Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-lnqnp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T14:10:21.827Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Can Powerful Dictators Escape ‘The Market as Prison’? The Case of Pension Privatisation in Pinochet's Chile

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 December 2024

Ignacio Schiappacasse*
Affiliation:
Economy and Society Research Center (ESOC), Universidad Central de Chile
Diego Sánchez-Ancochea
Affiliation:
Department of International Development, University of Oxford
*
Corresponding author: Ignacio Schiappacasse; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The central role of economic elites in shaping public policy in Latin America has become increasingly clear. Yet most of the recent literature on the subject focuses on democratic contexts. This paper analyses pension privatisation in Chile as a case study for improving our understanding of business–state interaction in authoritarian contexts. Globally, the 1981 pension reform carried out during the Pinochet dictatorship became an example for pension privatisation elsewhere. Analysis of the policy-making process, based on novel empirical material, shows that from 1973 financial groups accumulated growing power which enabled them to first (a) defeat their opponents within the economic elite, (b) overpower their rivals within the state and, finally, (c) force Pinochet into passing pension privatisation legislation. Our results stress the need to include the study of different actors’ power resources – along with ideological issues and the regime structure – in attempts to understand the outcome of policy processes in authoritarian contexts.

El papel central de las élites económicas en la configuración de las políticas públicas en América Latina es cada vez más claro. Sin embargo, la mayor parte de la literatura reciente sobre el tema se centra en contextos democráticos. Este artículo analiza la privatización de las pensiones en Chile como un estudio de caso para ampliar nuestra comprensión de la interacción entre empresarios y Estado en contextos autoritarios. Globalmente, la reforma de las pensiones de 1981 llevada a cabo durante la dictadura de Pinochet se convirtió en un ejemplo de privatización de las pensiones en varios países del mundo. El análisis del proceso de formulación de esta política, basado en material empírico novedoso, muestra que desde 1973 los grupos financieros acumularon un poder creciente que les permitió primero (a) derrotar a sus oponentes al interior de la élite económica, (b) dominar a sus rivales dentro del Estado y, finalmente, (c) obligar a Pinochet a aprobar la privatización de las pensiones. Nuestros hallazgos enfatizan la necesidad de incluir el estudio de los recursos de poder de diferentes actores – junto con aspectos ideológicos y la estructura del régimen – para comprender el resultado de los procesos políticos en contextos autoritarios.

O papel central das elites econômicas na definição das políticas públicas na América Latina tornou-se cada vez mais claro. No entanto, a maior parte da literatura recente sobre o assunto centra-se em contextos democráticos. Este artigo analisa a privatização das pensões no Chile como um estudo de caso para melhorar a nossa compreensão da interação entre empresas e Estado em contextos autoritários. Globalmente, a reforma das pensões de 1981, levada a cabo durante a ditadura de Pinochet, tornou-se um exemplo de privatização das pensões em vários países do mundo. A análise do processo de elaboração desta política, com base em material empírico novo, mostra que desde 1973 os grupos financeiros acumularam um poder crescente que lhes permitiu primeiro (a) derrotar os seus oponentes dentro da elite econômica, (b) dominar os seus rivais dentro do Estado, e, finalmente, (c) forçar Pinochet a aprovar a privatização das pensões. Os nossos resultados sublinham a necessidade de incluir o estudo dos recursos de poder dos diferentes atores – juntamente com aspectos ideológicos e a estrutura do regime – para compreender o resultado dos processos políticos em contextos autoritários.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

Introduction

‘Who will manage the money? That gets me nervous because I also know that several gentlemen are becoming millionaires in this country, and they have sent people [abroad] to study the [pension] system since they want to operate in it’, said General Augusto Pinochet in October 1980 during the opening of the key secret session in which the military Junta discussed – and ultimately passed – the proposed reform to privatise Chile's pension system.Footnote 1 Later during the same meeting, the powerful dictator was to reiterate his concerns several times: ‘I believe that a new pension system is necessary, but the fact that there will be so much money and [that] here we have a bunch of crooks [who might take advantage of the system] causes me anguish.’Footnote 2

Pinochet thus revealed his significant misgivings regarding the radical pension reform which was to replace the pay-as-you-go system by a scheme of individual capitalisation.Footnote 3 In the privacy of a secret session of the military Junta, the dictator, who ruled Chile with an iron fist for 17 years (1973–90), recognised the anguish caused by the prospect of a pension system being run by the private sector. Pinochet was fearful of the mammoth financial conglomerates (the ‘gentlemen’ and ‘crooks’) that controlled large swaths of the Chilean economy thanks to the policies implemented by his own government.Footnote 4

How can we explain, then, Pinochet's approval of pension privatisation in spite of these fears and even against the recommendations of trusted advisors? Previous research has explained the adoption of the radical reform by reference to state autonomy and the concentration of power in the hands of Pinochet.Footnote 5 This literature, nonetheless, has not addressed the central question of why Pinochet passed the reform in spite of his strong reservations and those of many collaborators. We argue that in order to make sense of this puzzle we have to pay more attention to the Chilean economic elite and its multifaceted sources of power. Using Charles Lindblom's metaphor,Footnote 6 we contend that Pinochet became hostage to the market prison built with his own assistance through a series of market-oriented reforms. As we shall see, these reforms strengthened financial conglomerates vis-à-vis other segments of the economic elite and the state, enhancing their power.

Our aim is thus to analyse pension privatisation in Chile so as to improve our understanding of business–state relations in authoritarian contexts. We show that from 1973 financial groups accumulated growing power, which enabled them to (a) firstly defeat their opponents within the economic elite (i.e. traditional conglomerates), (b) overpower their rivals within the state (high-ranking corporatist officers), and, finally, (c) force Pinochet into passing pension privatisation. We study these outcomes by means of a comparative analysis across three stages of the policy-making process, namely: (i) agenda setting before the coup (1970–3); (ii) the design of a compromise bill including both neoliberal and corporatist ideas (1973–6); and (iii) the definitive implementation of pension privatisation (1976–81). Our study of the policy process relies on a diversity of sources, including the minutes of the military Junta's secret sessions and a hitherto unpublished secret document prepared by the regime's Budget Office (see note Footnote 80). We also draw on interviews with key players who participated in the policy-making process, including five former high-ranking government officials and ministers with strong links to the economic elite. Additionally, we undertook extensive archival research in the press records at the Biblioteca Nacional (National Library). We identified causal mechanisms and assembled the explanations of our argument by triangulating information across those multiple, independent data sources.

In rethinking the relationship between the economic elite and the Pinochet dictatorship in Chile, we make a broader contribution to the political economy literature on state–business relations in non-democratic environments. This contribution is particularly useful given both the importance of dictatorships in Latin America's past development and the current authoritarian backlash across the world. Most of the recent literature on business power focuses on democratic contexts,Footnote 7 paying much less attention to the role of economic elites in dictatorships. Yet, as we will show, several sources of business power identified by authors working on democracies are also useful for the study of authoritarian regimes. By adapting the conceptual framework developed for studying business in democratic contexts to an authoritarian setting, we provide new insights into the channels and mechanisms through which economic elites might influence the policy process under authoritarian regimes. Our contribution is also empirical as we provide novel evidence – including unpublished secret documents from the dictatorship era – about a case of global interest. Chile represents the world's first and most notable case of pension privatisation and an inspiration to a number of Latin American, Asian and European countries.Footnote 8

We proceed now with a review of the literature on business–state relations – paying particular attention to the Latin American context – showing its insufficient attention to mechanisms of influence exerted by businesses in authoritarian contexts. We then argue that the categories for the study of business power recently developed for democratic contexts can be adapted to non-democratic regimes. The bulk of the paper comprises an empirical analysis of the policy process (1970–81). It concludes with some reflections on the broader relevance of our research.

Business Power and the State under Authoritarian Regimes: An Incomplete Literature

During the 1970s, influential political economists studied the role of big business under authoritarian regimes. Much of this literature – covering topics from bureaucratic authoritarianism to dependency theory – followed a macro-historical approach in order to show how capitalist groups influenced political and economic development. These approaches were interested in explaining structural outcomes: in the case of bureaucratic authoritarianism, the challenge was to account for the emergence of bureaucratic dictatorships as the result of the process of late modernisation.Footnote 9 Dependency scholars assessed the historical origins of different capitalist modes of production.Footnote 10 These approaches often assumed business influence instead of providing supporting empirical evidence or illustrating the mechanisms by which such influence operated in practice. Similarly, other influential authors have developed typologies of authoritarian regimes, distinguishing them according to the role played by ideologies, modes of repression, and party and mass organisations, among other factors.Footnote 11 However, in these works the multiple mechanisms by which big business influences the policy-making process also remain understudied.

After the attention on business elites faded from Latin America's research agenda during the 1980s, the issue returned to the fore in the early 1990s.Footnote 12 The new literature paid more attention to specific policy processes and provided richer empirical accounts but failed to develop an adequate understanding of business–state relations under authoritarianism. This literature swung between theories of the ‘autonomous state’ (in which insulated policy-makers were able to adopt whichever policies they wanted)Footnote 13 and others suggesting that big businesses shaped policy in military regimes.Footnote 14

Similarly, much of the study of social policy in authoritarian contexts in Latin America adopted a state-centred approach even when considering the role of economic elites. For example, in her informative analyses of Chile and Uruguay, Rossana Castiglioni highlights the centralised structure of Chile's dictatorship and the ideological position of technocratic elites.Footnote 15 According to this view, Pinochet's one-man rule facilitated the rise of the Chicago Boys to the upper echelons of the Chilean state.Footnote 16 From such positions and with high degrees of autonomy, they were able to push for a radical re-structuring of the country's pension system. This literature thus presents social policy reforms as a battle over ideas and state power, paying much less attention to the role of business interests.

Eduardo Silva considers the role of business groups in the politics of policy change in Latin America more explicitly.Footnote 17 Focusing on the study of market liberalisation during the Pinochet regime, Silva argues that the pace and content of neoliberal reforms was a result of changing relations between the state and different business coalitions. He characterises the process of economic restructuring according to changes occurring within both the state and the dominant business coalition that supported the dictatorship, which also influenced the patterns of interaction between the state and business. Although we draw on Silva's excellent research, we aim to provide a clearer understanding of the different means and mechanisms used by economic elites to advance their interests. Since he focuses on explaining large-scale policy shifts, we contend that the next step required to advance theory on business power in authoritarian regimes is the detailed, sustained analysis of specific policy-making processes.

During the last decade, there has been a surge in studies of economic elites in Latin America, following and extending path-breaking work in the Global North. The work of Tasha Fairfield has inspired a number of contributions that have studied the influence of big business in different realms such as redistribution and industrial and social policy.Footnote 18 This scholarly work has focused precisely on the examination of the multiple means and mechanisms by which economic elites might influence governments’ decision-making. Rooted in Jacob Hacker and Paul Pierson's seminal work,Footnote 19 Fairfield specifies a comprehensive set of mechanisms of business influence and guidelines for operationalisation, thereby providing analytical tools with stronger explanatory leverage for causal inference.

This operationalisation is mainly based on two categories for the study of business power: instrumental power and structural power (see Table 1). Instrumental power refers to deliberate, organised actions carried out in the political arena to influence the policy-making process.Footnote 20 Lobbying, funding political parties and editorialising in the press constitute some examples of collective actions carried out by economic elites using their sources of instrumental power. The second type is structural power, which arises from the myriad of investment decisions – based on profit-maximising criteria – taken by firms and capital owners. In a capitalist society, the state depends on businesses to invest and produce in ways that foster collective prosperity.Footnote 21 Hence, governments may themselves halt reforms that can harm investors’ confidence, thus affecting investment and economic growth.Footnote 22 In contrast to instrumental power, structural power does not require any capacity for collective action.

Table 1. Main Descriptive Aspects of Instrumental and Structural Power

Note: Underlining indicates those sources of power that do not translate from democratic to authoritarian contexts; bold indicates sources of power that are new to authoritarian contexts (i.e. do not exist in the democratic context).

Source: Authors’ elaboration based on Hacker and Pierson, ‘Business Power and Social Policy’; Fairfield, Private Wealth and Public Revenue in Latin America; Fairfield, ‘Structural Power in Comparative Political Economy’.

Fairfield applies the instrumental–structural framework to the study of tax politics in Latin America. She finds that taxing economic elites was difficult when either their instrumental or their structural power was strong, or when, in combination, those two types of power exerted a significant influence on policy-making. As such, along with her specification of multiple causal mechanisms, her contribution to the field lies in the recognition that instrumental power and structural power are mutually reinforcing. These two types of business power were traditionally seen as mutually exclusive in the literature.

However, Fairfield and the recent scholarly work inspired by the instrumental– structural framework have focused primarily on democratic contexts. These works yield insights into how economic elites exert influence in market democracies, with elections and political parties. They rely, for example, on the close links between economic elites and conservative parties. How useful are these concepts in non-democratic environments? How does business power operate in authoritarian settings, with outlawed political parties, shut-down legislative assemblies, and highly concentrated executive power?

The recent literature exploring these questions is scarce. To the best of our knowledge, there are no studies of business power in Latin America's military regimes that apply the instrumental–structural framework. We need to turn our attention to other regions to find studies that follow this approach. In particular, Jeffrey Winters analyses Indonesia's political economy during General Suharto's authoritarian regime (1965–98).Footnote 23 He assesses how business power influenced Indonesia's policy trajectory, accounting for variations in the state's responsiveness to those controlling private capital. Nonetheless, his work focuses on the analysis of structural power (with, besides, a strong emphasis on capital mobility), paying less attention to instrumental power.

Adapting the Instrumental–Structural Framework to Authoritarian Contexts

In this paper we adapt Fairfield's framework to understand how economic elites can achieve their policy preferences in authoritarian settings. Economic elites, in this context, wield their power to obtain the policies they prefer, which in turn are determined by their material interests. For instance, the financial sector tends to constitute an unambiguous proponent of pension privatisation because it allows it to become providers of retirement savings products.Footnote 24 In this view, then, economic elites pursue their preferences by influencing policy-making through different sources of power (e.g. recruitment of business representatives into government), which allow them to carry out a number of actions (e.g. direct participation in policy-making), which in the end result in observable implications (e.g. pension privatisation). The application of the instrumental–structural framework to authoritarian contexts requires the modification of some of the causal mechanisms shown in Table 1: we underline those sources of power that do not translate from democratic to authoritarian contexts, while sources of power that are new to authoritarian contexts are highlighted in bold. For the sake of brevity, the following discussion will focus on the analysis of those sources of power, actions and observable implications that change when we move the analysis from democratic to authoritarian contexts.Footnote 25

Given the nature of structural power, we do not expect substantial changes in the way this type of power might influence the policy process. As long as markets remain a key allocation mechanism, we expect structural power to exert a similar effect on democratic and authoritarian governments: in both cases policy-makers refrain from implementing reforms that could harm investment. Nonetheless, at this point we depart from Fairfield's operationalisation since we acknowledge the possibility that economic considerations might compel both authoritarian and democratic governments to implement policies in order to promote investment. As such, the pressure to restore or enhance business confidence might also act in the opposite direction to a credible disinvestment threat: it may compel governments to enact and implement reforms benefiting business interests.Footnote 26

The channel of transmission of structural power does differ between the two contexts. In democratic regimes, policy-makers chiefly avoid negative aggregate economic outcomes since they might be severely punished at the polls. Dictators are subject to the effects of economic performance but in different ways. For instance, a severe economic crisis could prompt the economic elite to shift their regime loyalty and promote a process of political change. Likewise, an economic downturn might activate popular sectors, with the potential of becoming a veritable threat to the regime's continuity.

In comparison with structural power, sources of instrumental power vary significantly in authoritarian contexts. In terms of relationships with policy-makers, partisan linkages and election to public office are sources of power that do not translate to authoritarian contexts. By contrast, in authoritarian regimes there are new avenues for business influence. In military regimes, members of the armed forces usually become policy-makers. This fact determines the need – and opportunity – for business representatives to curry favour with high-ranking officers. In this regard, we expect to find evidence of power-building investments carried out by members of the economic elite aimed at strengthening their relationships with the military (i.e. ties to the armed forces in Table 1).

As for resources, the main differences relate to media access. We expect that money, technical expertise and cohesion will be mobilised in similar ways in both authoritarian and democratic contexts. In the case of media access, however, the direction of change is not clear and will be highly context specific. As a norm, authoritarian regimes severely curtail the freedom of the press. The extent to which an authoritarian government controls and censors their domestic press will determine the effect on ‘media access’ as businesses’ sources of power. In cases in which authoritarian governments censor free press except for media outlets owned by the economic elite, we expect business power through media access be significantly augmented. Under these circumstances, conservative media would have substantial leeway to shape public opinion and determine the policy agenda.

In the next section, we will see how the interplay of these multiple sources of power determined the implementation of the 1981 pension reform in Chile.

Privatisation of Chile's Pension System: Analysis of the Policy Process

The following sections analyse the policy-making process that started in the early 1970s and led to the outcome we are trying to understand: implementation of the radical 1981 pension reform. The aim is to carry out a comparative analysis of three distinct stages, highlighting changes in the independent variables (business power, state structure and the interaction among them) that led to changes in our dependent variable (different stages of the neoliberal pension reform). In the analysis of each subperiod we will begin by describing the outcome to be explained and will then discuss changes in the independent variables.

First Stage (1970–September 1973): Pension Reform in the Making

The Outcome

During this period, the first outline of the ultimately approved pension reform was published. Months before the coup, top executives and neoliberal technocrats – selected and controlled by business representatives – had drafted an economic programme dubbed ‘El Ladrillo’ (‘The Brick’), distributed in mimeographed form and eventually printed in 1992.Footnote 27 This economic plan advocated for a gradual shift toward a market-based economy. In one of its chapters, El Ladrillo already contains the main features of the scheme based on individual capitalisation accounts, later known as the ‘AFP system’ after the for-profit Administradoras de Fondos de Pensiones (Pension Funds Administrators, AFPs) that managed workers’ savings. Prepared in the event of a military takeover, El Ladrillo largely defined the military regime's economic agenda and represented a compromise between the different segments of the broad business coalition that supported the coup.

The Pre-Coup Gradualist Business Coalition

Two segments of the economic elite played a leading role in this broad business coalition: (i) traditional, internationally competitive economic groups, and (ii) financial conglomerates with connections to international financial markets.Footnote 28 Differences in the conglomerates’ concentration in different sectors of the economy determined such categories. Given that the economic composition of business conglomerates is closely related to their interests (which, in turn, may determine distinct policy preferences and roles in the policy-making process), a brief analysis of their business portfolios is in order.Footnote 29 Conglomerates with a higher concentration in (highly mobile) liquid assets, for example, may push for faster, radical changes as they are able to adjust much more quickly than fixed-assets holders to market signals. Financial conglomerates held portfolios with a heavy concentration in liquid assets, with two-thirds or more of their companies in sectors such as banking, insurance, commerce and real estate speculation. In contrast, only roughly a half of the holdings of the traditional conglomerates were in liquid assets; the other half were in industrial, fixed-asset sectors (see Table 2). Importantly, traditional conglomerates constituted the dominant fraction in this broad, intersectoral gradualist coalition, while financial conglomerates occupied a subordinate position.Footnote 30

Table 2. Major Conglomerates in 1970 and Concentration of Companies by Economic Activity

Source: Adapted from Silva, The State and Capital in Chile.

Both groups favoured economic restructuring towards a market-based economy, including pension privatisation. Traditional conglomerates, the dominant segment, pushed for a gradual market-based restructuring with an emphasis on industrialisation: as they held interests in fixed-asset sectors, these groups could adapt only to a gradual, slower opening of the economy to external competition. By contrast, financial conglomerates – given their portfolios concentrated in liquid assets – preferred a swift and radical restructuring of the economy. The gradualist coalition, forged in the early 1970s during the political campaign against the Socialist presidential candidate Salvador Allende, was thus to be a fragile, short-lived alliance.Footnote 31 By 1975, it would be superseded by a coalition led solely by the radical financial conglomerates (hereafter referred to as the ‘radical neoliberal coalition’ or simply ‘radical coalition’) and excluding traditional groups.Footnote 32

As different historical accounts attest, business opposition to the Allende government started soon after his election in 1970.Footnote 33 In mid 1971, top executives of the most influential traditional and financial conglomerates began to meet on a regular basis. Representatives of the Edwards group (traditional) and of the radical financial conglomerate BHC coalesced around what they called ‘The Monday Club’ (as they met every Monday for lunch). This network represented a key source of instrumental power, becoming the main locus of civilian organisation of the coup and coordination with the armed forces. From this network, the gradualist coalition was able to establish strong ties to the armed forces. These ties would allow the gradualist coalition to influence the economic agenda (and particularly the discussion on pensions) in the initial phase of the military regime.

One of the main participants in this network was ex-navy officer Hernán Cubillos, at that time top executive of the Edwards group, and future minister of Foreign Affairs during the dictatorship (1978–80). Cubillos constituted the chief link between the gradualist coalition and the armed forces. Navy officers who participated in the plot against Allende let it be known that they could not go ahead with the coup if they did not have a clear economic programme.Footnote 34 The communication channel for this message was via another ex-navy officer and top executive of the Edwards conglomerate, Roberto Kelly, who passed the message to Cubillos and would later play a key role recruiting neoliberal technocrats for the Oficina de Planificación Nacional (National Planning Office, ODEPLAN; see further below).Footnote 35

Months before the coup d’état, representatives of the Monday Club convened a group of top executives and Chicago Boys with the aim of drafting a post-coup economic programme: the afore-mentioned Ladrillo.Footnote 36 This policy document represented a compromise between the dominant, traditional conglomerates and the subordinate radical financial conglomerates. It advocated for economic restructuring, but proposed a gradual process without a defined calendar.Footnote 37

El Ladrillo's authors were neoliberal technocrats, materially connected with both traditional and financial conglomerates, who were to reach highly influential posts in the authoritarian regime's Cabinet. The lead author was Sergio de Castro, known as the ‘dean’ of the Chicago Boys. Linked to the Edwards group through his work for the Centro de Estudios Sociales (Social Studies Centre, CESEC), the think-tank funded by this conglomerate,Footnote 38 after the coup de Castro began his service in government as an advisor, becoming Minister of the Economy in April 1975. Another prominent author of El Ladrillo was Manuel Cruzat, a close friend of de Castro, who was top executive of the largest financial conglomerate, the BHC. In the early 1970s, Cruzat and his brother-in-law, Fernando Larraín, split off from the BHC group.Footnote 39 From 1974 onwards, then, Manuel Cruzat would lead the mammoth Cruzat-Larraín financial conglomerate.

Previous research has generally depicted the Chicago Boys as autonomous, failing to highlight their close contacts with the economic elite.Footnote 40 Top executives of economic conglomerates were closely allied to the radical Chicago Boys, forming a network that grew out of a shared social, professional and academic background. For instance, most of the Chicago Boys and some top executives had studied economics together at the Pontificia Universidad Católica and, in some cases, at the University of Chicago.Footnote 41 Furthermore, the most prominent Chicago Boys were top executives of both traditional and financial conglomerates before and after their appointments to top positions in Pinochet's dictatorship.

As noted, El Ladrillo contains the first blueprint of the pension reform finally implemented in 1981. In one section, entitled ‘Welfare and Social Security Policies’, it introduces what was to constitute a paradigmatic shift: the transition from a pay-as-you-go pension plan to a fully funded scheme based on individual accounts.Footnote 42 The new pension scheme would consist of two subsystems: a state-provided minimum pension and ‘the second, that would be based on a system of mandatory savings scheme that would be deposited monthly in a specialised institution … which savings could be drawn out only in the form of a life annuity on reaching retirement age’.Footnote 43 Given their significant holdings in liquid assets, pension privatisation as outlined in El Ladrillo suited the interests of both traditional and financial conglomerates. Among other opportunities provided by the new scheme, pension fund managers could invest in debt instruments issued by their banks and shares issued by their companies, and their insurance companies could sell life annuities to retirees.

Having coalesced around the Monday Club and offered a coherent economic plan, the gradualist business coalition was able to set the policy agenda early in the authoritarian government: the one detailed in El Ladrillo prevailed because it was a coherent programme. In contrast, the top military officers involved in the conspiracy did not have a clear economic plan.Footnote 44 Immediately after the coup some asked precisely those neoliberal technocrats who had worked on El Ladrillo for help. Thus, early on ties to the armed forces coupled with technical expertise constituted an additional source of instrumental power for the economic elite. In the aftermath of the coup, then, civilians materially connected to the gradualist coalition became ministers in influential positions, while the Chicago Boys were appointed as advisors.Footnote 45

Critical for the analysis of pension policy-making, the segment of internationally uncompetitive capitalists producing for the domestic markets constituted the only fraction of the economic elite which was not part of the broad, gradualist coalition just discussed. This segment did not favour a departure from the Import-Substitution Industrialisation (ISI) strategy and opposed a shift toward a market-based economy. These internationally uncompetitive industrialists had been passive supporters of the expansion of the social security system as it constituted a vital aspect of the bargain maintaining the multiclass alliance that supported the ISI model.Footnote 46 Nonetheless, Allende's policy of nationalisation had weakened this segment, thus reducing their influence.

Second Stage (September 1973–March 1976): Corporatist Officers Limit the Chances for Radical Pension Privatisation

The Outcome

During this second stage that extends from the military takeover (11 September 1973) to March 1976, the military Junta pursued a compromise pension bill. This bill attempted to harmonise the reform proposal developed in El Ladrillo with one prepared by high-ranking corporatist officers (the so-called ‘Anteproyecto’).Footnote 47 This group of corporatist officers – who were the main plotters of the military takeover – was independent of business power. As such, they pursued their own agenda. Proponents of El Ladrillo controlled ODEPLAN while corporatist military officers – who aimed to harmonise labour–capital relations as a means of purging Marxism from Chilean society and strengthening national security – were more influential within the Ministry of Labour and Social Security, formally in charge of the reform process. ODEPLAN was a key agency for the Chicago Boys: they controlled it immediately after the coup, and from there they designed and promoted their policies.Footnote 48

The compromise bill pursued by the government up to 1976 was, therefore, an attempt to harmonise contradictory, disparate concepts such as state subsidiarity (the principle of a limited role for the state being key for neoliberal technocrats) and universalism (supported by corporatist officers).Footnote 49 While ODEPLAN prevailed in the financial aspects of the proposal (i.e. creation of individual capitalisation accounts),Footnote 50 the Ministry of Labour prevailed in the determination of the administrative structure: pension funds were to be managed by semi-public, non-profit organisations run by workers to be called ‘Corporaciones de Seguridad Social’ (‘Social Security Corporations’). The Ministry of Labour officially presented the Anteproyecto to the public in November 1975, aiming to promote an open discussion. Nonetheless, the process came to an abrupt halt when the Chicago Boys took control of the Ministry of Labour in 1976 and blocked the proposal.

Pensions and the Gradualist Coalition

The dictatorship's initial ministerial structure reflected the balance of power within the economic elite. As we saw above, the broad, intersectoral gradualist coalition was dominated by traditional conglomerates, with financial groups playing a subordinate position. The radical neoliberal technocrats’ subordinate role in the government apparatus is evident in Figures 1a and 1b: in 1973 and 1974 Chicago Boys were in advisory positions and none of them occupied a ministerial post. Gradualists such as Fernando Léniz, former top executive of the Edwards group, occupied key positions like the Ministry of the Economy. The Ministry of Labour and Social Security was headed by a corporatist general, Nicanor Díaz, who was a very close associate of General Gustavo Leigh, member of the military Junta.

Figure 1. Evolution of the Composition of the Cabinet, 1973–81

Notes: Boxes shaded in grey indicate members of the Chicago Boys’ network.

DC Member of Democracia Cristiana

M Minister/Ministry

P President

SEGEGOB Secretaría General de Gobierno

VP Vice-president

Source: Authors’ elaboration based on Fontaine Aldunate, Los economistas y el presidente Pinochet; ‘Boris Blanco: la caída del superintendente’, Hoy, 15 March 1984, pp. 24–9; ‘Falleció ex canciller Hernán Cubillos’, El Mercurio, 11 April 2001, p. C1; Empresa Periodística de Chile, Diccionario Biográfico de Chile, 1984–1986, 18th edn (Santiago: Empresa Periodística de Chile, 1986); ‘Previsión: el debut de las AFP’, Hoy, 13 May 1981, pp. 30–3; ‘Quién es y cómo es Javier Vial, y el baile de los pesos’, Hoy, 26 Aug. 1981, pp. 22–6; ‘Quién es y cómo es Manuel Cruzat, el millonario invisible’, Hoy, 16 Sept. 1981, pp. 19–22; María Olivia Mönckeberg, El saqueo de los grupos económicos al Estado chileno (Santiago: Ediciones B, 2001); ‘Las once de la “competencia”’; ‘COPEC: los rostros nuevos’, Hoy, 24 June 1981, p. 43.

* Humberto Pizarro was an ‘outsider’: neither an economist nor a graduate of the Pontificia Universidad Católica.

ODEPLAN was led by Kelly, an ex-navy officer who opposed the high-ranking corporatist officers and was one of the main links between the military plotters and the economic elite. As mentioned above, after leaving the navy Kelly became top executive of the Edwards group, which was at the core of the gradualist coalition.Footnote 51 He recruited a number of neoliberal technocrats to ODEPLAN. The most prominent was Miguel Kast, who played a critical role in the pension discussions from the beginning: in 1972, his report on the US system of private retirement accounts constituted the basis for the proposal developed in El Ladrillo.Footnote 52 From then on Kast became the most prominent ideologist and promoter of the neoliberal reform of the pension system.Footnote 53

There were additional ties between the Chicago Boys and the armed forces. One of these links was Colonel Enrique Lackington, appointed Undersecretary for the Economy immediately after the coup. His son, also an economist, was a close friend of de Castro and recommended de Castro and other Chicago Boys as advisors to the Ministry of the Economy.Footnote 54 Ties to the armed forces, coupled with informal ties and recruitment of business representatives into government were, therefore, the most decisive sources of instrumental power for the gradualist coalition (and for financial conglomerates in particular) in the period following the military takeover.

The conflict between neoliberal economists and high-ranking corporatist officers had been acute since the beginning. Kelly, for instance, recalls that when Kast proposed in 1974 the replacement of a common fund with individual capitalisation accounts, ‘Leigh was furious, he said that it was madness to propose such reform.’Footnote 55 The economic elite pushed directly for neoliberal reform while they – and their Chicagoan associates – resisted the creation of workers’ associations to manage pension funds. Informal ties afforded the economic elite the opportunity to reach General Díaz himself and put pressure on him. Speaking to Hoy magazine in 1980, Díaz asserted that ‘many businessmen came directly to my office to criticise the bill given that, in their opinion, workers would not be able to manage their funds efficiently’.Footnote 56

For the authoritarian regime, the solution to this acute conflict was the compromise bill. The first draft of the Anteproyecto was formally submitted to the military Junta on 23 October 1974,Footnote 57 and the government announced the reform to the public in November 1975.Footnote 58 The proposal sought to solve the severe economic burden of the pay-as-you-go system by streamlining benefits. The bill also considered the introduction of a common fund and cross-subsidies in order to fund other social security programmes. The Ministry of Labour promoted open discussion by disseminating the reform in the media and carrying out dialogues with workers’ associations and specialists.Footnote 59 The result of this consultation process, which culminated in February 1976, was a four-volume report with comments and suggestions.Footnote 60

Yet this participatory process came to an abrupt halt in March 1976 when Sergio Fernández replaced General Díaz as the head of the Ministry of Labour. Fernández was a gremialista and hardliner, who had been working with Kast on ODEPLAN's reform proposal.Footnote 61 Why did this change take place? Did it reflect a change in the balance of power within and outside the state?

Mutually Reinforcing Changes within the Economic Elite and the State

General Díaz had battled for the pre-eminence of corporatist ideas, opposing the Chicagoans’ uncompromising neoliberal orthodox views.Footnote 62 Yet he grew increasingly isolated: the economic elite opposed his plans because they were too ‘statist’, while trade unions did not support them either. Díaz's resignation and the appointment of Fernández as Minister of Labour signalled the Chicago Boys’ growing ascendency and can be explained by mutually reinforcing changes within the economic elite and the state.

Disputes between traditional and financial conglomerates over the pace and extent of the economy's liberalisation broke the gradualist coalition in early 1975.Footnote 63 The short-lived gradualist coalition was to be replaced by the radical neoliberal coalition led by the financial conglomerates, which progressively enhanced their sources of structural and instrumental power.

A combination of international and domestic factors facilitated this process. At the beginning of the 1970s, only two conglomerates made up the financial segment's core (see Table 2): the Vial group and its spin-off, the Cruzat-Larraín conglomerate. Critically, these financial groups controlled the negotiation of foreign loans.Footnote 64 By late 1973, the first oil crisis, coupled with the lack of loans from multilateral lending banks, aggravated Chile's traditional foreign exchange bottlenecks. The country found itself without access to international financial institutions because of an international boycott of the authoritarian regime. Moreover, in 1974, a sharp fall in the price of copper – Chile's main export – made the external position even worse.

Financial conglomerates promoted the implementation of an orthodox stabilisation programme (so-called ‘shock therapy’) to solve the crisis. Breaking with the gradualist coalition, they pushed for drastic neoliberal economic measures including the deregulation of the financial sector, faster privatisation and tariff reductions. Crucially, in April 1975 Pinochet decided to support the implementation of the ‘shock therapy’ to stabilise the economy. This decision was followed by a Cabinet reshuffle, which crystallised the rise of the radical financial coalition to the top and meant the delegation of decision-making to the Chicago Boys. Firstly, Jorge Cauas, a former Christian Democrat and Chicago Boy sympathiser,Footnote 65 took over the post of ‘Super-Minister of Finance’ through a decree granting him extraordinary powers.Footnote 66 Secondly, de Castro replaced gradualist Fernando Léniz as Minister of the Economy.Footnote 67 By April 1975, then, neoliberal technocrats materially linked to financial conglomerates controlled all positions in the Economics Ministry (comparison of Figures 1b and 1c shows the speed and scale of the change). Chile thus began to embrace an extreme version of neoliberalism.Footnote 68

Pinochet's support for the shock therapy was decisive for its implementation: by late 1974, he had concentrated all executive power in his hands. A significant step in this direction came in mid 1974 with the creation of DINA (the military intelligence agency), which operated under Pinochet's direct command. He was also successful in gradually purging his most influential (mostly corporatist) political rivals within the army.Footnote 69

Why did Pinochet support the radical and risky stabilisation programme? The answer has little to do with economic theory: Pinochet did not have a clear policy agenda or much understanding of economics.Footnote 70 Rather, two other factors are more significant. First, according to Silva, Pinochet was well aware of the growing structural power of the radical financial coalition in the context of the severe credit crunch and hopeful that such groups would back neoliberal policies with increasing levels of investment.Footnote 71 The fact that these conglomerates had the ability to provide foreign reserves made them very attractive to Pinochet.Footnote 72 Second, Pinochet decided to support the Chicago Boys as a way of distancing himself from his adversaries inside the military Junta, especially the corporatist General Leigh.Footnote 73

The application of the shock treatment significantly strengthened the radical coalition. It gave financial conglomerates an advantageous position to acquire low-priced state companies during the recessionary period, while further weakening the internationally uncompetitive industrialists.Footnote 74 Sources of instrumental power were key for the further economic expansion of financial conglomerates, and, ultimately, for the enhancement of their structural power. Their relationships with the Chicago Boys afforded them critical insider information: neoliberal technocrats advised them of policy changes before they were announced to the public.Footnote 75 This access to privileged information allowed the Cruzat-Larraín and Vial conglomerates to expand rapidly.

A factor that further strengthened the radical business coalition was the expansion of its power base when the Edwards group, owner of the highly influential El Mercurio newspaper, joined the radicals. The Edwards group, with its sources of instrumental power (e.g. media access), contributed to the swift, radical restructuring of Chile's economy. In November 1974, for example, El Mercurio published its first editorial advocating rapid privatisation, a reduction in tariffs and drastic deflationary policies.Footnote 76 By early 1975 three powerful conglomerates comprised the core of the radical coalition: Cruzat-Larraín, Vial and Edwards, which were to throw all their weight behind the privatisation of the pension system.

The increasing centralisation of power of the authoritarian regime thus strengthened the radical business coalition. The establishment of one-man rule, without parallel within contemporary Latin American authoritarian regimes,Footnote 77 was pivotal for the neoliberal project.Footnote 78 With such power, Pinochet was to insulate the Chicago Boys from the pressure of those groups in a society negatively affected by the radical economic restructuring.Footnote 79 The opposition of the neoliberal coalition to the corporatist-led reform proposal was ultimately successful: according to the minutes of its secret sessions, after General Díaz's resignation the Junta never discussed the Anteproyecto again.

Third Stage (March 1976–May 1981): Imposition of the Private Pension System

The Outcome

The reform finally implemented in November 1980 (Law no. 3500)Footnote 80 put the management of savings for pensions in the hands of for-profit corporations, which had been a central goal of neoliberal technocrats since the beginning.Footnote 81 The proposal legally mandated each worker to transfer 10 per cent of her/his taxable income to an individual savings account managed by AFPs. The AFPs’ profits were to arise mainly from a fixed commission – established with a flat, regressive structure – charged to every worker. Critically, the reform did not include mechanisms for workers’ participation in the management of their savings. Under the new system, moreover, workers would receive a pension based solely on their savings plus returns (employers would not contribute to retirement accounts). This structure ultimately meant that a growing stream of savings was to be managed by for-profit providers established by financial conglomerates.

During this period, financial business groups dominated the economic elite, having displaced traditional economic groups from the top. This change in the economic elite's balance of power triggered further changes in the composition of the Cabinet, which became firmly dominated by neoliberal technocrats materially connected to the largest financial conglomerates. Accordingly, during this period we observe a highly exclusionary policy process characterised by unmediated access of the economic elite's financial fraction to the centres of policy-making.

Radical Neoliberal Coalition's Further Accumulation of Power, 1976–8

After the application of the shock treatment in 1975, the radical financial coalition continued expanding its economic base and, therefore, its sources of structural power.Footnote 82 By 1978, the Cruzat-Larraín and Vial conglomerates together controlled 48.3 per cent of private banking assets and 26 per cent of the country's external credit, increasing to 52 per cent by 1981.Footnote 83 Also by 1978, these two conglomerates alone controlled more than 37 per cent of the assets of Chile's largest 250 companies.Footnote 84

During this period, additional economic groups joined the radical business coalition. Several traditional conglomerates restructured their business strategies in order to take advantage of the opportunities created by the neoliberal reforms. As we have already seen, Edwards was the first conglomerate to pursue this strategy.Footnote 85 The powerful traditional Matte and Luksic groups followed suit in subsequent years.

As the radical coalition's control of the economy and its sources of structural power grew, their sources of instrumental power also increased. Critically, the radical coalition built closer relationships with policy-makers by, for example, the recruitment into government of more of its members. The paradigmatic case is the appointment of José Piñera as Minister of Labour and Social Security in December 1978. Piñera embodied the direct access of the radical financial coalition to the policy-making process. Before heading the Ministry, he was a top executive of the Cruzat-Larraín conglomerate advocating for the adoption of ODEPLAN's original radical proposal. Working in close collaboration with Cruzat, Piñera waged a campaign for the imposition of private accounts managed by private providers from 1976. The campaign benefited from the support of newspapers controlled by the Edwards conglomerate, which played a crucial role in savaging the pay-as-you-go system (see more on this below) and legitimising radical reform.Footnote 86 Privileged media access was another source of instrumental power greatly strengthened during this period. The Cruzat-Larraín conglomerate, for instance, acquired the influential Ercilla magazine in September 1976.Footnote 87 Piñera regularly wrote op-eds for the magazine, as did Kast.Footnote 88

The Final Road to Privatisation, 1979–81

Notwithstanding their growing clout, neoliberals could not impose their project between 1976 and 1978. According to General Díaz, ‘they [the Chicago Boys] did not dare to touch the reform for two years after I left the ministry’.Footnote 89 The main explanation for the deadlock is Leigh's continuing role in the Junta. The turning point came only in July 1978, when Pinochet removed General Leigh from the Junta, thus giving further impetus to the pension reform.Footnote 90 Leigh was the only member of the military Junta with connections to the segment of internationally uncompetitive industrialists (excluded from both the gradualist and radical coalitions) and his departure made the policy process even more one-sided.Footnote 91

After Leigh's departure the Cabinet became totally dominated by neoliberal technocrats, all members of the radical coalition. Five of the 12 top government positions shown in Figure 1d were held by top executives, employees or board members of the Cruzat-Larraín, Vial and Edwards groups. Five others (Fernández, Juan Carlos Méndez, Sergio de la Cuadra, Kast and Alfonso Serrano) did not have direct employment or business links with conglomerates at the time but were committed neoliberals; the last two (Generals René Vidal and Carlos Jiménez) had close ties to Pinochet.

After Piñera's appointment to the Ministry of Labour in December 1978, he convened a commission charged with detailing the reform.Footnote 92 The commission, chaired by Martín Costabal (a former top executive of the Matte group), began to meet weeklyFootnote 93 and held regular meetings with representatives of the Ministry of Finance.Footnote 94 It worked on actuarial studies and the specific reform design following ODEPLAN's earlier ideas.Footnote 95 Later, in early 1980, Pinochet convened a joint, special legislative commission charged with the single task of discussing the proposal prepared by Piñera's team.Footnote 96

Publicly, the first announcement of the reform came in May 1980. In the May Day commemoration, the government officially declared 1980 ‘the year of social security’.Footnote 97 At that event, both Pinochet and Piñera declared to an audience of 3000 attendees that ‘the old system was totally bankrupt’.Footnote 98 As noted above, the campaign for the neoliberal reform was chiefly based on savaging the pay-as-you-go system, which entailed disseminating inaccurate facts and figures. During our research we gained access to a secret, unpublished report prepared by the Ministry of Finance's Budget Office, which neoliberal technocrats used to support their claims for the alleged bankruptcy of the pay-as-you-go system.Footnote 99 The document constitutes the main historical proof of the blatant, deliberate attempt to discredit the old pay-as-you-go system and to legitimise the radical pension reform promoted by the Chicago Boys.

The argument developed in the secret report lacks scientific rigour. For instance, in computing the overall financial balance of the system, it makes the indefensible assumption that every Chilean worker would automatically switch from the pay-as-you-go scheme to the AFP system once the latter was implemented. This situation would inevitably mean that the pay-as-you-go scheme would instantly have been seriously underfunded. Following this assumption, the authors underestimated the assets of the old system since they did not include the present value of workers’ payroll contributions.

The legislative process slowed for some months while the government concentrated on the constitutional referendum scheduled for September 1980.Footnote 100 Then, Piñera cunningly seized the opportunity offered by the triumphant atmosphere in the aftermath of the referendum to convince Pinochet to discuss the bill in the Junta's secret sessions.Footnote 101 The Junta discussed and passed the reform over two sessions, 14–16 and 24 October.Footnote 102 As mentioned in the introduction above, Pinochet raised his concerns regarding the management of the funds in the opening of the first session: ‘I also agree on the fact that the social security system has to be modified … But at the same time, I have said that I do not agree with the idea that the funds go to the private sector.’Footnote 103 Then, he openly proposed that funds be managed by the state:

Therefore, Minister [Piñera], everything is OK, but when we discuss the issue of the management of the funds, I hesitate. Let me explain: could it be that one of our agencies, a responsible state agency … such as the Central Bank, that such an agency could hold the money and assign it to banks and ‘cajas’, I don't know, I can't work it out at the moment.Footnote 104

Later, he once again made clear his reservations about the role the private sector was to play in the defined-contribution, for-profit system:

I maintain the apprehensions I pointed out before. Why? Because here there are two gentlemen who are trying to grab … I will not name them, but you know perfectly well who they are since Hoy magazine published a report on this … The machinery is so big, but if you remove the nut at the bottom the whole building collapses. The evidence is clear: they have built an empire. Therefore, I have found out … they will be those who will ruin the [pension] system.Footnote 105

According to Carlos Huneeus, ‘the two gentlemen’ whom Pinochet was specifically pointing at in this passage were the heads of the two largest financial conglomerates, Cruzat, Minister Piñera's former boss, and Vial, head of the Vial group.Footnote 106 Pinochet was thus clearly expressing his fears that financial conglomerates could exploit the privatised pension system to their benefit. From information provided by the press, by the Comité Asesor de la Junta (Advisory Committee to the Junta, COAJ) and by military intelligence, Pinochet was very aware of the structure of the financial conglomerates and the way in which they operated.Footnote 107

Pinochet expressed his concerns 14 times during this secret session. Why, then, in the end did he support the radical pension reform? The answer lies to a large extent in the radical coalition's structural power augmented by their instrumental power: as we have seen, by 1980 financial conglomerates controlled vast sectors of Chile's economy, and Pinochet needed their investment in order to foster economic growth and consolidate his rule.

Critically, in the days before the Junta's secret sessions El Mercurio waged a campaign stressing the urgent need to boost investment. Just two days after the constitutional referendum, on 13 September 1980, the conservative daily urged ‘the authorities’ [i.e. Pinochet] in its editorial page to formulate a development programme that would ‘further clarify the rules of the game and propose specific policies in critical aspects for development with stability, with special emphasis on issues not yet resolved, such as the size of the state, the structure of public spending, the improvement of the investment rate … and the extension of property [ownership] to all Chileans’.Footnote 108 El Mercurio called for a reduction in the size of the state and an expansion of the role of the private sector in the economy.

In the same editorial, the newspaper announced ‘the upcoming pension reform’ and its potential effects (even before the Junta had discussed the reform proposal). Under the sub-heading ‘Investment must increase’, El Mercurio insisted that ‘private development in areas such as social security … is, in practice, hindered by the existing quasi-monopoly of the state’. The editorial also advocated for the elimination of employers’ contributions to the social security fund, which was incorporated to the letter in the reform approved by Pinochet: ‘Social security tax still exists and it seems essential to eliminate it completely in the coming years.’

As the discussion of the reform in the Junta drew nearer, pressure became even more explicit. For example, on 28 September 1980, under the sub-heading ‘Progress that Cannot be Delayed’, El Mercurio's editorial stated: ‘It is inevitable that the Government must keep moving forward relentlessly to implement the programme it has formulated.’ The editorial then listed the ‘modernisations’ proposed by the Chilean government, which were intended to ‘liberalise’ individuals and society. The first was the Plan Laboral of 1979, which, among other things, restricted the right to strike.Footnote 109 ‘The second modernisation … is the reform to social security and, specifically, to the old-age pension system.’Footnote 110 Stridently, under the sub-heading ‘The Importance of the Pension Reform’, the newspaper continued to stress the topic by asserting: ‘The reform means a mandatory allocation of substantial funds to productive investment.’ This campaign thus represents a textbook case of structural power augmented by instrumental power:Footnote 111 the country's most influential newspaper, controlled by the radical financial coalition, used its editorial pages, the ones which set the daily political agenda at that time, to stress time and again the urgent need for pension privatisation.

In October discussion in the Junta became fraught with military mistrust, on the one hand, and the Chicago Boys’ insistence on the alleged benefits of the reform, on the other. Piñera's attempts to convince a mistrustful military leadership were carefully framed. On the second day of the first secret session, held on 16 October 1980, he highlighted the importance of creating workers committed to private ownership:

By having an individual account and seeing that his savings rise, which depends on how the economy is doing, the worker will necessarily be interested in having an efficient and responsible Minister of Finance, in having Parliaments that are not so committed to partisan politicking, and in avoiding violent revolutions, because he will become a property owner with a direct interest in the general performance of the economy. In this way, there will be fewer strikes.Footnote 112

The few high-ranking officers that still defended the corporatist agenda then raised additional concerns. For instance, Major Juan Romero, Head of Legislation for the COAJ, objected that the alleged bankruptcy of the old system reported by Piñera was based on dubious accounting criteria.Footnote 113 Yet most members of the Junta readily bought in to Piñera's overstated arguments; their intimidation at the hands of the Chicago Boys when they tried to inquire about further details is apparent in the minutes.Footnote 114 Piñera grossly misled the Junta during the debate. For example, he said: ‘I want to emphasise what I have said before: the change … will mean zero cost to the state.’Footnote 115 The statement soon proved inaccurate: the state had to continue paying pensions to retirees of the old system but simultaneously received far lower contributions from active workers, as the number of affiliates decreased from ca. 1.7 million in 1980 to just below 450,000 by 1984.Footnote 116 Alberto Arenas reports that the reform caused a total budget deficit of 5.7 per cent of GDP from 1981 to 1998, more than doubling the deficit for the 1974–80 period.Footnote 117

The reform was finally approved in early November 1980. The subsequent implementation stage of the policy-making process offers a further example of the power of the business elite. Their unmediated access to policy-making provided financial conglomerates with privileged information even before the final approval. Hoy magazine reported that from 15 October to 4 November 1980, Chile's government gazette published the registration of 57 original trademarks that might be used for the new AFPs.Footnote 118 These names were registered before the new pension system was announced to the public on 6 November 1980.

The launch of the AFP system was a success. Most of the economically active population moved to the new system during the first six months.Footnote 119 The most powerful financial groups became key actors in the new system. Of the 11 AFPs initially created,Footnote 120 the Cruzat-Larraín conglomerate controlled two (ProVida and Alameda), the Vial Group another two (Santa María and San Cristóbal), and the Edwards conglomerate controlled El Libertador. Those traditional groups which had successfully adapted to the changing environment in the previous three years also benefited: the Luksic, Matte and Angelini conglomerates created Summa AFP, and the Yarur-Banna and Said conglomerates joined together to create PlanVital. The Cámara Chilena de la Construcción (Chilean Chamber of Construction, CChC), in turn, created Habitat AFP. In summary, ten out of 11 corporations were owned either by conglomerates or by big business interests.

Furthermore, the cosy relationship between radical conglomerates and the Chicago Boys was reflected in the structure of the boards. For instance, the chairman of Provida was Cauas, former Minister of Finance, and Alfonso Márquez de la Plata, former Minister of Agriculture, was a member of the board. Invierta counted Álvaro Bardón, former President of the Central Bank, as board chairman. The renown of these economists – along with the prestige of the conglomerates behind the AFPs – were presented as the guarantee of the efficiency, success and ‘modernity’ of the system.

Conclusions

This paper has illustrated the suitability of the instrumental–structural framework for the analysis of business power under authoritarian regimes. By adapting the instrumental–structural framework to non-democratic settings, we show that these categories are useful to account for the economic elite's progressive accumulation of power in authoritarian Chile. More specifically, the financial segment progressively accumulated sources of power until it was able to secure its goal of privatising the old-age pension system.

Multiple sources of power enabled financial conglomerates to defeat their opponents, while its state allies simultaneously gained more influence. The unmediated, privileged interaction between the state and the financial fraction of the economic elite gradually increased, reaching its zenith between 1979 and 1981, when neoliberal civilians dominated the Cabinet. This resulted in the creation of the new pension scheme based on individual accounts managed by for-profit companies controlled by the financial conglomerates. Even General Augusto Pinochet – arguably the most powerful dictator in Latin America during the 1960s and 1970s – ended up accepting a reform that he did not particularly like.

In addition to the contributions that we make in this work to an understanding of business power in non-democratic contexts, we offer a more nuanced view than does previous literature: the state is not a transmission belt of business interests, nor is it completely autonomous. Policy-making in authoritarian regimes, then, results from a complex interplay between dynamics within both the state and the economic elite. These dynamics, in turn, are influenced by the power resources wielded by each actor.

Overall, in rethinking the policy-making process in authoritarian contexts we make a broader contribution to the literature on the political economy of business–state relations in Latin America and beyond. We have shown that – important as it is – the study of the regime's structure is not enough for the formulation of an accurate picture of social policy reform in authoritarian contexts in general and Pinochet's Chile in particular. Likewise, factors that have previously occupied a central role in explaining outcomes – such as the ideological position of policy-makers – fall short of providing a sound explanation. Instead, we stress the need to include in the analysis the power resources of the different actors involved in the policy process, and the study of their material interests and relations. Given its centrality in shaping public policies in unequal contexts, Latin Americanists and other scholars of the global South should pay special attention to the role played by economic elites and their different fractions, in both the past and the future.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022216X24000476.

Acknowledgements

Firstly, we wish to acknowledge the unflagging research assistance of Sebastián Guiñez, Julio Vera and Paula Azócar. We would also like to thank Alan Angell, Marek Naczyk, Kirsten Sehnbruch, three anonymous reviewers and the editor for their suggestions and comments. Finally, we gratefully thank Virginia Catmur for her thorough, exhaustive editing of our manuscript. This work was partially funded by the Agencia Nacional de Investigación y Desarrollo (National Agency for Research and Development, ANID) scholarship programme ‘Doctorado en el Extranjero Becas Chile 2015’, grant no. 72160280.

References

1 Secretaría de la Junta, ‘Acta No. 398-A’, 14 Oct. 1980, Actas Secretas de la Junta de Gobierno, Biblioteca del Congreso Nacional (hereafter ASJG), p. 3. Online at https://obtienearchivo.bcn.cl/obtienearchivo?id=recursoslegales/10221.3/34262/1/acta398_1980_A.pdf (all URLs last accessed 4 July 2024).

2 Ibid., p. 9.

3 In contrast to defined-contribution pension systems based on individual capitalisation accounts managed by for-profit providers, pay-as-you-go systems are state-managed, defined-benefit pension schemes funded by contributions from current workers to pay retirees’ pensions.

4 Huneeus, Carlos, The Pinochet Regime (Boulder, CO and London: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Silva, Eduardo, The State and Capital in Chile: Business Elites, Technocrats, and Market Economics (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1996)Google Scholar; Foxley, Alejandro, Latin American Experiments in Neoconservative Economics (Berkeley, CA and London: University of California Press, 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 Castiglioni, Rossana, The Politics of Social Policy Change in Chile and Uruguay: Retrenchment versus Maintenance, 1973–1998 (New York and London: Routledge, 2005)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Silvia Borzutzky, ‘Chilean Politics and Social Security Policies’, unpubl. PhD diss., University of Pittsburgh, 1983; Borzutzky, Silvia, Vital Connections: Politics, Social Security, and Inequality in Chile (Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press, 2002)Google Scholar; Castiglioni, Rossana, ‘Explaining Uneven Social Policy Expansion in Democratic Chile’, Latin American Politics and Society, 60: 3 (2018), pp. 5476CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Borzutzky, Silvia, ‘You Win Some, You Lose Some: Pension Reform in Bachelet's First and Second Administrations’, Journal of Politics in Latin America, 11: 2 (2019), pp. 204–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Castiglioni, Rossana, ‘The Politics of Retrenchment: The Quandaries of Social Protection under Military Rule in Chile, 1973–1990’, Latin American Politics and Society, 43: 4 (2001), pp. 3766Google ScholarPubMed.

6 Lindblom, Charles E., Politics and Markets: The World's Political–Economic Systems (New York: Basic Books, 1977)Google Scholar; Lindblom, Charles E., ‘The Market as Prison’, The Journal of Politics, 44: 2 (1982), pp. 324–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 See for example: Schiappacasse, Ignacio, ‘Business Power in Post-Authoritarian Chile: Explaining Regulatory Continuity in the Pension System, 1990–1994’, Revista Española de Sociología, 29: 3 (2020), pp. 503–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Broockman, David, ‘The “Problem of Preferences”: Medicare and Business Support for the Welfare State’, Studies in American Political Development, 26: 2 (2012), pp. 83106CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Schiappacasse, Ignacio, ‘Continuidad del sistema de AFP en democracia: el rol del poder de la elite económica’, Revista Chilena de Derecho y Ciencia Política, 12: 1 (2021), pp. 104–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bril-Mascarenhas, Tomás and Maillet, Antoine, ‘How to Build and Wield Business Power: The Political Economy of Pension Regulation in Chile, 1990–2018’, Latin American Politics and Society, 61: 1 (2019), pp. 101–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 Orenstein, Mitchell A., Privatizing Pensions: The Transnational Campaign for Social Security Reform (Princeton, NJ and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2008)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Brooks, Sarah M., ‘Globalization and Pension Reform in Latin America’, Latin American Politics and Society, 49: 4 (2007), pp. 3162CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 David Collier, ‘Overview of the Bureaucratic–Authoritarian Model’, in David Collier (ed.), The New Authoritarianism in Latin America (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1979), pp. 19–32; David Collier, ‘Introduction’, in Collier (ed.), The New Authoritarianism in Latin America, pp. 3–16.

10 Fernando Henrique Cardoso and Enzo Faletto, Dependency and Development in Latin America (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1979).

11 E.g. Juan J. Linz, ‘Totalitarian and Authoritarian Regimes’, in Fred I. Greenstein and Nelson W. Polsby (eds.), Handbook of Political Science, vol. 5: Government Institutions and Processes (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, 1975), pp. 175–411; Juan J. Linz, Totalitarian and Authoritarian Regimes (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2000).

12 Ben Ross Schneider, ‘Elusive Synergy: Business–Government Relations and Development’, Comparative Politics, 31: 1 (1998), pp. 101–22.

13 Andrés Velasco, ‘The State and Economic Policy: Chile 1952–92’, in Barry P. Bosworth, Rudiger Dornbusch and Raúl Labán (eds.), The Chilean Economy: Policy Lessons and Challenges (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1994), pp. 379–411.

14 Jeffry A. Frieden, Debt, Development, and Democracy: Modern Political Economy and Latin America, 1965–1985 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1991).

15 Castiglioni, ‘The Politics of Retrenchment’; Castiglioni, The Politics of Social Policy Change.

16 The so-called ‘Chicago Boys’ were a group of Chilean economists, the majority of whom obtained their undergraduate degrees in economics at the Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile, and subsequently achieved their graduate degrees at the Department of Economics of the University of Chicago, under the instruction of Milton Friedman and Arnold Harberger. Borzutzky, ‘Chilean Politics and Social Security Policies’; Borzutzky, Vital Connections; Borzutzky, ‘You Win Some, You Lose Some’; Raúl L. Madrid, Retiring the State: The Politics of Pension Privatization in Latin America and Beyond (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2003); Castiglioni, ‘Explaining Uneven Social Policy Expansion’.

17 Silva, The State and Capital in Chile.

18 Tasha Fairfield, Private Wealth and Public Revenue in Latin America: Business Power and Tax Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2015); Tasha Fairfield and Candelaria Garay, ‘Redistribution under the Right in Latin America: Electoral Competition and Organized Actors in Policymaking’, Comparative Political Studies, 50: 14 (2017), pp. 1871–1906; Tomás Bril-Mascarenhas and Aldo Madariaga, ‘Business Power and the Minimal State: The Defeat of Industrial Policy in Chile’, Journal of Development Studies, 55: 6 (2019), pp. 1047–66; Schiappacasse, ‘Business Power in Post-Authoritarian Chile’; Bril-Mascarenhas and Maillet, ‘How to Build and Wield Business Power’.

19 Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson, ‘Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State’, Politics and Society, 30: 2 (2002), pp. 277–325.

20 Ralph Miliband, The State in Capitalist Society (London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1969); C. Wright Mills, The Power Elite (Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press, 1956).

21 Fred Block, ‘The Ruling Class does not Rule: Notes on the Marxist Theory of the State’, Socialist Revolution, 7: 3 (May–June 1977), pp. 6–28; Lindblom, Politics and Markets.

22 Tasha Fairfield, ‘Structural Power in Comparative Political Economy: Perspectives from Policy Formulation in Latin America’, Business and Politics, 17: 3 (2015), pp. 411–41.

23 Jeffrey A. Winters, Power in Motion: Capital Mobility and the Indonesian State (Ithaca, NY and London: Cornell University Press, 1996).

24 Marek Naczyk, ‘Agents of Privatization? Business Groups and the Rise of Pension Funds in Continental Europe’, Socio-Economic Review, 11: 3 (2013), pp. 441–69; Marek Naczyk, ‘Creating French-Style Pension Funds: Business, Labour and the Battle over Patient Capital’, Journal of European Social Policy, 26: 3 (2016), pp. 205–18.

25 For a complete and detailed study of businesses’ sources of power and their observable implications in democratic contexts see Fairfield, Private Wealth and Public Revenue in Latin America, pp. 27–52.

26 Winters, Power in Motion; Pepper D. Culpepper, ‘Structural Power and Political Science in the Post-Crisis Era’, Business and Politics, 17: 3 (2015), pp. 391–409.

27 Centro de Estudios Públicos (CEP), ‘El Ladrillo’: bases de la política económica del gobierno militar chileno, ed. by Sergio de Castro and Juan Carlos Méndez (Santiago: CEP, 1992). See also Juan Gabriel Valdés, Pinochet's Economists: The Chicago School in Chile (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); Arturo Fontaine Aldunate, Los economistas y el presidente Pinochet (Santiago: Zig-Zag, 1988); Silva, The State and Capital in Chile.

28 Silva, The State and Capital in Chile.

29 Jeff Frieden, ‘Classes, Sectors, and Foreign Debt in Latin America’, Comparative Politics, 21: 1 (1988), pp. 1–20.

30 Eduardo Silva, ‘From Dictatorship to Democracy: The Business–State Nexus in Chile's Economic Transformation, 1975–1994’, Comparative Politics, 28: 3 (1996), pp. 299–320; Silva, The State and Capital in Chile.

31 Pilar Vergara, Auge y caída del neoliberalismo en Chile: un estudio sobre la evolución ideológica del régimen militar (Santiago: FLACSO, 1984).

32 See further below and Eduardo Silva, ‘Capitalist Coalitions, the State, and Neoliberal Economic Restructuring: Chile, 1973–88’, World Politics, 45: 4 (1993), pp. 526–59.

33 Mónica González, La conjura: los mil y un días del golpe (Santiago: UDP/Catalonia, 2012).

34 Vergara, Auge y caída del neoliberalismo en Chile; Verónica Valdivia, El golpe después del golpe: Leigh vs. Pinochet. Chile 1960–1980 (Santiago: LOM, 2003).

35 Philip J. O'Brien and Jacqueline Roddick, The Pinochet Decade (London: Latin American Bureau, 1983); Fontaine Aldunate, Los economistas y el presidente Pinochet.

36 Valdés, Pinochet's Economists; Fontaine Aldunate, Los economistas y el presidente Pinochet.

37 Silva, ‘Capitalist Coalitions’.

38 Philip O'Brien, ‘The New Leviathan: The Chicago School and the Chilean Regime 1973–80’, IDS Bulletin, 13: 1 (1981), pp. 38–50; ‘Reportaje: Los Chicago Boys’, Qué Pasa, 29 May 1975, pp. 32–7; Víctor Herrero, Agustín Edwards Eastman: una biografía desclasificada del dueño de El Mercurio (Santiago: Debate, 2014).

39 Fernando Dahse, El poder de los grandes grupos económicos nacionales (Santiago: FLACSO, 1983); Silva, ‘Capitalist Coalitions’. Subsequently, the BHC conglomerate became known as the Vial conglomerate, named after its main shareholder Javier Vial.

40 Castiglioni, The Politics of Social Policy Change; Borzutzky, Vital Connections.

41 Fontaine Aldunate, Los economistas y el presidente Pinochet.

42 Huneeus, The Pinochet Regime.

43 CEP, ‘El Ladrillo’, p. 130.

44 Valdivia, El golpe después del golpe; Vergara, Auge y caída del neoliberalismo en Chile.

45 O'Brien, ‘The New Leviathan’.

46 Guillermo Campero, ‘Entrepreneurs under the Military Regime’, in Paul W. Drake and Iván Jaksić (eds.), The Struggle for Democracy in Chile, 1982–1990 (Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska Press, 1991), pp. 128–60; Michael Albertus and Victor Menaldo, Authoritarianism and the Elite Origins of Democracy (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 2018).

47 Ministerio del Trabajo, Anteproyecto del estatuto fundamental de principios y bases del sistema de seguridad social (Santiago: Editorial Universitaria y Ministerio del Trabajo, 1975).

48 Carlos Huneeus, ‘Technocrats and Politicians in an Authoritarian Regime. The “ODEPLAN Boys” and the “Gremialists” in Pinochet's Chile’, Journal of Latin American Studies, 32: 2 (2000), pp. 461–501.

49 Ministerio del Trabajo, Anteproyecto.

50 Borzutzky, ‘Chilean Politics and Social Security Policies’.

51 Patricia Arancibia Clavel, Conversando con Roberto Kelly V.: recuerdos de una vida (Santiago: Editorial Biblioteca Americana, 2005); Patricia Arancibia Clavel, Chile: un milagro. Roberto Kelly, un padre fundador (Santiago: Self-published, 2013).

52 Kast's report is lost, but it is referred to by Patricia Arancibia Clavel and Francisco Balart Páez, Sergio de Castro: el arquitecto del modelo económico chileno (Santiago: Editorial Biblioteca Americana, 2007), pp. 323–4 and Heraldo Muñoz, The Dictador's Shadow: Life under Augusto Pinochet – A Political Memoir (New York: Basic Books, 2008), p. 80. See also Ignacio Schiappacasse and Carlos Tromben, ‘Más allá de José Piñera: los verdaderos padres del actual sistema de pensiones chileno’, Interferencia (Santiago), 8 Aug. 2020, https://interferencia.cl/articulos/mas-alla-de-jose-pinera-los-verdaderos-padres-del-actual-sistema-de-pensiones-chileno.

53 Miguel Kast, ‘La previsión y el mercado del trabajo’; ‘El sector previsional como inversionista institucional en el mercado de capitales’, in H. Burdiles (ed.), El pensamiento de Miguel Kast en perspectiva (Santiago: Fundación Miguel Kast, 2006 [1976]), pp. 138–41; 95–105; authors’ interview with minister who served the dictatorship during the 1970s, 11 Oct. 2017.

54 Fontaine Aldunate, Los economistas y el presidente Pinochet.

55 Gonzalo Vial, Pinochet: la biografía, vol. 1 (Santiago: El Mercurio-Aguilar, 2002), p. 274.

56 ‘Previsión II: razones para el debate’, Hoy, 22 Oct. 1980, pp. 31–2.

57 Secretaría de la Junta, ‘Acta No. 163-A’, 23 Oct. 1974, ASJG, p. 40.

58 ‘Anteproyecto: de la previsión a la seguridad social’, Ercilla, 19 Nov. 1975, pp. 13–17; Emilio Filippi, ‘Análisis: inquietudes frente al cambio’, Ercilla, 26 Nov. 1975, p. 11; Secretaría de la Junta, ‘Acta No. 215-A’, 22 July 1975, ASJG; Ministerio del Trabajo, Anteproyecto.

59 ‘Estatuto fundamental de principios y bases del sistema de seguridad social’, El Mercurio, 8 Nov. 1975, pp. 1, 34; Borzutzky, ‘Chilean Politics and Social Security Policies’; Ministerio del Trabajo, Anteproyecto; ‘Anteproyecto: de la previsión a la seguridad social’.

60 The report has been lost. However, it is mentioned in ‘Entrevista a Alfonso Serrano’, Ercilla, 1 Dec. 1976, p. 23.

61 The gremialista movement was a conservative, right-wing political movement born in the Pontificia Universidad Católica during the late 1960s. It is the predecessor of the Unión Demócrata Independiente (UDI), the political party that has defended the dictatorship's legacy since 1990. The gremialista movement was closely allied with the Chicago Boys during the dictatorship. Kast constituted the main bridge between these two elite groups: he had joined the gremialista movement during his undergraduate years at the Universidad Católica and was also a former postgraduate student of the University of Chicago. See Huneeus, ‘Technocrats and Politicians’. See also Ascanio Cavallo, Manuel Salazar and Óscar Sepúlveda, La historia oculta del régimen militar (Santiago: La Época, 1988), p. 85; Sergio Fernández, Mi lucha por la democracia (Santiago: Los Andes, 1994); authors’ interview with minister who served the dictatorship during the 1970s, 11 Oct. 2017.

62 Fontaine Aldunate, Los economistas y el presidente Pinochet.

63 Silva, ‘From Dictatorship to Democracy’; Silva, The State and Capital in Chile; Silva, ‘Capitalist Coalitions’.

64 Fernando Dahse, El mapa de la extrema riqueza: los grupos económicos y el proceso de concentración de capitales (Santiago: Aconcagua, 1979).

65 The Partido Demócrata Cristiano (also known as Democracia Cristiana, DC) supported the coup against Allende, and some of its most prominent members initially participated in the dictatorship (see Figure 1). Later, however, this political party withdrew its support and ended its participation in the government in protest against the systematic human rights violations committed by the military regime. See Carlos Tromben and Ignacio Schiappacasse, Todo legal: Los grandes zarpazos de la elite financiera chilena (1973–2021) (Santiago: Editorial Planeta, 2022), pp. 28, 49–50.

66 He had originally taken over the Ministry of Finance in July 1974.

67 John R. Bawden, The Pinochet Generation: The Chilean Military in the Twentieth Century (Tuscaloosa, AL: University of Alabama Press, 2016).

68 Alan Angell, ‘Chile since 1958’, in Leslie Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin America, vol. 8: Latin America since 1930: Spanish South America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 311–82.

69 Karen Remmer, ‘Political Demobilization in Chile, 1973–1978’, Comparative Politics, 12: 3 (1980), pp. 275–301.

70 Valdivia, El golpe después del golpe.

71 Silva, The State and Capital in Chile.

72 O'Brien and Roddick, The Pinochet Decade.

73 Valdivia, El golpe después del golpe.

74 Silva, The State and Capital in Chile.

75 Silva, ‘Capitalist Coalitions’.

76 O'Brien and Roddick, The Pinochet Decade, p. 4.

77 Robert Barros, Constitutionalism and Dictatorship: Pinochet, the Junta, and the 1980 Constitution (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 2002).

78 Castiglioni, The Politics of Social Policy Change; Karen L. Remmer, ‘State Change in Chile, 1973–1988’, Studies in Comparative International Development, 24: 3 (1989), pp. 5–29.

79 Guillermo Campero, Los gremios empresariales en el período 1970–1983: comportamiento sociopolítico y orientaciones ideológicas (Santiago: Instituto Latinoamericano de Estudios Transnacionales, 1984); Karen L. Remmer, ‘Public Policy and Regime Consolidation: The First Five Years of the Chilean Junta’, The Journal of Developing Areas, 13: 4 (1979), pp. 441–61.

80 Secretaría de Legislación, Historia de la ley: decreto de ley 3.500, 2 vols. (Santiago: Junta de Gobierno, 1980). As these volumes are not easily accessible, we provide them as Supplementary Materials to this article.

81 Authors’ interview with advisor at ODEPLAN 1979–80, 24 May 2017.

82 Foxley, Latin American Experiments; Alejandro Foxley, ‘The Neoconservative Economic Experiment in Chile’, in J. Samuel Valenzuela and Arturo Valenzuela (eds.), Military Rule in Chile: Dictatorship and Oppositions (Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1986), pp. 13–49.

83 Conversely, over the same period the state went from controlling 23.4 per cent of the external credit in 1978 to just 6.3 per cent in 1981. Dahse, Mapa de la extrema riqueza, pp. 154–6; Dahse, El poder de los grandes grupos económicos, p. 54.

84 Dahse, El poder de los grandes grupos económicos, p. 50.

85 Silva, The State and Capital in Chile, pp. 97–102.

86 Herrero, Agustín Edwards Eastman. Besides El Mercurio, the Edwards group controlled (and still controls) the evening newspaper La Segunda, and the more popular Las Últimas Noticias.

87 Human Rights Watch, The Limits of Tolerance: Freedom of Expression and the Public Debate in Chile (New York and London: Human Rights Watch, 1998). Until then, Ercilla had been a popular and influential magazine which opposed Pinochet's dictatorship.

88 For example: José Piñera, ‘A paso ligero’, Ercilla, 21 Dec. 1977, p. 20; ‘Ahora o nunca’, Ercilla, 29 March 1978, p. 25; Miguel Kast, ‘El empleo: un derecho por adquirir’, Ercilla, 26 April 1978, p. 16.

89 ‘Entrevista al general Nicanor Díaz Estrada’, in Sergio Marras (ed.), Confesiones: entrevistas con Sergio Marras (Santiago: Ornitorrinco, 1988), pp. 95–119.

90 Huneeus, The Pinochet Regime, pp. 88, 198; Arancibia Clavel and Balart Páez, Sergio de Castro, p. 306.

91 Campero, ‘Entrepreneurs under the Military Regime’; Florencia Varas, Gustavo Leigh: el general disidente (Santiago: Aconcagua, 1979), p. 34.

92 Authors’ interview with advisor to the Minister of the Economy 1974–9, 31 May 2017; interview with Member #1 of the Technical Committee of the 1980 Pension Reform, 4 July 2017.

93 Ignacio Bazán and Francisco Artaza, ‘Regreso al origen de las AFP’, La Tercera, 31 July 2016, Sección Reportajes, pp. 10–12.

94 Arancibia Clavel and Balart Páez, Sergio de Castro, pp. 324–5.

95 Authors’ interview with Member #2 of the Technical Committee of the 1980 Pension Reform, 30 May 2017.

96 Secretaría de Legislación, Historia de la ley.

97 ‘El año de la previsión’, Hoy, 7 May 1980, p. 10.

98 Ibid.

99 Dirección de Presupuestos, El antiguo sistema previsional: cómo era y a dónde iba (Santiago: Ministerio de Hacienda, 1980).

100 Secretaría de Legislación, Historia de la ley, vol 1.

101 José Piñera, El cascabel al gato: la batalla por la Reforma Previsional (Santiago: Zig-Zag, 1991).

102 Secretaría de la Junta, ‘Acta No. 398-A’, p. 175 and ‘Acta No. 399-A’, 24 Oct. 1980, ASJG, p. 41. Online at https://obtienearchivo.bcn.cl/obtienearchivo?id=recursoslegales/10221.3/34704/1/acta399_1980_A.pdf.

103 Secretaría de la Junta, ‘Acta No. 398-A’, p. 3.

104 Ibid. ‘Cajas’ is a reference to the ‘cajas previsionales’, the 32 pension funds – in bankruptcy, according to the Chicago Boys – that made up the old pay-as-you-go system.

105 Secretaría de la Junta, ‘Acta No. 398-A’, p. 45.

106 Huneeus, The Pinochet Regime, p. 349.

107 Ibid.

108 ‘Temas económicos: la futura marcha de la economía’, El Mercurio, 13 Sept. 1980, p. A3.

109 The Plan Laboral comprised eight laws passed between 1978 and 1979. See Vallejos, Rolando Álvarez, ‘El Plan Laboral y la negociación colectiva: ¿origen de un nuevo sindicalismo en Chile? 1979–1985’, Boletín del Instituto de Historia Argentina y Americana ‘Dr. Emilio Ravignani’, 3: 35/36 (2011–12), pp. 92115.Google Scholar

110 ‘La semana política’, El Mercurio, 28 Sept. 1980, p. A3.

111 See Fairfield, ‘Structural Power in Comparative Political Economy’.

112 Secretaría de la Junta, ‘Acta No. 398-A’, p. 97.

113 Ibid., p. 110.

114 Ibid., pp. 35–7, 47, 77, 94.

115 Secretaría de la Junta, ‘Acta No. 399-A’, p. 22.

116 José Pablo Arellano, Políticas sociales y desarrollo: Chile 1924–1984 (Santiago: CIEPLAN, 1985).

117 Alberto Arenas, ‘El sistema de pensiones en Chile: principales resultados y desafíos pendientes’, in Encuentro latinoamericano y caribeño sobre las personas de edad: seminario técnico (Santiago: CEPAL, 2000), pp. 465–502.

118 ‘Previsión: ya viene la reforma’, Hoy, 22 Oct. 1980, pp. 30–2; ‘Previsión: en la puerta del horno’, Hoy, 5 Nov. 1980, pp. 19–20. Among the names registered were ‘Trust de Previsión Privada’ and ‘Corporación Previsional de Profesionales de Chile’.

119 Arellano, Políticas sociales y desarrollo.

120 ‘Las once de la “competencia”’, Análisis, June 1981, pp. 10–12.

Figure 0

Table 1. Main Descriptive Aspects of Instrumental and Structural Power

Figure 1

Table 2. Major Conglomerates in 1970 and Concentration of Companies by Economic Activity

Figure 2

Figure 1. Evolution of the Composition of the Cabinet, 1973–81Notes: Boxes shaded in grey indicate members of the Chicago Boys’ network.DC Member of Democracia CristianaM Minister/MinistryP PresidentSEGEGOB Secretaría General de GobiernoVP Vice-presidentSource: Authors’ elaboration based on Fontaine Aldunate, Los economistas y el presidente Pinochet; ‘Boris Blanco: la caída del superintendente’, Hoy, 15 March 1984, pp. 24–9; ‘Falleció ex canciller Hernán Cubillos’, El Mercurio, 11 April 2001, p. C1; Empresa Periodística de Chile, Diccionario Biográfico de Chile, 1984–1986, 18th edn (Santiago: Empresa Periodística de Chile, 1986); ‘Previsión: el debut de las AFP’, Hoy, 13 May 1981, pp. 30–3; ‘Quién es y cómo es Javier Vial, y el baile de los pesos’, Hoy, 26 Aug. 1981, pp. 22–6; ‘Quién es y cómo es Manuel Cruzat, el millonario invisible’, Hoy, 16 Sept. 1981, pp. 19–22; María Olivia Mönckeberg, El saqueo de los grupos económicos al Estado chileno (Santiago: Ediciones B, 2001); ‘Las once de la “competencia”’; ‘COPEC: los rostros nuevos’, Hoy, 24 June 1981, p. 43.* Humberto Pizarro was an ‘outsider’: neither an economist nor a graduate of the Pontificia Universidad Católica.

Supplementary material: File

Schiappacasse and Sánchez-Ancochea supplementary material 1

Schiappacasse and Sánchez-Ancochea supplementary material
Download Schiappacasse and Sánchez-Ancochea supplementary material 1(File)
File 25.1 MB
Supplementary material: File

Schiappacasse and Sánchez-Ancochea supplementary material 2

Schiappacasse and Sánchez-Ancochea supplementary material
Download Schiappacasse and Sánchez-Ancochea supplementary material 2(File)
File 23.5 MB