimum wage for ride-hail drivers. Seattle began a process to do something similar. The State of California passed AB5, which made gig workers employees, in a dramatic departure from the independent contractor model that dominates. While Uber, Lyft, and Doordash were able to carve out their workers from that statute in a bitter electoral fight in 2020, the viability of this arrangement has come under increasing scrutiny. In London, Uber was forced to transform its workers into employees. In the European Union, tolerance for platforms’ attempts to evade labor laws is likely to end soon.

These developments suggest that the future of platform labor remains uncertain. One possibility is that in North America and Europe, pressures to convert workers to employees will mount, especially where progressive governments are in power (though even conservative governments have begun to consider applying antitrust statutes to digital behemoths, potentially widening their vulnerability to industrial and economic reform). The other possibility is that the gig model will entrench itself and expand, providing a powerful model for the organization of work, leading conventional firms to convert their expensive workforces into independent contractors. Another option is one in which employment law and regulations institute a “third category” of gig workers, giving them some of the benefits typically associated with employment, but not many of its privileges and conditions. While we cannot foresee which of these pathways the sector will take, what we can predict is that, like its first decade of its existence, the second is likely to be characterized by heterogeneity, conflict, and continuous change, as the platform and conventional economies grow ever more intertwined.

7 Contemplating the Next Generation of Sharing Economy Regulation

Rashmi Dyal-Chand
7.1 Introduction

As with any new and disruptive market force, the sharing economy has posed a significant regulatory challenge. Indeed, it is fair to say that the first generation of regulations of the sharing economy exhibits confoundment over basic definitional questions. What are the best legal analogies for sharing economy platforms? What are the goals and interests at stake? And how do the participants in the sharing economy view the need for, or value of, regulation? These definitional struggles have obscured equally important questions that remain unanswered. Significantly, it remains unclear how different sharing industries will develop, and this unknown continues to make regulation extraordinarily challenging.

Yet, as we consider the next generation of regulations of and for the sharing economy, we do have at least some of the benefit of hindsight. We have now seen the values held by platform proprietors, consumers, and workers in the sharing economy as such values are expressed through market practices. For example, we have seen the extent to which Uber and Lyft have replaced busses and subways as an essential form of transportation, and we have seen the increased access they create to areas that are inaccessible by public transportation. These developments redefine values such as convenience and accessibility in ways that the first generation of sharing economy regulations did not anticipate. We have even experienced the extremes in need, usage, and access dictated by a global pandemic. We know, for example, that while platform proprietors tend to portray platforms as attractive online alternatives to consumer marketplaces for accessing products and services, an increasing number of consumers view some forms of sharing economy businesses as basic necessities.

This chapter reviews the first generation of sharing economy regulations and proposes an approach for developing the second generation of regulations. In Section 7.2, I argue that first-generation sharing economy regulations rely on legal categories and assumptions that have been used to address business operations that have developed over decades (sometimes centuries), but that such legal approaches are at times ill-suited to regulation of the sharing economy.Footnote 1 In Section 7.3, I argue for a new regulatory approach that directly addresses core principles or values in the sharing economy. I focus in particular on four core principles that ought to serve as foundations for the next generation of sharing economy regulations.

7.2 First Generation Regulations
7.2.1 Safety and Consumer Protection

Some of the earliest and most important regulations of the sharing economy were those responding to safety and other consumer protection concerns raised by users of sharing platforms, especially those who used home- and car-sharing services such as Uber and Airbnb. Such concerns included reports of sexual assault, harassment, and other forms of unsafe behavior by drivers.Footnote 2 While renters also raised similar concerns with respect to home-renting services, some of Airbnb’s most prominent troubles were raised by hosts whose homes were burglarized or misused by renters.Footnote 3

The first generation of regulatory responses to such safety concerns was either to ban sharing businesses from operating, to sanction them, or to require them to obtain the same permits required of their competitors in the non-sharing economy for rooms, rides, and other services. Thus, for example, London recently banned Uber citing safety concerns, and California fined the company $59 million for failing to turn over information on sexual assaults.Footnote 4 These and other car-sharing services also faced repeated efforts by states to require some level of permitting.Footnote 5 Similarly, Airbnb became entangled in disputes about the legality of its business operations in New York City, Paris, and other cities.Footnote 6

Sharing economy businesses typically fought these regulatory measures by arguing that they were not hotels, rental agencies, or taxicab companies.Footnote 7 Rather, they claimed they were only the providers of software that facilitates online markets.Footnote 8 They also developed their own internal measures for assuring customers about safety and product efficacy, many of which increased the transparency of their measures as a means of transferring the burden of safety assurance to their customers.Footnote 9 For example, Uber claimed to screen criminal and driving records and to provide a transparent system for reviewing driver profiles and the anonymous ratings of other users.Footnote 10 In 2019, in partnership with the National Sexual Violence Resource Center, the company released its own safety report detailing the number of accidents and assaults that occurred during Uber rides.Footnote 11 Airbnb went considerably further by providing hosts with a “host guarantee.”Footnote 12 In 2019, after five people were killed at an Airbnb property, the company pledged to verify all its listings and provide a hotline for neighborhood complaints.Footnote 13

More recently, regulators at especially the municipal level in some cities have begun to think about safety and consumer protection from a broader perspective, including traffic safety and congestion, neighborhood safety and preservation, and environmental protection.Footnote 14 Some cities have even begun responding to concerns about loss of permanent housing and neighborhood gentrification.Footnote 15 While most, and arguably all, consumer protection regulation is justified on the grounds that it forces the internalization of negative externalities,Footnote 16 these more recent regulatory moves seem to recognize the breadth of the negative externalities that have proliferated in some sharing economy sectors. Though reactive, such regulation implicitly acknowledges the enormous extent to which network effects drive the development of the sharing economy. However, the piecemeal manifestation of these regulatory acknowledgements does not really comprehend the systemic relevance of both positive and negative externalities in the sharing economy.

7.2.2 Discrimination

A significant interdisciplinary literature has captured the proliferation of racial and other forms of discrimination across sharing economy industries. One well-known analysis, by Nancy Leong and Aaron Belzer, described the differing experiences of White and Black Uber customers, wherein the former were able to obtain Uber rides quickly and easily, while the latter had more difficulty obtaining Uber rides. Leong and Belzer traced the differing experiences partly to discrimination by Uber drivers, and particularly the rating system pursuant to which the drivers gave lower ratings to Black passengers.Footnote 17 But multiple studies have also traced discrimination to the very algorithms used by Uber.Footnote 18 In the United States, these algorithms incorporate geographical and other data that reflect residential racial segregation resulting from redlining and other hallmarks of structural racism.

The proprietors of platform technologies argue that the product features that have contributed most straightforwardly to discrimination on their platforms have other claimed benefits. For example, Uber’s ratings system is intended to increase transparency for both drivers and passengers, which Uber claims makes its ridesharing service safer for all involved and “includes steps to mitigate racial bias.”Footnote 19 Airbnb and other home-sharing services make similar claims about their ratings system.Footnote 20

With some important recent exceptions, the first generation of regulations has barely addressed these forms of discrimination. While algorithmic bias is the subject of intense scholarly attention by legal experts, it has not translated into many lawsuits or much law reform.Footnote 21 Moreover, to the extent they have resulted in legal redress, successful claims have relied largely on existing laws that are not well-tailored to addressing algorithmic bias or other forms of discrimination that result from the industry norms of platform operation. Thus, for example, current regulation has failed to address the lack of transparency in the development of algorithms or the extraordinary extent to which intellectual property rights shield discriminatory behavior.Footnote 22

7.2.3 Workers Rights

Some sharing economy firms, especially Uber, have also come under attack for their treatment of the workers who provide services through their platforms. Several lawsuits have claimed that these individuals are not really independent contractors or businesses that contract with companies such as Uber; rather, they are employees.Footnote 23 This distinction has significant consequences, because some states (such as the Commonwealth of Massachusetts) provide extensive protections to employees, including requiring employers to provide unemployment and health benefits.Footnote 24 Lawsuits in Massachusetts and California also defeated Uber’s restrictions on the ability of drivers to request and retain tips.Footnote 25 These regulatory moves are another example of the growing recognition that negative externalities are also proliferating on the supply side of the sharing economy.

Of course, these companies dispute such claims, arguing instead that they have a much more limited role in these networks. However, the tide has begun to turn against them, opening a path for at least some sharing economy workers to have the benefits of true employment, including perhaps even unionization. The first generation of sharing economy regulations has left a significant open question, though, about the appropriate legal perspective on workers in platforms that are more genuinely peer-to-peer in their operation.Footnote 26

Recent scholarship has also begun to capture the racial inequalities among workers that are perpetuated by such platforms. In her analysis of a recent survey of platform workers, Daria Roithmayr noted: “Because workers of color have fewer options than their white counterparts, they are less free to refuse precarious work, and are more likely to form the core component of motivated workers on which the on-demand economy relies.”Footnote 27 Thus far, this form of discrimination on platforms has not resulted in much regulatory intervention.

7.2.4 Anticompetitive Behavior

A prominent form of first-generation regulatory interventions was aimed at preventing perceived anticompetitive behavior by businesses involved in the sharing economy. These claims were generally raised by traditional businesses, such as hotel or taxicab companies, that competed with sharing networks. Such businesses argued that by avoiding the costs associated with obtaining permits and complying with other regulations, sharing businesses were able to operate at lower costs.Footnote 28 Taxicab companies in Maryland even claimed antitrust violations on the grounds that Uber engages in price-fixing.Footnote 29

The regulatory responses to these claims of anticompetitive behavior generally involved revising state or local anticompetition and permitting laws to apply to sharing networks. For example, Chicago considered an ordinance imposing permitting requirements on car-sharing services.Footnote 30 Similarly, New York City radically limited the extent to which people could work as hosts through Airbnb. Both in their narrower focus on anticompetitive behavior and in their implicit recognition of the effects on neighbors of Airbnb hosts and other third parties, such regulations are yet another example of first-generation regulatory efforts to address negative externalities.

7.2.5 Taxation

Finally, and not surprisingly, regulatory authorities have puzzled over the question of how to tax the first generation of sharing economy businesses. One pair of prominent scholars described Congress and the Internal Revenue Service as cycling between a “Proactive Approach,” whereby they “change existing regulations to encourage the growth of new industries,” and a “Neutrality Approach” in which they “cut back on regulatory benefits all around.”Footnote 31 Meanwhile another pair of prominent scholars concluded that current tax law largely is capable of “tax[ing] sharing” and that the application of tax doctrine to sharing businesses is “not particularly novel.”Footnote 32 They did, however, caution that some sharing businesses have behaved opportunistically in exploiting regulatory ambiguities in the tax arena.Footnote 33 Indeed, this observation seems to be shared by many tax law experts. More generally, these and other commentators have noted that, as is the case with other first-generation regulations, much of the regulation in this arena is reactive, piecemeal, and less than ideal.

7.3 Governing Principles for the Next Generation of Regulation

The next generation of regulations must transition from reactive regulations that seek a rudimentary level of stability in the face of the upheaval of industry norms to proactive regulations that recognize the longer-term goals, expectations, and strategies of all relevant constituencies in sharing economy industries.

Perhaps the first and most basic regulatory transition that is required is a transition from substantive regulatory silos to regulation that directly addresses core principles or values in the sharing economy. This is not to say that the trend toward more robust treatment of platform workers as employees, for example, is wrong or ineffective. But it is to argue that current regulatory systems, and the assumptions on which they have been built, are not the best basis for approaching the next generation of regulation. In making this argument, I take issue with some prominent legal commentators who claim that the sharing economy is not really that new or different as a market phenomenon,Footnote 34 at least to the extent that such claims lead to the conclusion that the same regulatory approaches we have used with other seemingly disruptive technologies will suffice for regulating the sharing economy. Instead, I am more convinced by Pollman’s and Barry’s observation that platform proprietors are very effectively taking advantage of regulatory gaps and conflicts to innovate their business models in new directions to avoid regulations that they disfavor.Footnote 35 This sophisticated (and Legal Realist) understanding of the regulatory landscape has allowed some sharing economy businesses to attenuate traditional legal categories to the near breaking point, as the increasingly frequent queries about the future of work in the “gig economy” reveal.Footnote 36

Thus, policymakers would be better served by regulating on the basis of the core principles that they seek to promote in the next generation of sharing economy businesses. Returning to the example of platform workers, rather than trying to analyze whether Uber drivers or Airbnb hosts are employees or independent contractors according to the laws of any given jurisdiction, it will be more efficacious for policymakers to regulate in recognition of the actual roles such platforms play as a source of work and income. This in turn requires recognition of who exactly participates as workers in various sharing industries.

In this section, I review four core principles that have emerged essentially as consensus principles that ought to govern sharing economy practices. These are principles that scholars across disciplines have argued should govern continued development in the industry. Such scholars have argued, for example, that sharing economy businesses must optimize for more than profit.Footnote 37 They must optimize for values such as equity.Footnote 38 I argue here that these principles also should anchor the next generation of sharing economy regulation. The four principles on which I focus here are by no means a closed list. To the contrary, this list ought to be developed, expanded, and edited as the sharing economy continues to mature.

However, this list does serve several crucial functions for policymaking moving forward. First, it provides a model for policymaking that is a compelling alternative to the piecemeal, reactive, and often ill-fitting regulatory approaches that have thus far dominated the landscape. Second, it serves as a powerful basis for regulation of the sharing economy at this point in time, capturing a phenomenon that has established itself as a ubiquitous market force that significantly disrupted prior market practices and has yet to assume its ultimate (and perhaps more stable) form. Third, it forcefully reminds us that regulation that “leaves to the market” the opportunity to optimize just for profit is in fact regulation. Said another way, the perceived absence of regulation is a form of regulation that tips the balance of legal power and privilege precipitously in favor of platform proprietors. By providing regulatory support for optimizing for values other than profit, policymakers can and must acknowledge the reality that they have already been regulating the sharing economy. Moreover, and crucially, lawmakers can be more proactive in regulating the profit-making and economic behavior of sharing economy businesses in such a way as to enable greater innovation and ultimately competition among businesses in any given sector. In short, lawmakers must take active responsibility for regulating forward.

7.3.1 Principle 1: The Sharing Economy as Infrastructure

Our experience with the pandemic has starkly revealed the extent to which some platforms, including some sharing economy businesses, have begun to serve as essential infrastructure for many individuals, especially those in urban locations. For example, many of us have been utterly dependent in our work lives on platforms such as Zoom and Microsoft Teams, with all the attendant dependencies such as handing over our private lives for data collection by these platforms during the many hours in which we use these platforms for meetings.Footnote 39 Such dependencies extend to other core sharing economy sectors. Many of us have come to rely even more extensively on cloud technology to store both business and personal materials. Many of us have relied on ridesharing services both to get ourselves to workplaces, medical appointments, and grocery stores (during times when subways and busses have operated on much more limited capacity) and to provide additional income. Many of us have used sharing economy platforms to order products and services that are essential to our daily living, thereby also relying on last-mile delivery systems and other attendant services. And the list goes on.

These examples reveal that sharing economy businesses have directly replaced those things that we explicitly label as infrastructure, including modes of communication, transportation, storage, and essential equipment. Equally basically, such businesses have replaced – and displaced – those things that our federal, state, and local governments have built as public works. This basic reality dictates qualitatively different regulation. It is a given that policymakers develop fundamentally different rules for overseeing the operation, management, and maintenance of infrastructure.Footnote 40 Even when such infrastructure is privately owned, policymakers do not – and cannot afford to – leave the owners and managers of such infrastructure to their own devices for maximizing profit and efficiency. The stakeholders of such businesses include more constituencies than just their shareholders. The role of regulation is to ensure that the public has the right to access and use such infrastructure, regardless of whether it is publicly or privately owned.Footnote 41

Perhaps more than anything, this qualitative difference boils down to a recognition that the line between “public” and “private” in these sharing economy sectors is illusory in meaningful respects. Across a range of legal fields, the illusoriness of the public/private distinction has been the subject of more than a decade of robust legal scholarship, and much of this critique is directly applicable to the sharing economy.Footnote 42 Thus, for example, the argument by a platform proprietor that it is a private entity with the right to treat its workers as independent contractors, ought to be of little consequence in this arena. It may be an apt argument that Uber should be forced to internalize the negative externalities it produces by not treating its drivers as employees. But it is an equally realistic argument that Uber’s operations should be regulated in ways that other forms of infrastructure are regulated because it is now providing an essential service. Thus, just as regulations protect subway drivers and electrical service technicians by prioritizing their ability to work safely and for fair wages,Footnote 43 so too must regulations protect sharing economy workers so that they can continue to provide essential services without work interruption. The value of recognizing such platforms as infrastructure is that it forcefully creates more space for a broader range of regulatory interventions.

What regulatory possibilities might flow, then, from the recognition of at least some (perhaps many) sharing economy sectors as infrastructure? Consider the possibilities that such a perspective could have created during the coronavirus crisis. There should have been little question that Uber drivers should have received the same treatment as other essential workers in receiving personal protective equipment and early vaccinations. On the consumer side of the equation, the safety of consumers of such services should also have received more sweeping consideration. Meanwhile, just as we have enhanced rights of privacy from governmental surveillance,Footnote 44 so too should companies like Zoom and Microsoft have been regulated more strictly to protect the privacy of their many users.

Indeed, the pandemic has clarified the real role and value of such businesses, and it has also provided a basis for gaining much-needed regulatory perspective. Out of the many regulatory possibilities, three seem particular efficacious. First, and most basically, public monitoring of such sharing businesses is imperative. Just as the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, the Consumer Product Safety Commission, and a robust list of other federal and state agencies monitor and oversee a very broad range of consumer products and services, so too must sharing economy businesses receive the same careful scrutiny for safety, accessibility, value, and basic fairness.Footnote 45 Indeed, while monitoring is appropriate across all sharing economy sectors, it should be more extensive for those that serve as infrastructure.

Second, those sharing businesses that provide services that directly replace public infrastructure could be regulated as public utilities. Such regulation could take the form of treating some platforms as “essential facilities,” a possibility that Nikolas Guggenberger discusses as efficacious as a means of limiting monopoly power. As Guggenberger notes, “[t]o define the suitable remedies and to open the digital economy for competition, we can learn from the past. In the early twentieth century, the railroads controlled critical infrastructure and excluded competitors from crucial markets.”Footnote 46

Finally, it ought to be a routine option for public agencies at the federal or state level to consider investing in both research and development as well as the operation of government services that compete with and service as a public alternative to private sharing economy businesses that provide critical infrastructure. We have seen exactly this form of investment proposed by local governments such as New York City and the Biden Administration with respect to broadband access.Footnote 47 This form of regulatory investment has also been proposed in the ridesharing context, as is discussed by Behroozi in Chapter 8. It provides an intriguing opportunity for rebalancing and democratizing technological access that could contribute enormously to closing the digital divide and preempting some of the injustices that have proliferated as a result of the extreme emphasis on profit that we have seen in first-generation sharing economy businesses.

7.3.2 Principle 2: Protect Resilience

The pandemic has also helped to clarify the importance of a second principle – resilience – that I argue should define the next generation of regulatory approaches to the sharing economy. Indeed, the value of resilience is closely related to the recognition that some sharing economy sectors have become part of the infrastructure of modern society. However, I have separated resilience out as an independent core principle that must be promoted through regulation across all sharing economy sectors, even those that do not provide goods or services that can be deemed as essential facilities or infrastructure. Such a regulatory prioritization acknowledges that even niche markets, contexts, and consumer clusters can rely heavily on platforms, and concomitantly, that these consumers deserve protection also.

Returning again to the nature of work during the pandemic, Zoom glitches literally could mean hours of missed work, which had to be somehow made up, excused, or explained. When workers that our society labeled “essential” started catching COVID-19 in clusters, policymakers were forced to quickly discern the protections that were required in order to keep them at work. They also had to develop regulations that forced employers to provide such protections on an ongoing basis. Because the essential nature of some sharing economy sectors was invisible to policymakers, however, they did not have the information, nor often the motivation, to protect workers in those sectors who often were just as essential. Meanwhile, on the consumer side of the picture, prices of essential consumer goods fluctuated wildly, at times triggering price gouging laws,Footnote 48 as a result of problems with supply chains and delivery systems.Footnote 49

These lived experiences of crisis-generated disruption have taught new lessons about the importance of regulation that motivates and supports the development of resilient systems. Part of the function of regulation is to ensure that such lessons are not short-lived. The pandemic, and the range of economic and social crises that have surrounded and preceded it, have revealed a great deal about the fragility of many of the systems on which we rely. Our job now is to plan forward in building resilience for the crises we currently face and that we inevitably will face, including climate-related, health, financial, racial, and other disruptions and crises. Resilience can serve as a touchstone that clarifies both the need for regulation and the regulatory choices that ought to be made. In the realm of sharing economy businesses, one commonality across many sectors may be that sharing businesses have the capacity to rapidly and efficiently allocate resources for a very broad range of consumer needs. This makes them enormously attractive and useful in times of crisis.Footnote 50 Without regulation, however, such businesses may have little incentive to ensure that their allocation choices are equitable, accessible for all, and built to last.

Again, a rich array of regulatory options is available to optimize for resilience in the sharing economy. One important consideration is to ensure consistent consumer access by actively monitoring, and at times capping, prices. Uber’s and Lyft’s surge-pricing schemes taught important lessons about the predation that can easily occur when a business both monopolizes a market and is free to set its own prices.Footnote 51 While price caps seem particularly relevant during times of crisis, as evidenced by price gouging laws which typically only apply during states of emergency,Footnote 52 such caps should be in consideration more broadly as a means to ensure accessibility to all. Thus, for example, just as utility companies are constrained from “turning off” a service if individuals are unable to pay,Footnote 53 so too should at least some sharing sectors be subject to broader regulations on pricing. This is not to say that all forms of dynamic pricing are problematic. To the contrary, the reasonable use of such pricing can help to ensure temporally efficient supply during times when demand suddenly spikes. However, regulation has a role to play in establishing the parameters of what is reasonable in this context.

As I have discussed, a second area for regulation is in the realm of worker protections. While all workers deserve fair treatment and wages, the need to develop resilient systems within a range of sharing economy sectors should serve as an independent basis for considering regulations relating to workers and workplace conditions.

Finally, and more broadly, it will be important for policymakers to consider regulating in favor of redundancy in sharing sectors. This broad objective still leaves open many regulatory possibilities. For example, regulators could choose to develop their own publicly operating platform, as described above, or they could choose to regulate in such a manner as to promote competition within a sharing economy sector. Though radically different, both possibilities could avoid the fragility that results from over-dependence on a single provider of an essential platform service.

7.3.3 Principle 3: Create Equity

While the coronavirus pandemic has highlighted the importance of regulating to optimize for resilience, another ongoing crisis has shone a harsh light on the need for regulations across sharing economy sectors to address the imperative of equity. The murder of George Floyd has activated a long-overdue and more sustained reckoning with systemic racism and violence than has occurred in some time. While the almost weekly police killings of Black individuals demonstrate the urgency of such a reckoning in the area of criminal justice practice and regulation, no sector is immune from scrutiny. Indeed, that is one of the most important lessons from the recent dialogue about the nature of structural racism in US society.

Moreover, compelling research has revealed the extent and depth of racism in the sharing economy. The combination of individual decision making, such as the choice of Airbnb hosts not to rent to Black guests, and machine learning, namely the rampant nature of algorithmic bias, has resulted in tremendous inequities. Uber drivers have consistently given lower ratings to Black passengers. Gig workers who rely predominantly on gig work are also predominantly people of color. Platform technologies are configured in such a way as to exhibit algorithmic bias by race and other traits.Footnote 54 Here again, the list is almost endless.

Such inequities are not just racial, but include bias about gender, sexuality, disability, and many other identities and traits.Footnote 55 They also include economic inequalities, which have resulted in predation by platform proprietors – of lower-income consumers and workers.Footnote 56 The need for lower-income workers to access ridesharing services to reach their workplaces during the pandemic serves as a compelling example here. When such services were priced too expensively to be accessible to essential workers, the resulting inequities cried out for regulatory intervention.Footnote 57 Indeed, both the speed and extent of the proliferation of bias across sharing industries has been breathtaking. Especially given the failures of first-generation sharing economy providers to self-regulate to eliminate discrimination, it is imperative for policymakers to intervene.Footnote 58

While the creation and preservation of equity in the sharing economy will require a range of regulatory interventions, the threshold intervention that seems inescapable in this arena is the involvement of government agencies in monitoring the development and operation of sharing platforms. Simply put, it can no longer be a right of sharing economy businesses to hide behind claims of trade secrecy or other intellectual property rights as a way of avoiding scrutiny by public agencies to determine the existence or extent of differential impact by platforms on their consumers and workers.Footnote 59

Relatedly, it will be imperative for policymakers to develop a range of interventions when bias is discovered. These can and should occur at the federal and state level and should be driven by both legislatures and courts. They should include expanded rights of action for consumers to claim racial and other forms of discrimination. But especially when promulgated by legislatures, such regulations should also adopt a broad view of the imperative of equity, moving beyond the definitions of and tests for discrimination and the categories of protected classes traditionally determined by civil rights laws. Instead, lawmakers should consult the extensive literature on the benefits of equitable access to technology to define broad rights of equitable access to sharing economy systems and platforms.Footnote 60

Finally, the troubling extent to which Black, Indigenous, and People of Color (BIPOC) and other historically marginalized individuals are represented among the ranks of sharing economy workers mandates far greater regulatory attention to ensure equity in the sharing economy workplace. Such attention will require regulators to break through some of the traditional legal structures, including labels such as “independent contractor,” and rhetorical slogans such as freedom of contract, that have been used (and attenuated) by platform proprietors to avoid regulation. Just as the pandemic-induced rules allowing for gig workers to file for unemployment recognized the true nature of sharing economy work from the perspective of those workers, so too will more permanent regulations have to recognize the precarity that has resulted from the current imbalance of power between platform proprietors and their workers.

7.3.4 Principle 4: Develop Democracy

The fourth core principle that I wish to discuss here builds on the prior three principles, abstracting a crucial basis for governance of the sharing economy going forward. While the prior three principles provide foundations for regulations that shape rights and remedies for categories of participants in the sharing economy as a means of correcting the imbalance of power and providing stability, this fourth principle addresses the instability and imbalance of power by providing a foundation for governance as a form of regulatory intervention. The imperative to develop democratic institutions for governance within the sharing economy recognizes that platforms today are a powerful means of organizing and controlling social interactions and behaviors. This powerful role dictates ongoing access by the public not only to the goods and services provided but also to the right to determine how such platforms operate.

Currently, the governance of sharing economy platforms is controlled almost exclusively by their proprietors, who set the rules for participation in such platforms. The resulting governance failures are numerous. Rather than enumerating examples, the best demonstration of such failures may be simply to contrast Wikipedia, which is arguably a governance success,Footnote 61 with Uber, which has repeatedly disregarded the voices and participation of consumers, workers, and really anyone (other than its owners) who has a stake in the company’s operations.

Extreme examples such as this have generated a developing consensus that, like home-owners associationsFootnote 62 and bowling societiesFootnote 63 a generation earlier, some platforms are developing into institutions that substitute for public institutions. It is not an exaggeration to describe such platforms as forums in which private forms of government have developed. As with predecessor institutions that have developed in this manner, one of the roles of regulation is to provide scaffolding that promotes their democratic growth and development.

Thus, policymakers should investigate the regulation of home-owners associations and other similar institutions as models for developing democracy in the sharing economy. They should also draw strategies from Wikipedia and other truly “open access” platforms. Indeed, one basic assumption that may well be both an appropriate starting point for such work, as well as a basis for further investigation, is that genuinely peer-to-peer sharing platforms are a home-grown, internally generated form of governance within the sharing economy.Footnote 64 Assuming such investigations bear out the validity of this assumption, then policymakers can and should investigate ways in which to incorporate some of the operational strategies of peer-to-peer platforms more broadly into sharing economy sectors, particularly those that serve as crucial infrastructure today.

7.4 Conclusion

While regulation of the sharing economy has thus far been a reactive process, exhibiting very little attention to priorities such as consistency and the development of core regulatory principles, it need not be going forward. We now have a much greater level of knowledge about the sharing economy as well as interdisciplinary tools for regulating it. Moving forward, it is incumbent upon policymakers to use the regulatory tools available to them in support of the optimization of a more just sharing economy.

Footnotes

2 A Sociotechnical Ecosystem Perspective of Sharing Economy Platforms

1 From this standpoint, we can consider the product Q&A feature of Amazon where previous buyers respond to questions by a prospective buyer as a form of sharing service.

3 The Sharing Economy and Environmental Sustainability

4 Sharing Economy and Privacy

5 Reputation, Feedback, and Trust in Online Platforms

This chapter is adapted from an article titled “Reputation and Feedback Systems in Online Platform Markets,” which appeared in the Annual Review of Economics in 2016 and is being published with permission.

1 I understand that not all readers may be familiar with the tools of game theory and hence, I tried to keep this example as simple as possible and minimize the use of jargon.

2 This scenario can be thought of as follows: If the buyer is offered to choose freely between two options, one is getting the good, and the other is getting $25, then this buyer is indifferent between the options – they are equally good. Hence, if the buyer is offered to pay $15 for the good, it is as if the buyer is getting $10 worth of net value.

3 You may wonder where p comes from. In game theory we assume that people have correct beliefs about the environment, possibly from their experience or possibly from trusted sources of information.

4 This is just like a business that can borrow today against future profits, but must pay some interest rate, making the amount it must pay back higher (it can borrow $δ today and repay $1 next month).

5 In fact, in the jargon of game theory, the unique sequential equilibrium (and the unique perfect Bayesian equilibrium) of this game with these assumptions has the opportunistic seller behaving honestly in the first period. For more on these concepts and for a more formal treatment of the material see Tadelis Reference Tadelis2012 (Part V).

6 This is an example of a game in the spirit of the seminal work by Kreps et al. (Reference Kreps, Milgrom, Roberts and Wilson1982). For some values of p≥0.6 the equilibrium involves the seller using “mixed strategies” in the first stage (i.e., the seller randomizes between honoring and abusing trust), as well as mixed strategies for the buyer in the second stage (i.e., the buyer randomizes between trusting and not trusting). This is beyond what I wish to highlight here, as the key insight is that a potential future creates incentives to behave honestly and not abuse trust. See chapter 17 in Tadelis (Reference Tadelis2012).

7 See Li et al. (Reference Li, Steven and Xiaolan2020) for more on Taobao’s reputation system.

8 This high fraction of feedback may be a surprise to many mainstream economists, but not to Pierre Omidyar, eBay’s founder. On his personal profile page, it states that “Pierre created eBay in 1995 on the premise that people are basically good” (www.omidyar.com/people/pierre-omidyar).

9 Notice the “Top Rated Plus” badge at the upper right corner of Figure 5.2. This designation is bestowed on sellers that meet a series of criteria believed by eBay to be an indication of a high quality seller. See Hui et al. (Reference Hui, Saeedi, Sundaresan and Shen2014) for a lengthy discussion of this feature.

10 While the feedback score is calculated using all past transactions, the percent positive only uses the last twelve months of a seller’s transactions.

11 Buyer abuse still persisted at a very low level: Some buyers would threaten to leave sellers negative feedback for no reason in order to get some partial refund, but the prevalence of this behavior was in the low single-digit percentages during the time I was at eBay.

12 See Resnick et al. (Reference Resnick, Zeckhauser, Kuwabara and Friedman2000) for a more detailed discussion of these studies.

13 This relates to the problem of distinguishing causation from correlation, as described in detail in Angrist and Pischke (2008). A randomized controlled experiment controls for all but one variable of interest, and creates two groups where only the variable of interest differs and all else remains the same. This allows the researcher to measure the causal effects of changes in the variable of interest without the concern that other important variables may also differ across the two groups. Exogenous variation refers to cases where there was no carefully designed experiment, but where for other reasons the researcher can be confident that the changes in the variable of interest are not correlated with other important variables that determine outcomes.

14 Li (Reference Li2010) proposed a mechanism designed to solve the problem of missing reports and positive bias. The mechanism provides the sellers with an option for giving rebates to rating buyers. Li and Xiao (2014) extended the model and conducted a laboratory experiment to test the main hypotheses. The lab results suggest that higher reporting costs decrease buyers’ willingness to review sellers, leading to a decrease in buyers’ trust and sellers’ trustworthiness, but these results are not statistically significant. Additionally, since the research design lacks a fear of retaliation, reports are negatively biased.

15 Not all attempts to purchase a reputation may be fraudulent. Signaling theory suggests that high-quality sellers may pay for honest feedback knowing that the feedback they receive will bode well for them. See Li et al. (Reference Li, Steven and Xiaolan2020) for a study of such behavior in Taobao’s marketplace.

6 Labor and the Platform Economy

1 For the sake of simplicity, this chapter uses the terms “platform” and “sharing” economy interchangeably, referring to firms operating in two-sided markets, using apps or websites to govern transactions between peers, that is, buyers and sellers. We make no assumptions that “sharing” is a valid descriptor of platform goals (Ravenelle Reference Ravenelle2017; Schor and Attwood-Charles Reference Schor and Attwood-Charles2017).

7 Contemplating the Next Generation of Sharing Economy Regulation

I am grateful to Hayley Reifeiss and Tess McMahon for excellent research support.

1 Portions of this section were originally published in 90 Tulane Law Review, 241 (2015).

2 US Safety Report 2017–2018, 50, 57, 58 (Uber Technologies, Inc., 2019); Jennifer Schaller, Lyft Sexual Assault Claims Consolidated for Pre-Trial Proceedings, National Law Review, Feb. 10, 2020, www.natlawreview.com/article/lyft-sexual-assault-claims-consolidated-pre-trial-proceedings; Sara Ashley O’Brien et al., CNN investigation: 103 Uber Drivers Accused of Sexual Assault or Abuse, CNN Wire, April 30, 2018, https://money.cnn.com/2018/04/30/technology/uber-driver-sexual-assault/index.html.

3 Biz Carson, Airbnb is Fixing its Safety Problems After California Shooting Leaves 5 Dead, Forbes.com, Nov. 6, 2019, www.forbes.com/sites/bizcarson/2019/11/06/airbnb-to-verify-all-listings-after-orinda-shooting/?sh=7156096ee49a; Olivia Carville, Airbnb Is Spending Millions of Dollars to Make Nightmares Go Away, Bloomberg Business Week, June 15, 2021, www.bloomberg.com/news/features/2021-06-15/airbnb-spends-millions-making-nightmares-at-live-anywhere-rentals-go-away.

4 Knowledge at Wharton, Can Uber Overcome its Regulatory Obstacles?, Fair Observer, Dec. 3, 2019, https://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article/can-uber-overcome-regulatory-obstacles; Suhauna Hussain, Uber Faces $59-Million Fine, License Threat, Los Angeles Times, Dec. 16, 2020, https://enewspaper.latimes.com/infinity/article_share.aspx?guid=750229ad-fbc6-41a0-b9ca-22837db84ca8.

5 Meera Joshi et. al., E-Hail Regulation in Global Cities (NYU Rudin Center for Transportation, 2019); Paul Nussbaum, PUC Approves UberX for State, Not Philadelphia, Philadelphia Inquirer (Business), Nov. 14, 2014, at A15; Andy Vuong, Likely Ride-Sharing Nod would be a First, Denver Post, Apr. 30, 2014, at A10; Public Service Commission of South Carolina Commission Directive, No. 2014-372-T, http://dms.psc.sc.gov/pdf/orders/5A23B2F8-155D-141F-23C07EAA18BA1E64.pdf. (ordering Uber to cease and desist operations in South Carolina until a regulatory determination has been made); Katherine Driessen, Ride-Share Operators Gain Access to Houston Airports; City Becomes Third in U.S. to Adopt Rules for App-Based Services, Houston Chronicle, Nov. 13, 2014, at A1.

6 Tim Logan, Boston’s Tough Rules Governing Airbnb Rentals are Finally in Full Effect, Boston Globe, Nov. 28, 2019, www.bostonglobe.com/business/2019/11/28/boston-tough-rules-governing-airbnb-rentals-are-finally-full-effect/qGyipfGarsWFPfcMmnrvyM/story.html; Sam Schechner and Matthias Verbergt, Paris Confronts Airbnb’s Rapid Growth, Wall Street Journal, June 25, 2015, www.wsj.com/articles/airbnb-still-has-stoops-to-conquer-paris-takes-to-airbnb-like-a-croissant-1434999730?tesla=y; David Streitfeld, Airbnb Listings Mostly Illegal, New York State Contends, New York Times, Oct. 16, 2014, at A1; John Lichfield, Beware Airbnb If You’re A Tenant Looking For A Quick Euro, Independent (World), May 23, 2014, at p. 32.

7 These arguments have regularly arisen in the context of disputes with workers over employment status. See, for example, Noam Scheiber, Uber and Lyft Drivers Win Ruling on Unemployment Benefits, New York Times, July 28, 2020, www.nytimes.com/2020/07/28/business/economy/lyft-uber-drivers-unemployment.html; Tyler Sonnemaker, Court Rules Uber and Lyft Must Face Worker-Misclassification Lawsuit from Massachusetts’ Attorney General, Business Insider, Mar 25, 2021, www.businessinsider.com/uber-lyft-massachusetts-attorney-general-misclassification-lawsuit-proceed-court-2021-3.

8 Lori Aratani, A ‘Balancing Act’ for Ride-Sharing Service, Washington Post, May 12, 2014 at B01 (Uber and Lyft argue “that they are not transportation companies but rather go-betweens that link drivers who have vehicles with customers who need a ride.”); Brief for Defendants-Appellees, Anoush Cab, Inc. v. Uber Technologies, Inc., No. 19-2001 (1st Cir. Aug. 25, 2020).

9 See, for example, Michael Liedtke, “Sharing Safety Program”: Uber, Lyft Team Up on Database to Expose Abusive Drivers, USA Today, Mar. 11, 2021, www.usatoday.com/story/travel/news/2021/03/11/uber-lyft-team-up-database-expose-abusive-drivers/4654902001/.

10 Uber Background Checks, Uber, http://blog.uber.com/driverscreening (visited Aug. 11, 2014).

11 Leidtke, “Sharing Safety Program”; US Safety Report 2017–2018, 50, 57, 58 (Uber Technologies, Inc., 2019).

12 Ron Lieber, A Liability Risk for Airbnb Hosts, New York Times, Dec. 5, 2014, www.nytimes.com/2014/12/06/your-money/airbnb-offers-homeowner-liability-coverage-but-hosts-still-have-risks.html.

13 Carson, Airbnb is Fixing its Safety Problems; David Yaffe-Bellany, Airbnb to Verify All Listings, C.E.O. Chesky Says, New York Times, Nov. 6, 2019.

14 See Chapter 8 (Behroozi) and Chapter 9 (Katsoupolos et al.).

15 See Chapter 10 (O’Brien et al.). See also Josh Bivens, The Economic Costs and Benefits of Airbnb, The Economic Policy Institute, 2019.

16 Joshua D. Wright, The Antitrust/Consumer Protection Paradox: Two Policies at War With Each Other, 121 Yale Law Journal, 2216 (2012).

17 Nancy Leong and Aaron Belzer, The New Public Accommodations: Race Discrimination in the Platform Economy, 105 Georgetown Law Journal, 1271 (2017).

18 Donna Lu, Uber and Lyft Pricing Algorithms Charge More in Non-White Areas, New Scientist, June 18, 2020.

19 Details on Safety, Uber News, http://newsroom.uber.com/2015/07/details-on-safety (accessed April 22, 2021); Josh Eidelson, Uber Sued for Using ‘Biased’ Rider Ratings to Fire Drivers, Bloomberg, Oct. 26, 2020, www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-10-26/uber-sued-for-using-biased-customer-ratings-to-fire-drivers.

20 Airbnb (n.d.), How Do Reviews Work?, www.airbnb.com/help/article/13 (accessed April 17, 2021); Emily Badger, Racial Bias in Everything: Airbnb Edition, Washington Post, Dec. 12, 2015.

21 See Leong and Belzer, The New Public Accommodations; Anne-Marie Hakstian et. al., The More Things Change, the More They Stay the Same: Online Platforms and Consumer Equality, 48 Pepperdine Law Review, 59 (2021); Allyson E. Gold, Redliking: When Redlining Goes Online, 62 William. & Mary Law Review, 1841 (2021); Sonia K. Katyal, Private Accountability in the Age of Artificial Intelligence, 66 UCLA Law Review, 54, 56 (2019); Anupam Chander, The Racist Algorithm?, 115 Michigan Law Review, 1023 (2017); Frank Pasquale, The Black Box Society: The Secret Algorithms that Control Money and Information, Harvard University Press, 2015.

22 Leong & Belzer, The New Public Accommodations; Rashmi Dyal-Chand, Autocorrecting For Whiteness, 101 Boston University Law Review, 191 (2021).

23 Healey v. Uber Techs., Inc., 2021 Mass. Super. LEXIS 28, 2021 WL 1222199; Kate Conger and Noam Scheiber, California’s Contractor Law Stirs Confusion Beyond the Gig Economy, New York Times, Sept. 11, 2019, www.nytimes.com/2019/09/11/business/economy/uber-california-bill.html?utm_source=Triggermail&utm_medium=email&utm_campaign=Post%20Blast%20bii-transportation-and-logistics:%20Uber%20faces%20more%20regulatory%20woes%20%7C%20Trucking%20telematics%20-looks%20poised%20for%20takeoff%20%7C%20Amazon%20brings%20offline%20Alexa%20functionalities%20to%20the%20car&utm_term=BII%20List%20T%26L%20ALL; Michael B. Farrell, Suit Claims Uber Exploits Drivers, Boston Globe, June 27, 2014, at B7; Uber Technologies, Inv. v. Berwick, Case No. 11-46739 (CA Labor Commissioner, June 3, 2015); O’Connor v. Uber Techs., Inc., No. C-13-3826 EMC, 2013 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 171813 (N.D. Cal. Dec. 5, 2013).

24 In Massachusetts, these protections are buttressed by a very strict statute enacted to classify many of the people working as “independent contractors” instead as employees. See M.G.L. c. 149, s. 148B.

25 Uber Drivers: Don’t Sign Away Your Rights, http://uberlawsuit.com/ (visited Jan. 23, 2015); Lauren Weber and Rachel Emma Silverman, “We Are Not Robots” – Is Technology Liberating or Squeezing The New Class of Freelance Labor?, Wall Street Journal, Jan. 28, 2015, at B1 (describing a number of lawsuits filed by workers in the sharing economy to claim more benefits).

26 See Rashmi Dyal-Chand, Regulating Sharing: The Sharing Economy as an Alternative Capitalist System, 90 Tulane Law Review,241 (2015).

27 Daria Roithmayr, Racism is at the Heart of the Platform Economy, Law & Political Economy Project, https://lpeproject.org/blog/racial-capitalism-redux-how-race-segments-the-new-labor-markets/ (accessed April 17, 2021).

28 Ill. Transp. Trade Assn v. City of Chi., 839 F.3d 594, 2016 U.S. App. LEXIS 18285; Zeninjor Enwemeka, Boston Taxi Group Files Federal Lawsuit Over State’s New Ride-Hailing Law, WBUR, Sept. 23, 2016, www.wbur.org/bostonomix/2016/09/23/boston-taxi-group-sues-massachusetts; Lori Aratani, Taxis Paralyze Downtown Traffic to Protest Ride Sharing Services, Washington Post (Metro), June 26, 2014, at B5; Boom and Backlash; The Sharing Economy, Economist, Apr. 26, 2014, at 61.

29 Parveer S. Ghuman, Analysis of Competition Cases Against Uber Across the Globe, CUTS International, 2017; Aratani, Taxis Paralyze Downtown Traffic.

30 Jon Hilkevitch, Uberx Caught Illegally Sharing; Company Directed Drivers to Airports, Violating Ordinance, Chicago Tribune, May 7, 2014, at C1; Kip Hill, Lyft, Uber Drivers Will Have to Pay New Fees, Follow New Rules under Spokane City Council Proposal, Spokesman-Review, Dec. 10, 2018, www.spokesman.com/stories/2018/dec/10/lyft-uber-drivers-will-have-to-pay-new-fees-follow/; H.R. 1093 Relating To Transportation Network Companies, 30th Leg., 2019 (Hi. 2019).

31 Jordan M. Barry and Paul L. Caron, Tax Regulation, Transportation Innovation, and the Sharing Economy, 82 University of Chicago Law Review, Dialogue 69, 82–83 (2015).

32 Shu-Yi Oei and Diane M. Ring, Can Sharing be Taxed?, 93 Washington University Law Review, 989, 994 (2016).

34 Orly Lobel, The Gig Economy and the Future of Employment and Labor Law, 51 University of San Francisco Law Review, 51, 56 (2017) (asserting that the sharing economy is an expansion on previously existing contingent workforces); Valerio De Stefano, The Rise of the “Just-in-Time Workforce”: On-Demand Work, Crowdwork, and Labor Protection in the “Gig-Economy,” 37 Comparative Labor Law & Policy Journal, 471, 480–481 (2016) (relating modern gig-workers to a broader trend of casualization and demutualization in the workforce that predated the modern platform-based sharing economy); Derek Miller, The Sharing Economy and How it is Changing Industries, The Balance Small Business (Jun. 25, 2019), www.thebalancesmb.com/the-sharing-economy-and-how-it-changes-industries-4172234#:~:text=The%20sharing%20economy%20is%20an%20economic%20principle%20that,share%20value%20from%20an%20under-utilized%20skill%20or%20asset.

35 Elizabeth Pollman and Jordan M. Barry, Regulatory Entrepreneurship, 90 Southern California Law Review, 383, 392, 398–399 (2017).

36 Robert Reich, Why the Sharing Economy is Harming Workers – And What Must be Done, RobertReich.Org, https://robertreich.org/search/sharing+economy, Nov. 27, 2015; Juliet Schor, Debating the Sharing Economy, Great Transition Initiative, Oct. 2014; Charlotte S. Alexander and Elizabeth Tippet, The Hacking of Employment Law, 82 Missouri Law Review, 973, 1000–1001 (2017).

37 Alexiomar D. Rodríguez-López, Trust Me, I Share Your Values, 10 University of Puerto Rico Business Law Journal, 44, 50–51 (2019) (arguing that the sharing economy could address economic problems in Puerto Rico, but only if implemented with a pool of shared values between the business and the clients in mind). Nestor M. Davidson and John J. Infranca, The Sharing Economy as an Urban Phenomenon, 34 Yale Law & Policy Review, 215, 268–269 (2016).

38 Orly Lobel, The Law of the Platform, 101 Minnesota Law Review, 87, 163 (2016) (stating that equity issues should be addressed as platform companies continue to expand). See also Vanessa Katz, Regulating the Sharing Economy, 30 Berkeley Technology Law Journal, 1067– 1112 (2015); Abbey Stemler, The Myth of the Sharing Economy and Its Implications for Regulating Innovation, 67 Emory Law Journal, 197, 223n (2017).

39 See, for example., Jane Wakefield, Zoom Boss Apologises for Security Issues and Promises Fixes, BBC News, April 2, 2020, www.bbc.com/news/technology-52133349 (reporting on Zoom’s response to widely criticized security breaches at the beginning of the coronavirus pandemic); Kate O’Flaherty, Zoom’s Security Nightmare Just Got Worse: But Here’s the Reality, Forbes, June 5, 2020, www.forbes.com/sites/kateoflahertyuk/2020/06/05/zooms-security-nightmare-just-got-worse-but-heres-the-reality/?sh=34b456592131 (reporting on the anger users expressed upon learning that end-to-end encryption was for paid users only). See also Celine Castronuovo, EU Privacy Regulator Proposes $425M Fine Against Amazon, The Hill, June 10, 2021 https://thehill.com/policy/technology/557863-eu-privacy-regulator-proposes-425m-fine-against-amazon (reporting on charges against Amazon for alleged privacy data invasions that violate EU law); Barbara Ortutay, Record Facebook Fine Won’t End Scrutiny of the Company, AP News, June 24, 2019, https://apnews.com/article/technology-business-facebook-privacy-scandal--ap-top-news-ca-state-wire-47f5f7fd9e0941a880b929af081a37a0; Jordan Valinsky, 4 Companies Affected by Security Breaches in June, CNN Business, June 26, 2021, www.cnn.com/2021/06/26/tech/cyberattacks-security-breaches-june/index.html (reporting on data privacy breaches from platforms including Electronic Arts and Peloton).

40 Ganesh Sitaraman, Morgan Ricks, and Christopher Serkin, Regulation and the Geography of Inequality, 70 Duke Law Journal, 1763, 1830–1832 (2021) (noting that transportation and communications resources are foundational to economic growth and development, and analogizing high speed internet to the modern postal service as necessary to bring infrastructural equity to marginalized communities); Sofia Ranchordás, Innovation Experimentalism in the Age of the Sharing Economy, 19 Lewis & Clark Law Review, 871, 889 (2015) (relating the regulation of the modern gig-economy to earlier efforts to regulate infrastructure-based activities such as telecommunications and energy). See also, Lobel, The Law of the Platform, at 163 (raising questions of equity in whether platform companies serve poor and marginalized communities and arguing that platform companies should include such considerations as they expand); Stemler, The Myth of the Sharing Economy, at 239 (“For performance standards to be effective, they must be monitored”).

41 For an insightful treatment of this subject, see Nik Guggenberger, The Essential Facilities Doctrine in the Digital Economy: Dispelling Persistent Myths, Yale Journal of Law & Technology, 2021. See also, Frank Pasquale, Dominant Search Engines: An Essential Cultural & Political Facility, in The Next Digital Decade, 401–418 (Berin Szoka and Adam Markus, eds., 2010, Washington, DC: Tech Freedom).

42 See, for example, Brian Jason Fleming, Regulation of Political Signs in Private Homeowner Associations: A New Approach, 59 Vanderbilt Law Review, 571, 573–574 (2006) (noting that home-owner associations take up an ambiguous legal space as private governing bodies whose jurisdiction overlaps with federal and state governing bodies). Gillian E. Metzger, Privatization as Delegation, 103 Columbia Law Review, 1367, 1371–1373 (2003) (discussing the blurred line between the public and private sectors in constitutional law); Michael P. Vandenbergh, Private Environmental Governance, 99 Cornell Law Review, 129, 171–172 (2013) (discussing the emergence of private–public environmental governance); Matthew A. Shapiro, Delegating Procedure, 118 Columbia Law Review, 983, 998 (2018) (arguing that three significant aspects of civil litigation have been delegated by the federal government to private parties); Benjamin Zhu, A Traditional Tort for a Modern Threat: Applying Intrusion Upon Seclusion to Dataveillance Observations, 89 New York University Law Review, 2381, 2389 (2014) (claiming the digitization of public documents has given access and intrusive power to private data collection agencies); Orly Lobel, The Renew Deal: The Fall of Regulation and the Rise of Governance in Contemporary Legal Thought, 89 Minnesota Law Review, 342, 345 (2004) (discussing the emerging governance model of transferring governing responsibilities to states, localities, private businesses and nonprofit organizations); Robert C. Hockett and Saule T. Omarova, Public Actors in Private Markets: Toward a Developmental Finance State, 93 Washington University Law Review, 103, 122 (2015) (arguing public and private sectors are “inseparable and deeply interconnected parts of the nation’s economic organism”). See also, Tabrez Y. Ebrahim, National Cybersecurity Innovation, 123 West Virginia Law Review, 483, 494–495 (2020) (noting that the private and public sectors are interconnected and co-mingled, thus requiring similar treatment in cybersecurity regulation).

43 Ross Barkan, New York’s Transit Workers Keep Getting Sick, The Nation, April 9, 2020, www.thenation.com/article/politics/mta-transit-driver-covid/ (discussing the high rate of COVID-19 infection among public transit workers in New York and efforts to protect essential workers in public transit); Rachel Burgaris, Why Electrical Safety Should be a Priority in Post-COVID Planning, Occupational Health & Safety, June 1, 2020, https://ohsonline.com/articles/2020/06/01/why-electrical-safety-should-be-a-priority-in-postcovid-planning.aspx (discussing the safety concerns and protections unique to electrical safety practices, including COVID-19 precautions); Heidi Groover, Masks, Driver Shields, Artificial Intelligence: How Do We Make Public Transit in the Puget Sound Area Safe Amid COVID-19, Seattle Times, Aug. 23, 2020, www.seattletimes.com/seattle-news/transportation/masks-driver-shields-artificial-intelligence-how-do-we-make-public-transit-in-the-puget-sound-amid-covid-19/ (reporting on high death rates of transit workers and on the rules in place to protect them from COVID-19); What Have Platforms Done to Protect Workers During the Coronavirus (COVID 19) Crisis?, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Sept. 21, 2020, www.oecd.org/coronavirus/policy-responses/what-have-platforms-done-to-protect-workers-during-the-coronavirus-covid-19-crisis-9d1c7aa2/ (reporting on the unique risks to platform workers during the pandemic and protections governments have taken to protect workers from the financial and health risks of the virus).

44 Deborah Pearlstein, Before Privacy, Power: The Structural Constitution and the Challenge of Mass Surveillance, 9 Journal of National Security Law & Policy, 159, 166–168 (2017) (outlining the history of bulk surveillance and the regulations that limited the ability of the National Security Agency to monitor certain data from US citizens); leuan Jolly, Data Protection in the United States: Overview, Practical Law,(law stated as of June 8, 2020), https://1.next.westlaw.com/Document/I02064fbd1cb611e38578f7ccc38dcbee/View/FullText.html?contextData=%28sc.Default%29&transitionType=Default (a question and answer guide to privacy regulation in the United States).

45 See Dodd-Frank Act 12 U.S.C.A. § 5491 (2010) (establishing Consumer Financial Protection Bureau); Consumer Product Safety Act 15 U.S.C.A. § 1261 (1972) (current version at 15 U.S.C.A. § 1261 [2008]) (establishing the Consumer Product Safety Commission).

46 Nik Guggenberger, Essential Platform Monopolies: Open Up, Then Undo, Promarket, Dec. 7, 2020, https://promarket.org/2020/12/07/essential-facilities-regulation-platform-monopolies-google-apple-facebook/.

47 Andrew Duehren, Kristina Peterson, and Sabrina Siddiqui, Biden, Senators Agree to Roughly $1 Trillion Infrastructure Plan, Wall Street Journal, June 24, 2021, www.wsj.com/articles/biden-senators-agree-to-roughly-1-trillion-infrastructure-plan-11624553972?mod=searchresults_pos3&page=1(noting that increased broadband access is a priority of legislators under the Biden administration); Stacie Sherman, Cuomo Signs New York Bill Requiring Low-Cost Broadband Access, Bloomberg, April 16, 2021, www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2021-04-16/n-y-to-require-all-internet-providers-offer-low-cost-broadband (discussing new legislation in New York that mandates that Internet providers ensure access to high-speed internet services at an affordable rate for all New York families).

48 See COVID-19 Price Gouging Prevention Act, H.R. 6472, 116th Cong. (2d Sess. 2020) (a bill proposed in response to price gouging in the COVID-19 pandemic); see also Ky. Rev. Stat. Ann. § 367.374 (West 2021); 73 Pa. Stat. Ann. § 232.2 (West 2007); N.Y. Gen. Bus. Law § 396-r (McKinney 2020) (examples of statutes designed to protect against price gouging; Kentucky’s and New York’s laws appeared after the COVID-19 pandemic).

49 Michael Levenson, Price Gouging Complaints Surge Amid Coronavirus Pandemic, New York Times, Mar. 27, 2020, www.nytimes.com/2020/03/27/us/coronavirus-price-gouging-hand-sanitizer-masks-wipes.html; Danielle Wiener-Bronner, Everything at the Grocery Store is Getting More Expensive, CNN Business, Aug. 5, 2020, www.cnn.com/2020/08/05/business/grocery-prices-rising/index.html (reporting on the disrupted supply chains due to the pandemic); Lisa Baertlein, COVID-19 Delivery Surge Strains FedEx Service, Opening Doors for UPS, Reuters, June 30, 2020.

50 Kentaro Toyama, The Sharing Economy Will Survive the Pandemic. Is That a Good Thing?, World Politics Review, July 7, 2020, www.worldpoliticsreview.com/articles/28893/what-the-coronavirus-pandemic-means-for-the-sharing-economy-business-model; Josh Whitney, Rebuild ‘Sharing Economy’ Post-Virus to Prepare for Climate Change, Bloomberg Law, May 1, 2020, https://news.bloombergtax.com/coronavirus/insight-rebuild-sharing-economy-post-virus-to-prepare-for-climate-change (arguing that companies such as Uber’s and Airbnb’s services to healthcare workers in the early stages of the pandemic are examples of how the sharing economy can nimbly respond to future crises such as climate change).

51 Fran Spielman, Alderman Accuses Uber, Lyft of ‘Predatory Fares,’ Wants Price Cap Imposed, Chicago Sun-Times, May 24, 2021, https://chicago.suntimes.com/city-hall/2021/5/24/22451667/uber-lyft-ride-share-hailing-surge-pricing-cap-city-council-ordinance-alderman-reilly-taxi-cabs#:~:text=They%20would%20be%20free%20to%20use%20%E2%80%9Csurge%20pricing%E2%80%9D,and%20other%20ride-hailing%20companies%20would%20limit%20surge%20pricing; Michael Sainato, Uber and Lyft Fares Surge as Pandemic Recedes – but Drivers Don’t Get ‘Piece of Pie,’ The Guardian, June 21, 2021, www.theguardian.com/technology/2021/jun/21/uber-lyft-fares-surge-drivers-dont-get-piece-of-pie (reporting on the reemergence of surge pricing following the pandemic, but noting that drivers are not receiving the financial benefit of surge pricing and neither customers nor drivers have transparency about how surge prices are allocated).

52 See, for example, Price Gouging Prohibited, 73 PA. Stat. Ann. § 232.4 (prohibiting price gouging in Pennsylvania during states of emergencies); Price Protections During the COVID-19 Recovery Period, Del. Code Ann. tit. 6, § 2528 (2020) (prohibiting price gouging during the state of emergency precipitated by COVID-19). See also, 8NewsNow Staff, Surge Pricing Cap on Uber Stems from 2015 Nevada Law, 8News Now, Apr. 14, 2021, www.8newsnow.com/news/local-news/surge-pricing-cap-on-uber-stems-from-2015-nevada-law/ (reporting that Uber blamed Nevada’s declaration of emergency for preventing the company from charging surge prices).

53 See, for example, Prohibition on Discontinuance or Disconnection of Utility Service During the Winter Heating Season; Minimum Payments; Payment Plans; Exceptions, N.M. Stat. Ann. § 27-6-18.1 (protecting low-income New Mexican citizens from having essential utilities turned off during inclement weather and ensuring access to government energy assistance programs); Limitations on Termination of Utility Service, Wash. Rev. Code § 54.16.285 (prohibiting Washington utility companies from terminating heating services during the winter months).

54 See, for example, Benjamin G. Edelman, Michael Luca, and Daniel Svirsky, Racial Discrimination in the Sharing Economy: Evidence from a Field Experiment, 9 American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1 (2017), https://dash.harvard.edu/bitstream/handle/1/33045458/edelman,luca,svirsky_racial-discrimination-in-the-sharing-economy.pdf?sequence=1. See also Stemler, The Myth of the Sharing Economy, 222–223.

55 See, for example, Naomi Cahn, June Carbone, and Nancy Levit, Discrimination by Design?, 51 Arizona State Law Journal, 1 (2019) (discussing how the platform economy reflects and exacerbates gender disparities in the workforce by relegating women to low-paying gig jobs such as clutter organization rather than high-paying jobs such as moving furniture).

56 Virginia Eubanks, Automating Inequality: How High-Tech Tools Profile Police and Punish the Poor, Macmillan, 2017, 111–115 (defining modern algorithms that monitor poor and minority communities as the “digital poorhouse” and describing how as a result of these facially neutral algorithms, marginalized groups are subjected to practices such as predatory lending and reverse redlining).

57 See Community Rides: UTA Essential Workers, Utah Transit Authority News, Aug. 18, 2020, https://rideuta.com/news/2020/08/Community-Rides-UTA-Essential-Workers (discussing how essential workers continued to use Utah’s public transportation services throughout the pandemic); Matt McFarland, Traffic Deaths Jump for Black Americans Who Couldn’t Afford to Stay Home During Covid, CNN, June 21, 2021, https://edition.cnn.com/2021/06/20/economy/2020-traffic-deaths-black-americans/index.html (discussing how nonwhite pedestrians have much higher fatality rates than white counterparts, and reporting on the sharp rise of pedestrian deaths during the pandemic, especially in minority and low-income communities); Christine Roher and Randy Mac, Rideshare Prices Soar: Here’s What’s Going On, NBC Los Angeles, May 19, 2021, www.nbclosangeles.com/investigations/rideshare-prices-increase-uber-lyft-pricing/2598627/.

58 See Rashmi Dyal-Chand, Autocorrecting for Whiteness, 101 Boston University Law Review, 191, 250–251 (2021).

59 Footnote Ibid., 253–254. See also Pauline T. Kim, Data-Driven Discrimination at Work, 58 William. & Mary Law Review, 857, 921 (2017) (explaining how algorithm creators often escape liability for bias by claiming their algorithms are proprietary information).

60 Ifeoma Ajunwa, The Paradox of Automation as Anti-Bias Intervention, 41 Cardozo Law Review, 1671, 1733–1735 (2020); Stephanie Bornstein, Antidiscriminatory Algorithms, 70 Alabama Law Review, 519, 534 (2018); Kim, Data-Driven Discrimination at Work, 919–921. See also Matthew Adam Bruckner, The Promise and Perils of Algorithmic Lenders’ Use of Big Data, 93 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 3, 18-19, 23, 26 (2018); Ifeoma Ajunwa, Algorithms at Work: Productivity Monitoring Applications and Wearable Technology as the New Data-Centric Research Agenda for Employment and Labor Law, 63 St. Louis University Law Journal, 21, 44–45, 50–51 (2018).

61 Yochai Benkler, Coase’s Penguin, or, Linux and the Nature of the Firm, 112 Yale Law Journal, 369 (2002).

62 Paula A. Franzese and Steven Siegal, The Twin Rivers Case: Of Homeowners Associations, Free Speech Rights, and Privatized Mini-Governments, 5 Rutgers Journal of Law & Public Policy, 729, 752–753, 767 (2008) (discussing the rise of home-owners associations as governing bodies).

63 Robert D. Putnam, Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community, Simon & Schuster, 2000 (discusses the rise and fall of social capital in the United States, explaining that once-common civic participation in clubs and other social activities complemented state and federal governance).

64 Daniel H. Kahn, Social Intermediaries: Creating a More Responsible Web Through Portable Identity, Cross-Web Reputation, and Code-Backed Norms, 11 Columbia Science & Technology Law Review, 176, 199-200 (2010) (discussing Wikipedia’s success in creating a code-of-conduct-based governance system); Molly Cohen and Arun Sundararajan, Self-Regulation and Innovation in the Peer-to-Peer Sharing Economy, 82 University of Chicago Law Review: Dialogue, 116, 129 (2015) (arguing peer-to-peer platforms have tremendous grassroots potential, and that the platforms themselves should be included in developing needed regulatory solutions to governance issues in the sharing economy); Kasey C. Tuttle, Embracing the Sharing Economy: The Mutual Benefits of Working Together to Regulate Short-Term Rentals, 79 University of Pittsburgh Law Review, 803 (2018) (arguing local governments should work together with peer-to-peer property sharing platforms, such as Airbnb, and home owners themselves to develop regulations to govern property sharing); Bryant Cannon and Hanna Chung, A Framework for Designing Co-Regulation Models Well-Adapted to Technology-Facilitated Sharing Economies, 31 Santa Clara High Technology Law Journal, 23, 55, 91 (2015) (using the example of California’s Occupational Health and Safety Administration’s collaboration with management and existing labor unions to develop a co-regulation strategy that could be applied to sharing economy regulation models).

References

References

Acquier, Aurélien, Daudigeos, Thibault, and Pinkse, Jonatan. 2017. “Promises and Paradoxes of the Sharing Economy: An Organizing Framework.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 125 (December): 110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.07.006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adner, Ron and Kapoor, Rahul. 2010. “Value Creation in Innovation Ecosystems: How the Structure of Technological Interdependence Affects Firm Performance in New Technology Generations.” Strategic Management Journal 31 (3): 306333.Google Scholar
Airbnb. n.d. “Investing in Our Partnerships with Local Communities – Resource Center.” Accessed June 11, 2021. www.airbnb.com/resources/hosting-homes/a/investing-in-our-partnerships-with-local-communities-266.Google Scholar
Angrist, Joshua D., Caldwell, Sydnee, and Hall, Jonathan V.. 2017. “Uber vs. Taxi: A Driver’s Eye View.” Working Paper, w23891. National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w23891.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armstrong, Mark. 2006. “Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” The RAND Journal of Economics 37 (3): 668691.Google Scholar
Autio, Erkko and Thomas, Llewellyn D. W.. 2014. “Innovation Ecosystems: Implications for Innovation Management.” In Dodgson, Mark, Gann, David, and Phillips, Nelson, eds., The Oxford Handbook of Innovation Management. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 204228.Google Scholar
Baldwin, Carliss Y. 2012. “Organization Design for Business Ecosystems.” Journal of Organization Design 1 (1): 2023. https://doi.org/10.7146/jod.6334.Google Scholar
Baldwin, Carliss Y. and Woodard, C. J..(2009). “The Architecture of Platforms: A Unified View.” In Gawer, A., ed., Platforms, Markets and Innovation, London: Edward Elgar, 1944.Google Scholar
Benoit, Sabine, Baker, Thomas L., Bolton, Ruth N., Gruber, Thorsten, and Kandampully, Jay. 2017. “A Triadic Framework for Collaborative Consumption (CC): Motives, Activities and Resources & Capabilities of Actors.” Journal of Business Research 79 (October): 219227. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2017.05.004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouton, Shannon, Canales, Diego, and Trimble, Elaine. n.d. “Public–Private Collaborations for Transforming Urban Mobility.” Accessed June 11, 2021. www.mckinsey.com/business-functions/sustainability/our-insights/public-private-collaborations-for-transforming-urban-mobility#.Google Scholar
Carbone, Valentina, Rouquet, Aurélien, and Roussat, Christine. 2018. “A Typology of Logistics at Work in Collaborative Consumption.” International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management 48 (6): 570585. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJPDLM-11-2017-0355.Google Scholar
Carlsson, B. and Stankiewicz, R.. 1991. “On the Nature, Function and Composition of Technological Systems.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 1 (2): 93118. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01224915.Google Scholar
Cohen, Boyd and Kietzmann, Jan. 2014. “Ride On! Mobility Business Models for the Sharing Economy.” Organization & Environment 27 (3): 279296. https://doi.org/10.1177/1086026614546199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cusumano, Michael A., Gawer, Annabelle, and Yoffie, David B.. 2019. The Business of Platforms: Strategy in the Age of Digital Competition, Innovation, and Power. New York: Harper Business.Google Scholar
Gawer, Annabelle, and Cusumano, Michael A.. 2014. “Industry Platforms and Ecosystem Innovation.” Journal of Product Innovation Management 31 (3): 417433. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpim.12105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geels, Frank W. 2005. Technological Transitions and System Innovations: A Co-Evolutionary and Socio-Technical Analysis. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Geels, Frank W. 2019. “Socio-Technical Transitions to Sustainability: A Review of Criticisms and Elaborations of the Multi-Level Perspective.” Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 39: 187201.Google Scholar
Gurran, Nicole and Phibbs, Peter. 2017. “When Tourists Move In: How Should Urban Planners Respond to Airbnb?Journal of the American Planning Association 83 (1): 8092. https://doi.org/10.1080/01944363.2016.1249011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heydari, Babak and Herder, Paulien. 2021. “Technical and Social Complexity.” In Maier, Anja, Oehmen, Josef, and Vermaas, Pieter E., eds., Handbook of Engineering Systems Design. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 130.Google Scholar
Heydari, Babak, Mosleh, Mohsen, and Dalili, Kia. 2016. “From Modular to Distributed Open Architectures: A Unified Decision Framework.” Systems Engineering 19 (3): 252266.Google Scholar
Heydari, Babak and Pennock, Michael J.. 2018. “Guiding the Behavior of Sociotechnical Systems: The Role of Agent‐Based Modeling.” Systems Engineering 21 (3): 210226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iansiti, Marco and Levien, Roy. 2004. The Keystone Advantage: What the New Dynamics of Business Ecosystems Mean for Strategy, Innovation, and Sustainability. Boston, MA: Harvard Business Press.Google Scholar
Ke, Laiyang, O’Brien, Daniel T., and Heydari, Babak. 2021. “Airbnb and neighborhood crime: The incursion of tourists or the erosion of local social dynamics?PLoS One 16 (7): e0253315.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kuhzady, Salar, Olya, Hossein, Farmaki, Anna, and Ertaş, Çağdaş. 2021. “Sharing Economy in Hospitality and Tourism: A Review and the Future Pathways.” Journal of Hospitality Marketing & Management 30 (5): 549570. https://doi.org/10.1080/19368623.2021.1867281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Francis G. N., Trutnevyte, Evelina, and Strachan, Neil. 2015. “A Review of Socio-Technical Energy Transition (STET) Models.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 100 (November): 290305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, James Frederick. 1993. “Predators and Prey: A New Ecology of Competition.” Harvard Business Review 71 (3): 7586.Google Scholar
Morgan-Thomas, Anna, Dessart, Laurence, and Veloutsou, Cleopatra. 2020. “Digital Ecosystem and Consumer Engagement: A Socio-Technical Perspective.” Journal of Business Research 121 (December): 713723. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.03.042.Google Scholar
Muñoz, Pablo and Cohen, Boyd. 2017. “Mapping out the Sharing Economy: A Configurational Approach to Sharing Business Modeling.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 125 (December): 2137. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.03.035.Google Scholar
Pierce, Lamar. 2009. “Big Losses in Ecosystem Niches: How Core Firm Decisions Drive Complementary Product Shakeouts.” Strategic Management Journal 30 (3): 323347.Google Scholar
Porter, , Michael, E. and Kramer, Mark R.. 2011. “How to Reinvent Capitalism – and Unleash a Wave of Innovation and Growth.” Harvard Business Review 89 (1–2): 6277.Google Scholar
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Tirole, Jean. 2003. “Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (4): 9901029.Google Scholar
Rogers, Brishen. 2015. “The Social Costs of Uber.” University of Chicago Law Review Dialogue 82 (1): 85104.Google Scholar
Roma, Paolo, Panniello, Umberto, and Lo Nigro, Giovanna. 2019. “Sharing Economy and Incumbents’ Pricing Strategy: The Impact of Airbnb on the Hospitality Industry.” International Journal of Production Economics 214 (August): 1729.Google Scholar
Rong, Ke, Li, Boyi, Peng, Wan, Zhou, Di, and Shi, Xinwei. 2021. “Sharing Economy Platforms: Creating Shared Value at a Business Ecosystem Level.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 169 (August): 120804. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2021.120804.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanasi, Silvia, Ghezzi, Antonio, Cavallo, Angelo, and Rangone, Andrea. 2020. “Making Sense of the Sharing Economy: A Business Model Innovation Perspective.” Technology Analysis & Strategic Management 32 (8): 895909.Google Scholar
Schaller, Bruce. 2021. “Can Sharing a Ride Make for Less Traffic? Evidence from Uber and Lyft and Implications for Cities.” Transport Policy 102 (March): 110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2020.12.015.Google Scholar
Schreieck, M., Wiesche, M., and Krcmar, H.. (2016). “Design and Governance of Platform Ecosystems – Key Concepts and Issues for Future Research.” Paper presented at the Twenty-Fourth European Conference on Information Systems, Istanbul, Turkey, June 2016.Google Scholar
Stemler, Abbey. 2017. “The Myth of the Sharing Economy and Its Implications for Regulating Innovation.” Emory Law Journal 67 (2): 197241.Google Scholar
Trist, Eric L. 1981. The Evolution of Socio-Technical Systems. Vol. 2. Toronto: Ontario Quality of Working Life Centre.Google Scholar
Tsujimoto, Masaharu, Kajikawa, Yuya, Tomita, Junichi, and Matsumoto, Yoichi. 2018. “A Review of the Ecosystem Concept – Towards Coherent Ecosystem Design.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 136 (November): 4958. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.06.032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zervas, Georgios, Proserpio, Davide, and Byers, John W.. 2017. “The Rise of the Sharing Economy: Estimating the Impact of Airbnb on the Hotel Industry.” Journal of Marketing Research 54 (5): 687705.Google Scholar
Zhang, Shunyuan, Lee, Dokyun, Singh, Param Vir, and Mukhopadhyay, Tridas. 2020. “Demand Interactions in Sharing Economies: Evidence from a Natural Experiment Involving Airbnb and Uber/Lyft.” SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 3124712. Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3124712.Google Scholar

References

Bocker, L. and Meelen, T.. 2017. Sharing for people, planet or profit? Analysing motivations for intended sharing economy participation. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions 23: 2839.Google Scholar
Chen, T. D. and Kockelman, K. M.. 2016. Carsharing’s life-cycle impacts on energy use and greenhouse gas emissions. Transportation Research Part D-Transport and Environment 47: 276284.Google Scholar
Chenoweth, J. 2009. Is tourism with a low impact on climate possible? Worldwide Hospitality and Tourism Themes 1: 274287.Google Scholar
Chertow, M. R. 2000. Industrial symbiosis: literature and taxonomy. Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 25: 313337.Google Scholar
Chester, M. V. and Horvath, A.. 2009. Environmental assessment of passenger transportation should include infrastructure and supply chains. Environmental Research Letters 4: 024008.Google Scholar
Coles, P. A., Egesdal, M., Ellen, I. G., Li, X., and Sundararajan, A.. 2018. Airbnb usage across New York City neighborhoods: geographic patterns and regulatory implications. In Davidson, N. M., Finck, M., and Infranca, J. J., eds. The Cambridge Handbook on the Law of the Sharing Economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.Google Scholar
Davies, A. R., Edwards, F., Marovelli, B., Morrow, O., Rut, M., and Weymes, M.. 2017. Making visible: interrogating the performance of food sharing across 100 urban areas. Geoforum 86: 136149.Google Scholar
Davies, A. R. and Legg, R.. 2018. Fare sharing: interrogating the nexus of ICT, urban food sharing, and sustainability. Food Culture & Society 21: 233254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demailly, D. and Novel, A.-S.. 2014. The sharing economy: make it sustainable. Studies 3/14.Google Scholar
Dhanorkar, S. 2019. Environmental benefits of internet-enabled C2C closed-loop supply chains: a quasi-experimental study of Craigslist. Management Science 65: 660680.Google Scholar
Eckelman, M. J. and Chertow, M. C.. 2013. Life cycle energy and environmental benefits of a US industrial symbiosis. International Journal of Life Cycle Assessment 18: 15241532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrenfeld, J. R. 2000. Industrial ecology: paradigm shift or normal science? American Behavioral Scientist 44: 229244.Google Scholar
Ellen MacArthur Foundation. 2017. A new textiles economy: redesigning fashion’s future. Ellen MacArthur Foundation: Cowes.Google Scholar
Erhardt, G. D., Roy, S., Cooper, D., Sana, B., Chen, M., and Castiglione, J.. 2019. Do transportation network companies decrease or increase congestion? Science Advances 5: eaau2670.Google Scholar
Fishman, E. and Schepers, P.. 2016. Global bike share: what the data tells us about road safety. Journal of safety research 56: 4145.Google Scholar
Fishman, E., Washington, S., and Haworth, N.. 2014. Bike share’s impact on car use: evidence from the United States, Great Britain, and Australia. Transportation Research Part D: Transport and Environment 31: 1320.Google Scholar
Fremstad, A. 2017. Does Craigslist reduce waste? Evidence from California and Florida. Ecological Economics 132: 135143.Google Scholar
Frenken, K. 2017. Political economies and environmental futures for the sharing economy. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences 375: 20160367.Google Scholar
Frenken, K. and Schor, J.. 2019. Putting the sharing economy into perspective. A research agenda for sustainable consumption governance. Edward Elgar: Cheltenham.Google Scholar
Geissinger, A., Laurell, C., Oberg, C., and Sandstrom, C.. 2019. How sustainable is the sharing economy? On the sustainability connotations of sharing economy platforms. Journal of Cleaner Production 206: 419429.Google Scholar
Graehler, M., Mucci, R. A., and Erhardt, G. D.. 2019. Understanding the recent transit ridership decline in major US cities: service cuts or emerging modes? 98th Annual Meeting Transportation Research Board 19–04931.Google Scholar
Harvey, J., Smith, A., Goulding, J., and Branco Illodo, I.. 2019. Food sharing, redistribution, and waste reduction via mobile applications: a social network analysis. Industrial Marketing Management 88: 437448.Google Scholar
Hollingsworth, J., Copeland, B., and Johnson, J. X.. 2019. Are e-scooters polluters? The environmental impacts of shared dockless electric scooters. Environmental Research Letters 14: 084031.Google Scholar
Kalmykova, Y., Sadagopan, M., and Rosado, L.. 2018. Circular economy: from review of theories and practices to development of implementation tools. Resources, Conservation and Recycling 135: 190201.Google Scholar
Makov, T., Shepon, A., Krones, J., Gupta, C., and Chertow, M.. 2020. Social and environmental analysis of food waste abatement via the peer-to-peer sharing economy. Nature Communications 11: 18.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Martin, M., Lazarevic, D., and Gullstrom, C.. 2019. Assessing the environmental potential of collaborative consumption: peer-to-peer product sharing in Hammarby Sjostad, Sweden. Sustainability 11: 190.Google Scholar
Mi, Z. and Coffman, D. M.. 2019. The sharing economy promotes sustainable societies. Nature Communications 10: 1214.Google Scholar
Mueller, N., Rojas-Rueda, D., Salmon, M., Martinez, D., Ambros, A., Brand, C., De Nazelle, A., Dons, E., Gaupp-Berghausen, M., and Gerike, R.. 2018. Health impact assessment of cycling network expansions in European cities. Preventive Medicine 109: 6270.Google Scholar
Niinimäki, K., Peters, G., Dahlbo, H., Perry, P., Rissanen, T., and Gwilt, A.. 2020. The environmental price of fast fashion. Nature Reviews Earth & Environment 1: 189200.Google Scholar
Nijland, H. and van Meerkerk, J.. 2017. Mobility and environmental impacts of car sharing in the Netherlands. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions 23: 8491.Google Scholar
Parguel, B., Lunardo, R., and Benoit-Moreau, F.. 2017. Sustainability of the sharing economy in question: when second-hand peer-to-peer platforms stimulate indulgent consumption. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 125: 4857.Google Scholar
Plepys, A. and Singh, J.. 2019. Evaluating the sustainability impacts of the sharing economy using input–-output analysis. In Mont, Oksana, ed., A Research Agenda for Sustainable Consumption Governance. Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, 6684.Google Scholar
Skjelvik, J. M., Erlandsen, A. M., and Haavardsholm, O.. 2017. Environmental Impacts and Potential of the Sharing Economy. Nordic Council of Ministers: Copenhagen.Google Scholar
Son, A., Kurisu, Kiyo, Nakatani, Juan, Phuphisith, Sarunnoud, and Moriguchi, Yuichi. 2019. Evaluation of sharing services from the perspectives of environmental loads, consumers’ perceptions and providers’ opinions: A case study of bike sharing and clothes sharing in Bangkok, Thailand. Paper presented at the ISIE 2019 Conference, July 7–11, 2019. Beijing.Google Scholar
Tussyadiah, I. P. and Pesonen, J.. 2016. Impacts of peer-to-peer accommodation use on travel patterns. Journal of Travel Research 55: 10221040.Google Scholar
UCS. 2020. Ride-hailing’s climate risks: steering a growing industry toward a clean transportation future. Union of Concerned Scientists, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Voytenko Palgan, Y., Zvolska, L., and Mont, O.. 2017. Sustainability framings of accommodation sharing. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions 23: 7083.Google Scholar
Wastling, T., Charnley, F., and Moreno, M.. 2018. Design for circular behaviour: considering users in a circular economy. Sustainability 10: 1743.Google Scholar
Woodcock, J., Tainio, M., Cheshire, J., O’Brien, O., and Goodman, A.. 2014. Health effects of the London bicycle sharing system: health impact modelling study. British Medical Journal 348: g425.Google Scholar
Zhang, Y. and Mi, Z.. 2018. Environmental benefits of bike sharing: a big data-based analysis. Applied Energy 220: 296301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

References

Aguirre, E., Mahr, D., Grewal, D., de Ruyter, K., and Wetzels, M. (2015). Unraveling the Personalization Paradox: The Effect of Information Collection and Trust-Building Strategies on Online Advertisement Effectiveness. Journal of Retailing, 91(1), 3449. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2014.09.005Google Scholar
Altman, I. (1977). Privacy Regulation: Culturally Universal or Culturally Specific? Journal of Social Issues, 33(3), 6684.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Awad, N. F. and Krishnan, M. S. (2006). The Personalization Privacy Paradox: An Empirical Evaluation of Information Transparency and the Willingness to Be Profiled Online for Personalization. MIS Quarterly, 30(1), 1328. doi: www.jstor.org/stable/25148715Google Scholar
Bart, Y., Shankar, V., Sultan, F., and Urban, G. L. (2005). Are The Drivers and Role of Online Trust the Same for All Web Sites and Consumers? A Large-Scale Exploratory Empirical Study. Journal of Marketing, 69(4), 133152. doi:https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkg.2005.69.4.133Google Scholar
Bartsch, M. and Dienlin, T. (2016). Control Your Facebook: An Analysis of Online Privacy Literacy. Computers in Human Behavior, 56(March), 147154. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2015.11.022Google Scholar
Belk, R. (2014). You Are What You Can Access: Sharing and Collaborative Consumption Online. Journal of Business Research, 67(8), 15951600. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.10.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bleier, A. and Eisenbeiss, M. (2015). Personalized Online Advertising Effectiveness: The Interplay of What, When, and Where. Marketing Science, 34(5), 669688. doi:https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2015.0930Google Scholar
Bucher, E., Fieseler, C., and Lutz, C. (2016). What’s Mine Is Yours (for a Nominal Fee) – Exploring the Spectrum of Utilitarian to Altruistic Motives for Internet-Mediated Sharing. Computers in Human Behavior, 62(September), 316326. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2016.04.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Centre for International Governance Innovation, and IPSOS. (2018). Data Privacy: New Global Survey Reveals Growing Internet Anxiety. https://unctad.org/en/pages/newsdetails.aspx?OriginalVersionID=1719Google Scholar
Cespedes, F. V. and Smith, H. J. (1993). Database Marketing: New Rules for Policy and Practice. MIT Sloan Management Review, 34(4), 722.Google Scholar
Chellappa, R. K. and Sin, R. G. (2005). Personalization Versus Privacy: An Empirical Examination of the Online Consumer’s Dilemma. Information Technology and Management, 6(2–3), 181202. doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10799-005-5879-yGoogle Scholar
Dienlin, T. and Metzger, M. J. (2016). An Extended Privacy Calculus Model for SNSs: Analyzing Self-Disclosure and Self-Withdrawal in a Representative US Sample. Journal of Computer-Mediated Communication, 21(5), 368383. doi:https://doi.org/10.1111/jcc4.12163Google Scholar
Dinev, T. and Hart, P. (2006). An Extended Privacy Calculus Model for e-Commerce Transactions. Information Systems Research, 17(1), 6180. doi:https://pubsonline.informs.org/doi/abs/10.1287/isre.1060.0080Google Scholar
Eckhardt, G. M., Houston, M. B., Jiang, B., Lamberton, C., Rindfleisch, A., and Zervas, G. (2019). Marketing in the Sharing Economy. Journal of Marketing, 83(5), 527. doi:10.1177/0022242919861929Google Scholar
Fay, S., Mitra, D., and Wang, Q. (2009). Ask or Infer? Strategic Implications of Alternative Learning Approaches in Customization. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 26(2), 136152. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijresmar.2008.12.003Google Scholar
Hamari, J., Sjoklint, M., and Ukkonen, A. (2016). The Sharing Economy: Why People Participate in Collaborative Consumption. Journal of the Association for Information Science and Technology, 67(9), 20472059. doi: https://doi.org/10.1002/asi.23552Google Scholar
Hartzog, W. (2018). Privacy’s Blueprint: The Battle to Control the Design of New Technologies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hong, W. and Thong, J. Y. (2013). Internet Privacy Concerns: An Integrated Conceptualization and Four Empirical Studies. MIS Quarterly, 37(1), 275298. doi: www.jstor.org/stable/43825946Google Scholar
Karwatzki, S., Dytynko, O., Trenz, M., and Veit, D. (2017). Beyond the Personalization–Privacy Paradox: Privacy Valuation, Transparency Features, and Service Personalization. Journal of Management Information Systems, 34(2), 369400. doi:https://doi.org/10.1080/07421222.2017.1334467Google Scholar
Kim, T., Barasz, K., and John, L. K. (2018). Why Am I Seeing This Ad? The Effect of Ad Transparency on Ad Effectiveness. Journal of Consumer Research, 45(5), 906932. doi: //doi.org/10.1093/jcr/ucy039Google Scholar
Kumar, V. (2018). Transformative Marketing: The Next 20 Years. Journal of Marketing, 82(4), 112. doi:https://doi.org/10.1509/jm.82.41Google Scholar
Lemon, K. N. and Verhoef, P. C. (2016). Understanding Customer Experience Throughout the Customer Journey. Journal of Marketing, 80(6), 6996. doi:10.1509/jm.15.0420CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lutz, C., Hoffmann, C. P., Bucher, E., and Fieseler, C. (2018). The Role of Privacy Concerns in the Sharing Economy. Information, Communication and Society, 21(10), 14721492. doi:https://doi.org/10.1080/1369118X.2017.1339726Google Scholar
Lutz, C. and Newlands, G. (2018). Consumer Segmentation Within the Sharing Economy: The Case of Airbnb. Journal of Business Research, 88, 187196. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2018.03.019Google Scholar
Malhotra, N. K., Kim, S. S., and Agarwal, J. (2004). Internet Users’ Information Privacy Concerns (IUIPC): The Construct, the Scale, and a Causal Model. Information Systems Research, 15(4), 336355. doi:https://doi.org/10.1287/isre.1040.0032CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, K. D., Borah, A., and Palmatier, R. W. (2017). Data Privacy: Effects on Customer and Firm Performance. Journal of Marketing, 81(1), 3658. doi:https://doi.org/10.1509/jm.15.0497Google Scholar
Mathur, A., Acar, G., Friedman, M. J., Lucherini, E., Mayer, J., Chetty, M., and Narayanan, A. (2019). Dark patterns at scale: Findings from a crawl of 11K shopping websites. Proceedings of the ACM on Human-Computer Interaction, 3(Computer-Supported Cooperative Work), 132.Google Scholar
Moorman, C., Deshpande, R., and Zaltman, G. (1993). Factors Affecting Trust in Market Research Relationships. Journal of Marketing, 57(1), 81101. doi:https://doi.org/10.1177/002224299305700106Google Scholar
Park, J. H., Gu, B., Leung, A. C. M., and Konana, P. (2014). An Investigation of Information Sharing and Seeking Behaviors in Online Investment Communities. Computers in Human Behavior, 31(February), 112. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2013.10.002Google Scholar
Ranzini, G., Etter, M., Lutz, Ch., and Vermeulen, I. (2017). Privacy in the Sharing Economy (April 30, 2017). https://ssrn.com/abstract=2960942 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2960942CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Satariano, A. and Isaac, M. (2018) Facebook Used People’s Data to Favor Certain Partners and Punish Rivals, Documents Show. The New York Times, December 5.Google Scholar
Smith, H. J., Milberg, S. J., and Burke, S. J. (1996). Information Privacy: Measuring Individuals’ Concerns about Organizational Practices. MIS Quarterly, 20(2), 167196. doi: www.jstor.org/stable/249477Google Scholar
Teubner, T. and Flath, C. M. (2019). Privacy in the Sharing Economy. Journal of the Association for Information Systems, 20(3), 213242. doi:https://doi.org/10.17705/1jais.00534Google Scholar
Thelen, K. (2018). Regulating Uber: The Politics of the Platform Economy in Europe and the United States. Perspectives on Politics, 16(4), 938953. doi:https://doi.org/10.1017/S1537592718001081Google Scholar
Trepte, S., Reinecke, L., Ellison, N. B., Quiring, O., Yao, M. Z., and Ziegele, M. (2017). A Cross-Cultural Perspective on the Privacy Calculus. Social Media+ Society, 3(1), 113. doi:https://doi.org/10.1177/2056305116688035Google Scholar
Trepte, S. Teutsch, D., Masur, P. K., Eicher, C., Fischer, M., Hennhofer, A., and Lind, F. (2015) Do People Know About Privacy and Data Protection Strategies? Towards the “Online Privacy Literacy Scale” (OPLIS). In: Gutwirth, S., Leenes, R., and de Hert, P. (Eds.) Reforming European Data Protection Law. Law, Governance and Technology Series (pp. 333365). Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wasko, M. M., and Faraj, S. (2005). Why Should I Share? Examining Social Capital and Knowledge Contribution in Electronic Networks of Practice. MIS Quarterly, 29(1), 3557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yates, J. F. and Stone, E. R. (1992). Risk appraisal. In Yates, J. F. (Ed.), Wiley Series in Human Performance and Cognition. Risk-Taking Behavior (pp. 4985). Oxford: John Wiley.& Sons.Google Scholar

References

Akerlof, George A. 1970. “The Market for ‘Lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 84(3): 488500.Google Scholar
Angrist, Joshua D. and Jorn-Steffen, Pischke. 2008. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist’s Companion. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bar-Isaac, Heski and Tadelis, Steven. 2008. “Seller Reputation.” Foundations and Trends®in Microeconomics 4(4):273351.Google Scholar
Bolton, Gary, Greiner, Ben, and Ockenfels, Axel. 2013. “Engineering Trust: Reciprocity in the Production of Reputation Information.” Management Science 59(2):265285.Google Scholar
Briedis, Holly, Choi, Michele, Huang, Jess, and Kohli, Sajal. 2020. “Moving Past Friend or Foe: How to Win with Digital Marketplaces.” McKinsey & Company. www.mckinsey.com/industries/retail/our-insights/moving-past-friend-or-foe-how-to-win-with-digital-marketplacesGoogle Scholar
Brown, Jennifer and Morgan, John. 2006. “Reputation in online auctions: The market for trust.” California Management Review 49(1):6181.Google Scholar
Cabral, Luis and Hortaçsu, Ali. 2010. “The Dynamics of Seller Reputation: Evidence from Ebay*.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 58(1):5478.Google Scholar
Cai, Hongbin, Zhe Jin, Ginger, Liu, Chong, and Zhou, Li-An. 2014. “Seller Reputation: From Word-of-Mouth to Centralized Feedback.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 34(C):5165.Google Scholar
Dellarocas, Chrysanthos. 2003. “The Digitization of Word of Mouth: Promise and Challenges of Online Feedback Mechanisms.” Management Science 49(10):1407–24.Google Scholar
Dellarocas, Chrysanthos and Wood, Charles A.. 2008. “The Sound of Silence in Online Feedback: Estimating Trading Risks in the Presence of Reporting Bias.” Management Science 54(3):460476.Google Scholar
Fradkin, A., Grewal, E., Holtz, D., and Pearson, M.. 2015. “Bias and Reciprocity in Online Reviews: Evidence from Experiments on Airbnb.” Paper presented at the 16th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce, June 2015 (EC 2015).Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Horton, John and Golden, Joe. 2015. “Reputation Inflation: Evidence from an Online Labor Market.” Working Paper, New York University.Google Scholar
Hui, Xi-Ang, Saeedi, Maryam, Sundaresan, Neel, and Shen, Zeqian. 2014. “From Lemon Markets to Managed Markets: The Evolution of EBay’s Reputation System.” Working Paper, Ohio State University.Google Scholar
Jaffe, Sonia, Coles, Peter, Levitt, Steven, and Popov, Igor. 2019. “Quality Externalities on Platforms: The Case of Airbnb.” Working Paper.Google Scholar
Jin, Ginger Zhe and Kato, Andrew. 2006. “Price, Quality, and Reputation: Evidence from an Online Field Experiment.” The RAND Journal of Economics 37(4):9831005.Google Scholar
Klein, Tobias, Lambertz, Christian, and Stahl, Konrad. 2013. “Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard in Anonymous Markets.” ZEW – Centre for European Economic Research Discussion Paper no. 13–050.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. M. 1990. “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory.” Pp. 90143 in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, edited by Alt, J. E. and Shepsle, K. A.. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kreps, David M., Milgrom, Paul, Roberts, John, and Wilson, Robert. 1982. “Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoners’ Dilemma.” Journal of Economic Theory 27(2):245252.Google Scholar
Li, Lingfang (Ivy). 2010. “Reputation, Trust, and Rebates: How Online Auction Markets Can Improve Their Feedback Mechanisms.” Journal of Economics \& Management Strategy 19(2):303331.Google Scholar
Li, Lingfang (Ivy), Steven, Tadelis, and Xiaolan, Zhou. 2020. “Buying Reputation as a Signal of Quality: Evidence from an Online Marketplace.” Rand Journal of Economics 51(4):965988.Google Scholar
Li, Lingfang (Ivy) and Erte, Xiao. 2014. “Money Talks: Rebate Mechanisms in Reputation System Design.” Management Science 60(8):20542072.Google Scholar
Livingston, Jeffrey A. 2005. “How Valuable Is a Good Reputation? A Sample Selection Model of Internet Auctions.” Review of Economics and Statistics 87(3):453465.Google Scholar
Masterov, Dimitriy V, Mayer, Uwe F., and Tadelis, Steven. 2015. “Canary in the E-Commerce Coal Mine: Detecting and Predicting Poor Experiences Using Buyer-to-Seller Messages.” Pp. 8193 in Proceedings of the Sixteenth ACM Conference on Economics and Computation, EC ’15. ACM.Google Scholar
Mayzlin, Dina, Dover, Yaniv, and Chevalier, Judith. 2014. “Promotional Reviews: An Empirical Investigation of Online Review Manipulation.” American Economic Review 104(8):24212455.Google Scholar
McDonald, Cynthia G. and Slawson, V. Carlos. 2002. “Reputation in an Internet Auction Market.” Economic Inquiry 40(4):633650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul R., North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1990. “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs.” Economics \& Politics 2(1):123.Google Scholar
Nosko, Chris and Tadelis, Steven. 2015. “The Limits of Reputation in Platform Markets: An Empirical Analysis and Field Experiment.” NBER Working Paper (no. w20830).Google Scholar
Resnick, Paul, Zeckhauser, Richard, Kuwabara, Ko, and Friedman, Eric. 2000. “Reputation Systems.” Communications of the ACM 43(12):4548.Google Scholar
Resnick, Paul, Zeckhauser, Richard, Swanson, John, and Lockwood, Kate. 2006. “The Value of Reputation on EBay: A Controlled Experiment.” Experimental Economics 9(2):79101.Google Scholar
Roth, Alvin E. 2002. “The Economist as Engineer: Game Theory, Experimentation, and Computation as Tools for Design Economics.” Econometrica 70(4):13411378.Google Scholar
Tadelis, Steven. 1999. “What’s in a Name? Reputation as a Tradeable Asset.” American Economic Review 89(3):548563.Google Scholar
Tadelis, Steven. 2012. Game Theory: An Introduction. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Xu, H., Liu, D., Wang, H., and Stavrou, A.. 2015. “E-Commerce Reputation Manipulation: The Emergence of Reputation-Escalation-as-a-Service.” Proceedings of 24th World Wide Web Conference (WWW 2015):12961306, ACM.Google Scholar
Zervas, Georgios, Proserpio, David, and Byers, John. 2015. “A First Look at Online Reputation on Airbnb, Where Every Stay is Above Average.” Working Paper, Boston University.Google Scholar

References

Bearson, Dafna, Kenney, Martin, and Zysman, John. 2020. “Measuring the Impacts of Labor in the Platform Economy: New Work Created, Old Work Reorganized, and Value Creation Reconfigured.” Industrial and Corporate Change 30(3): 536563. doi: 10.1093/icc/dtaa046.Google Scholar
Bennhold, Katrin. 2017. “On London’s Streets, Black Cabs and Uber Fight for a Future.The New York Times, July 4, www.nytimes.com/2017/07/04/world/europe/london-uk-brexit-uber-taxi.htmlGoogle Scholar
Berg, Janine. 2016. “Income Security in the On-Demand Economy: Findings and Policy Lessons from a Survey of Crowdworkers.Comparative Labor Law & Policy Journal 37(3): 543576.Google Scholar
Calo, Ryan and Rosenblat, Alex. 2017. “The Taking Economy: Uber, Information, and Power.” Columbia Law Review 117(6):16231690.Google Scholar
Cameron, Lindsey D. 2018. “The Good Bad Job: Autonomy and Control in the Algorithmic Workplace.” Paper presented at the Academy of Management Annual Meeting in Chicago.Google Scholar
Chen, Julie Yujie. 2018. “Thrown under the Bus and Outrunning It! The Logic of Didi and Taxi Drivers’ Labour and Activism in the on-Demand Economy.” New Media & Society 20(8):26912711. doi: 10.1177/1461444817729149.Google Scholar
Christin, Angèle. 2020. Metrics at Work: Journalism and the Contested Meaning of Algorithms. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Collins, Brett, Garin, Andrew, Jackson, Emilie, Koustas, Dmitri, and Payne, Mark. 2019. “Is Gig Work Replacing Traditional Employment? Evidence from Two Decades of Tax Returns.” www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/19rpgigworkreplacingtraditionalemployment.pdfGoogle Scholar
Curchod, Corentin, Patriotta, Gerardo, Cohen, Laurie, and Neysen, Nicolas. 2019. “Working for an Algorithm: Power Asymmetries and Agency in Online Work Settings.” Administrative Science Quarterly 66(3): 644676. doi: 10.1177/0001839219867024.Google Scholar
Davis, Gerald F. 2016. The Vanishing American Corporation. Oakland CA: Berrett-Koehler.Google Scholar
Dubal, Veena. 2017. “Wage-Slave or Entrepreneur? Contesting the Dualism of Legal Worker Categories.” California Law Review 105:65126.Google Scholar
Dubal, Veena. 2020. “Digital Piecework.” Dissent Magazine. 67(4): 3744.Google Scholar
Dubal, Veena. 2021. “The New Racial Wage Code.” Harvard Journal of Law and Policy 15:511546.Google Scholar
Dubal, Veena and Schor, Juliet B.. 2021Gig Workers Are Employees. Start Treating Them That Way.” The New York Times, Op-ed, January 19.Google Scholar
Einav, Liran, Farronato, Chiara, and Levin, Jonathan. 2016. “Peer-to-Peer Markets.” Annual Review of Economics 8(1):615635. doi: 10.1146/annurev-economics-080315-015334.Google Scholar
Farrell, Diana, Greig, Fiona, and Hamoudi, Amar. 2018. “The Online Platform Economy in 2018: Drivers, Workers, Sellers, and Lessors.” JPMorgan Chase & Co. Institute.Google Scholar
Gorman, Elizabeth H. and Sandefur, Rebecca L.. 2011. “Golden Age,” Quiescence, and Revival: How the Sociology of Professions Became the Study of Knowledge-Based Work.” Work and Occupations 38(3): 275302.Google Scholar
Ilsøe, Anna, Larsen, Trine P., and Bach, Emma S.. 2021. “Multiple Jobholding in the Digital Platform Economy: Signs of Segmentation.” Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research 27(2): 201218.Google Scholar
Kalleberg, Arne L. 2011. Good Jobs, Bad Jobs: The Rise of Polarized and Precarious Employment Systems in the United States, 1970s-2000s. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Kalleberg, Arne L., and Vallas, Steven P.. 2018. “Probing Precarious Work: Theory, Research, and Politics.” Research in the Sociology of Work 31(1): 130.Google Scholar
Maffie, Michael David. 2020. “The Perils of Laundering Control through Customers: A Study of Control and Resistance in the Ride-hail Industry.” ILR Review. December. doi:10.1177/0019793920972679.Google Scholar
Mays, Jeffrey C. “Uber Gains Civil Rights Allies Against New York’s Proposed Freeze: ‘It’s a Racial Issue,’” The New York Times, July 29, www.nytimes.com/2018/07/29/nyregion/uber-cap-civil-rights.html.Google Scholar
Osnowitz, Debra. 2010. Freelancing Expertise. Ithaca: ILR/Cornell.Google Scholar
Parrott, James A. and Reich, Michael. 2018. An Earnings Standard for New York City’s App-Based Drivers. New York: The New School: Center for New York City Affairs.Google Scholar
Parrott, James A. and Reich, Michael. 2020. A Minimum Compensation Standard for Seattle TNC Drivers. Berkeley: University of California, Berkeley: Center on Wage and Employment Dynamics.Google Scholar
Ravenelle, Alexandrea J. 2017. “Sharing Economy Workers: Selling, Not Sharing.” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 10(2):281295. doi: 10.1093/cjres/rsw043.Google Scholar
Ravenelle, Alexandrea J. 2019. Hustle and Gig: Struggling and Surviving in the Sharing Economy. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Robinson, Hilary C. 2017. “Making a Digital Working Class: Uber Drivers in Boston, 2016-2017.” PhD thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Robinson, Hilary C. and Vallas, Steven P.. 2020. “The Lived Experience of Risk among Ride-Hailing Drivers in Boston.” Paper presented at the Annual Meetings of the Society for Socio-Economics. July.Google Scholar
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Tirole, Jean. 2003. “Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1(4): 9901029. doi: 10.1162/154247603322493212.Google Scholar
Rosenblat, Alex. 2018. Uberland: How Algorithms Are Re-Writing the Rules of Work. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Rosenblat, Alex and Stark, Luke. 2016. “Algorithmic Labor and Information Asymmetries: A Case Study of Uber’s Drivers.” International Journal of Communication 10: 37583784.Google Scholar
Scholz, Trebor. 2016. Uberworked and Underpaid: How Workers Are Disrupting the Digital Economy. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Schor, Juliet B. 2017. “Does the Sharing Economy Increase Inequality within the Eighty Percent?: Findings from a Qualitative Study of Platform Providers.” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 10(2): 263279. doi: 10.1093/cjres/rsw047.Google Scholar
Schor, Juliet B. and Attwood-Charles, William. 2017. “The Sharing Economy: Labor, Inequality and Sociability on For-profit Platforms.” Sociology Compass 11(8): 116.Google Scholar
Schor, Juliet B., Attwood-Charles, William, Cansoy, Mehmet, Ladegaard, Isak, and Wengronowitz, Robert. 2020a. “Dependence and Precarity in the Platform Economy.” Theory and Society 49(5): 833861. doi: 10.1007/s11186-020-09408-y.Google Scholar
Schor, Juliet B., Attwood-Charles, William, Cansoy, Mehmet, Carfagna, Lindsey B., Eddy, Samantha, Fitzmaurice, Connor J., Ladegaard, Isak, and Wengronowitz, Robert. 2020b. After the Gig: How the Sharing Economy Got Hijacked and How to Win It Back. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Aaron. 2018. “Between Autonomy and Control: Strategies of Arbitrage in the ‘On-Demand’ Economy.” New Media & Society 20(8): 29542971. doi: 10.1177/1461444817738236.Google Scholar
Srnicek, Nick. 2016. Platform Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity.Google Scholar
Stark, David and Pais, Ivana. 2021. “Algorithmic Management in the Platform Economy.” Sociologica 14(3): 4772.Google Scholar
Sundararajan, Arun. 2016. The Sharing Economy: The End of Employment and the Rise of Crowd-Based Capitalism. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Vallas, Stephen P. 2019. “Platform Capitalism: What’s at Stake for Workers?New Labor Forum 28(1): 4859.Google Scholar
Vallas, Stephen P. and Schor, Juliet B.. 2020. “What Do Platforms Do?:Understanding the Gig Economy.Annual Review of Sociology 46: 273294.Google Scholar
van Doorn, Niels and Chen, Julie Yujie. 2021. “Odds Stacked Against Workers: Datafied Gamification on Chinese and American Food Delivery Platforms.” Socio-Economic Review 19(4): 13451367.Google Scholar
Watkins, Elizabeth A. and Stark, David. 2018, “The Mobius Organizational Form: Make, Buy, Cooperate, or Co-opt?Sociologica 12(1): 6580.Google Scholar
Wood, Alex J., Graham, Mark, Lehdonvirta, Vili, and Hjorth, Isis. 2019. “Good Gig, Bad Gig: Autonomy and Algorithmic Control in the Global Gig Economy.” Work, Employment and Society 33(1): 5675. doi: 10.1177/0950017018785616.Google Scholar
Wood, Alex J. and Lehdonvirta, Vili. 2021. “Platform Precarity: Surviving Algorithmic Insecurity in the Gig Economy.” SSRN Electronic Journal. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3795375Google Scholar
Zanoni, P. 2019. “Labor Market Inclusion Through Predatory Capitalism? The ‘Sharing Economy,’ Diversity, and the Crisis of Social Reproduction in the Belgian Coordinated Market Economy.” In Work and Labor in the Digital Age (Research in the Sociology of Work, vol. 33), eds. Vallas, S. P. and Kovalainen, A., 145164. Binkley: Emerald.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 2.1 Three components of a sociotechnical approach to sharing economy platforms.

Figure 1

Figure 2.2 Sharing economy platforms ecosystem components

Figure 2

Table 4.1 Types of shared information

Figure 3

Figure 4.1 Exchange of information in the sharing economy.

Figure 4

Figure 4.2 Privacy calculus before accessing the sharing economy platform.

Figure 5

Figure 5.1 Trade game with asymmetric information.

Figure 6

Figure 5.2 eBay’s view item page displaying feedback.

Figure 7

Figure 5.3 eBay’s display of a seller’s feedback profile.

Figure 8

Figure 5.4 Percent positive of sellers on eBay.

Figure 9

Figure 5.5 Histogram of sellers’ effective percent-positive scores.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×