Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T20:41:23.780Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The credit-augmented Divisia aggregates and the monetary business cycle

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 March 2024

Apostolos Serletis*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Calgary, Calgary, AB, Canada
Libo Xu
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Lakehead University, Thunder Bay, ON, Canada
*
Corresponding author: Apostolos Serletis; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We follow Belongia and Ireland (2021) and investigate the role that the Center for Financial Stability credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates could play in monetary policy and business cycle analysis. We use Bayesian methods to estimate a structural VAR under priors that reflect Keynesian channels of monetary transmission, but produce posterior distributions for the structural parameters consistent with classical channels. We also find that valuable information is contained in the credit-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates and that they perform even better than the conventional Divisia aggregates, in terms of highlighting the role of the money supply in aggregate demand.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

The current approach to monetary policy and business cycle analysis is based on the New Keynesian model. It is expressed through the central bank’s manipulation of the interest rate on overnight loans between banks, such as the federal funds rate in the United States, and ignores variations in the quantity of money. In this regard, recently Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021, pp. 362) argue that “focusing entirely on interest rates and excluding measures of money, the strict New Keynesian model provides an overly narrow view of channels through which monetary policy affects the economy.”

The question then that arises is whether there is a useful role of monetary aggregates in monetary policy and business cycle analysis. In answering this question, as McCallum and Nelson (Reference McCallum and Nelson2011, p. 138) put it, “one should note that the shift toward analyses that ignore or downplay money largely reflects a change in empirical judgments. In the era in which monetary aggregates were used as guides to policy, policymakers expressed the view that—although monetary policy actions did work on spending via interest rates, and the authorities did typically employ a short-term nominal interest rate as their policy instrument—it was a more straightforward matter to establish money/inflation relations than it was to establish connections between policy-rate actions and subsequent inflation movements.”

Over the years, a large number of publications have shown that most of the puzzles and paradoxes in monetary economics are resolved by use of aggregation theoretic monetary aggregates, such as Barnett’s (Reference Barnett1980) Divisia monetary aggregates. See, for example, the journal articles reprinted in Barnett and Serletis (Reference Barnett and Serletis2000), Barnett and Chauvet (Reference Barnett and Chauvet2011), Schunk (Reference Schunk2001), Serletis (Reference Serletis2009), Serletis and Rahman (Reference Serletis and Rahman2013), Serletis and Gogas (Reference Serletis and Gogas2014), Hendrickson (Reference Hendrickson2014), Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2014, Reference Belongia and Ireland2015, Reference Belongia and Ireland2016, Reference Belongia and Ireland2018), Ellington (Reference Ellington2018), and Dery and Serletis (Reference Dery and Serletis2019), among others. In fact, Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2015, p. 268) again “call into question the conventional view that the stance of monetary policy can be described with exclusive reference to its effects on interest rates and without consideration of simultaneous movements in the monetary aggregates.” They argue that properly measured monetary aggregates, such as the new Center for Financial Stability (CFS) Divisia monetary aggregates (available since 1967), can and should play an important role (either as intermediate targets or indicator variables) for the conduct of monetary policy, in addition to that of the short-term nominal interest rate.

The original CFS Divisia monetary aggregates do not include the transaction services provided by credit cards. However, as noted by Liu et al. (Reference Liu, Dery and Serletis2020), the volume of credit card transaction services has more than doubled in recent years and over 80% of American households with credit cards are currently borrowing and paying interest on credit cards. Motivated by these developments in the financial services industry, Barnett et al. (Reference Barnett, Chauvet, Leiva-Leon and Su2023) and Barnett and Su (Reference Barnett and Su2016, Reference Barnett and Su2018, Reference Barnett and Su2019) derive Divisia monetary aggregates that jointly aggregate the services provided by credit cards and the services provided by monetary assets. The new aggregates are known as the credit card-augmented Divisia and credit card-augmented Divisia inside monetary aggregates. Data on these aggregates are also available from the CFS, but these series start in July 2006.

Regarding the (relatively new) credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates, many recent papers have found that they perform well relative to the conventional (original) Divisia monetary aggregates. For example, Barnett et al. (Reference Barnett, Chauvet, Leiva-Leon and Su2023), in the context of a multivariate state space model, find that nowcasting with credit card-augmented Divisia aggregates yields substantially smaller mean squared error than with the conventional Divisia aggregates. Liu et al. (Reference Liu, Dery and Serletis2020) find that both the narrow and broad credit card-augmented Divisia aggregates are superior to the conventional Divisia aggregates, and that broad Divisia monetary aggregates provide better measures of the flow of monetary services generated in the economy. In this regard, Liu and Serletis (Reference Liu and Serletis2020) also find that the volatility of the credit card-augmented (broad) Divisia M4 monetary aggregate has a statistically significant negative impact on output whereas there is no effect of the conventional Divisia M4 growth volatility on output. More recently, Barnett and Park (Reference Barnett and Park2023a), by using an autoregressive distributed lag model and Bayesian VAR, find that credit-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates are the better indicators for forecasting inflation and output. Also, Barnett and Park (Reference Barnett and Park2023b), in the context of a sign-restricted Bayesian VAR, find that considering credit-related variables and shocks helps to interpret recent economic phenomena, with the credit card-augmented Divisia aggregates being especially informative.

Clearly, despite the well-established literature on the conventional Divisia monetary aggregates, the credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates are mostly unexplored. In this paper, we follow Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) and, in the context of a five-variable structural VAR for inflation, the output gap, the short-term nominal interest rate, money balances, and the user cost of money, investigate whether there is a role of the CFS credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates in the monetary business cycle. As in Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021), we allow classical channels of monetary transmission to operate alongside the New Keynesian interest rate channel and estimate the model using the Bayesian methods outlined in Baumeister and Hamilton (Reference Baumeister and Hamilton2015, Reference Baumeister and Hamilton2018). We estimate the model under priors that reflect the New Keynesian view of the business cycle but produce posterior distributions for the model’s parameters consistent with a classical view of the cycle. We conclude that valuable information is contained in the credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates about monetary policy and its effects on the economy. A comparison with the Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) results based on the CFS conventional Divisia M2 monetary aggregate favors the credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates used in the present paper.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we provide a brief discussion of the Divisia approach to monetary aggregation, from both the demand side and the supply side. Section 3 discusses the Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) approach based on methods developed by Baumeister and Hamilton (Reference Baumeister and Hamilton2015, Reference Baumeister and Hamilton2018). Section 4 discusses the data and section 5 presents the empirical results. The final section concludes the paper and discusses the implications for monetary theory and policy and business cycle theory.

2. Divisia monetary aggregates

In this section, we review the development of the Divisia monetary aggregates, developed by Barnett (Reference Barnett1978, Reference Barnett1980) and Barnett et al. (Reference Barnett, Chauvet, Leiva-Leon and Su2023).

2.1. Conventional Divisia aggregates

Barnett (Reference Barnett1978) derived the formula for the real user cost of a monetary asset as

(1) \begin{equation} \pi _{it}^{a}=\frac{R_{t}-r_{it}^{a}}{1+{R_{t}}} \end{equation}

where $R_{t}$ is the rate of return on the benchmark asset, measuring the maximum expected rate of return available in the economy, and $r_{it}^{a}$ is the own rate of return on monetary asset $i$ during period $t$ . Barnett (Reference Barnett1980) argued that the simple sum monetary aggregates provided by the Federal Reserve are inconsistent with economic aggregation theory because they assume that the monetary assets are perfect substitutes with the same user cost. He developed the Divisia monetary aggregates which do not assume perfect substitution between component assets (and hence permit different user costs of the component assets).

The Divisia monetary aggregate (in discrete time) computes the growth rate of the aggregate as the share-weighted average of its monetary asset component growth rates as follows

(2) \begin{equation} d\log M_{t}=\sum _{i=1}^{I}s_{it}d\log m_{it}^{a} \end{equation}

where $m_{it}^{a}$ denotes the real balances of monetary asset $i$ and

\begin{equation*} s_{it}=\pi _{it}^{a}m_{it}^{a}/\sum _{i=1}^{I}\pi _{it}^{a}m_{it}^{a}, \end{equation*}

is the expenditure share on monetary asset $i$ during period $t$ .

Over the years, most of the modern formal investigations of the impact of money on economic activity are carried out using the Divisia monetary aggregates. See, for example, Belongia (Reference Belongia1996), Serletis and Gogas (Reference Serletis and Gogas2014), Hendrickson (Reference Hendrickson2014), and Keating et al. (Reference Keating, Kelly, Smith and Valcarcel2019), among others.

2.2. Credit card-augmented Divisia aggregates

The conventional Divisia monetary aggregates exclude credit card transaction services. Barnett et al. (Reference Barnett, Chauvet, Leiva-Leon and Su2023), using economic aggregation and index number theory, derived the credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates which also include the transaction services of credit cards. Under the assumption of risk neutrality, Barnett et al. (Reference Barnett, Chauvet, Leiva-Leon and Su2023) derive the user cost of credit card transaction services, $\pi _{lt}^{c}$ , as

(3) \begin{equation} \pi _{lt}^{c}=\frac{e_{lt}-R_{t}}{1+R_{t}} \end{equation}

where $e_{lt}$ is the expected interest on the credit card transaction $l$ and $R_{t}$ is as before the rate of return on the benchmark asset.

The credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregate is then given by

(4) \begin{equation} d\log M_{t}=\sum _{i=1}^{I}s_{it}d\log m_{it}^{a}+\sum _{l=1}^{L}s_{lt}d\log m_{lt}^{c} \end{equation}

where

\begin{equation*} s_{it}=\pi _{it}^{a}m_{it}^{a}/(\sum _{i=1}^{I}\pi _{it}^{a}m_{it}^{a}+\sum _{l=1}^{L}\pi _{lt}^{c}m_{lt}^{c}) \end{equation*}

is the user-cost-evaluated expenditure share of monetary asset $i$ , $i=1,\ldots,I$ , and

\begin{equation*} s_{lt}=\pi _{lt}^{c}m_{lt}^{c}/(\sum _{i=1}^{I}\pi _{it}^{a}m_{it}^{a}+\sum _{l=1}^{L}\pi _{lt}^{c}m_{lt}^{c}) \end{equation*}

is the user-cost-evaluated expenditure share of credit card transaction $l$ , $l=1,\ldots,L$ .

2.3. Credit card-augmented Divisia inside aggregates

The conventional Divisia aggregates and the credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates emphasize the demand side of liquidity services. However, conditions from the supply side of liquidity services are at least equally important. In this regard, the monetary services produced by financial firms are known as inside money and are highly relevant to the transmission mechanism of monetary policy. In fact, quantitative easing during the global financial crisis and the coronavirus pandemic, with the goal of affecting the supply of liquid assets, impacted inside money directly.

To account for the monetary services produced by deposit-based financial firms, Barnett (Reference Barnett1987) introduces Divisia supply monetary aggregates which are based upon supply-side aggregation theory, in the context of a conventional neoclassical model of financial intermediary monetary assets supply. These aggregates highlight the existence of noninterest-bearing required reserves for banks. This is important, because a regulatory wedge is created for the user of the monetary services produced by banks. Thus, the user cost of a monetary asset needs to subtract the implicit tax as follows

(5) \begin{equation} \pi _{it}^{a}=\frac{(1-k_{i})R_{t}-r_{it}}{1+R_{t}} \end{equation}

where $k_{i}$ is the required reserve ratio on monetary asset $i$ .

Barnett and Su (Reference Barnett and Su2018) construct the credit card-augmented Divisia inside monetary aggregates as in equation (4) with quantities demanded, $m_{it}^{a}$ , replaced by quantities supplied and with paid user costs, $\pi _{it}^{a}$ , replaced by received user costs calculated as in equation (5).

In what follows, we posit our empirical work on the most recently developed credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates and credit card-augmented Divisia inside monetary aggregates.

3. The structural VAR

We consider a five-variable structural VAR model, consistent with the Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) expanded New Keynesian model, in the inflation rate, $\pi _{t}$ , the output gap, $\tilde{y}_{t}$ , the short-term nominal interest rate, $i_{t}$ , the nominal money growth rate, $\mu _{t}$ , and the user cost of money, ${uc}_{t}$ , as follows

(6) \begin{equation} \boldsymbol{A}{\boldsymbol{z}}_{t}=\boldsymbol{C}+\sum _{i=1}^{k}\boldsymbol{\Gamma}_{i}z_{t-i}+\boldsymbol{\epsilon }_{t} \end{equation}

where

\begin{eqnarray*} z_{t} &=&\left [ \begin{array}{c} \pi _{t} \\ \tilde{y}_{t} \\ i_{t} \\ \mu _{t} \\{uc}_{t}\end{array} \right ] ;\quad \boldsymbol{A}=\left [ \begin{array}{ccccc} 1 & a_{12} & 0 & 0 & 0 \\ a_{21}-a_{23} & 1 & a_{23} & -a_{21} & 0 \\ a_{31} & a_{32} & 1 & a_{34} & 0 \\ -1 & a_{42} & 0 & 1 & a_{45} \\ a_{51} & 0 & a_{53} & -a_{51} & 1\end{array}\right ] ;\quad \boldsymbol{\epsilon }_{t}=\left [ \begin{array}{c} \epsilon _{\pi,{t}} \\ \epsilon _{\tilde{y},_{t}} \\ \epsilon _{i,{t}} \\ \epsilon _{\mu,t} \\ \epsilon _{uc,t}\end{array}\right ] \text{;} \\ && \\ && \\ \boldsymbol{C} &=&\left [ \begin{array}{c} c_{1} \\ c_{2} \\ c_{3} \\ c_{4} \\ c_{5}\end{array}\right ] ;\quad \boldsymbol{\Gamma}_{i}=\left [ \begin{array}{ccccc} \gamma _{i,11} & \gamma _{i,12} & \gamma _{i,13} & \gamma _{i,14} & \gamma _{i,15} \\ \gamma _{i,21} & \gamma _{i,22} & \gamma _{i,23} & \gamma _{i,24} & \gamma _{i,25} \\ \gamma _{i,31} & \gamma _{i,32} & \gamma _{i,33} & \gamma _{i,34} & \gamma _{i,35} \\ \gamma _{i,41} & \gamma _{i,42} & \gamma _{i,43} & \gamma _{i,44} & \gamma _{i,45} \\ \gamma _{i,51} & \gamma _{i,52} & \gamma _{i,53} & \gamma _{i,54} & \gamma _{i,55}\end{array}\right ]. \end{eqnarray*}

The structural errors, $\boldsymbol{\epsilon }_{t}$ , are assumed to follow the normal distribution with zero mean and the identity matrix for their variance. The $\boldsymbol{A}$ matrix identifies the model with seven zero restrictions and three equality restrictions. Based on Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021), the parameterized $\boldsymbol{A}$ matrix is consistent with New Keynesian theory, which is augmented by incorporating money and the cost of holding monetary balances.

We have the following structural interpretation for each equation in (6). The inflation rate equation

(7) \begin{equation} \pi _{t}=-a_{12}\tilde{y}_{t}+c_{1}+\sum _{i=1}^{k}\sum _{j=1}^{5}\gamma _{i,1j} z_{t-i,j}+\epsilon _{\pi,t} \end{equation}

mimics the New Keynesian Phillips curve. It shows a contemporaneous relationship between the inflation rate, $\pi _{t}$ , and the output gap, $\tilde{y}_{t}$ . The structural error term, $\epsilon _{\pi,t}$ , is referred to as the aggregate supply shock.

The second equation in the VAR system is

(8) \begin{equation} \tilde{y}_{t}=-a_{23}(i_{t}-\pi _{t})+a_{21}(\mu _{t}-\pi _{t})+c_{2}+\sum _{i=1}^{k}\sum _{j=1}^{5}\gamma _{i,2j} z_{t-i,j}+\epsilon _{\tilde{y},_{t}} \end{equation}

is basically the New Keynesian IS curve. It shows how the real (short-term) interest rate, $i_{t}-\pi _{t}$ , affects the output gap, $\tilde{y}_{t}$ . In general, an increase in the real interest rate will reduce the output gap. In particular, Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) augment the IS curve by allowing the growth rate of real money balances, $\mu _{t}-\pi _{t}$ , to impact real economic activity. This mechanism represents the classical view about the role of money in the economy. $\epsilon _{\tilde{y},_{t}}$ in equation (8) is referred to as the output shock.

The third equation gives the monetary policy rule

(9) \begin{equation} i_{t}=-a_{31}\pi _{t}-a_{32}\tilde{y}_{t}-a_{34}\mu _{t}+c_{3}+\sum _{i=1}^{k}\sum _{j=1}^{5}\gamma _{i,3j} z_{t-i,j}+\epsilon _{i,t}\text{.} \end{equation}

The monetary policy rule assumes that the central bank adjusts the interest rate by tracking inflation and output gap changes. $\epsilon _{i,t}$ is the monetary policy shock. It is to be noted that this policy rule also includes the growth rate of nominal money balances, $\mu _{t}$ . It indicates that a monetary policy shock can be considered a combined result of changes in the interest rate and the money stock. For example, an expansionary monetary shock may reflect a combination of a lower interest rate and higher nominal money growth.

The fourth equation is the money demand equation, which shows that the growth rate of real money balances is determined by the output gap (the scale variable) and the user cost of money (an opportunity cost variable), as follows

(10) \begin{equation} \mu _{t}-\pi _{t}=-a_{42}\tilde{y}_{t}-a_{45}{uc}_{t}+c_{4}+\sum _{i=1}^{k}\sum _{j=1}^{5}\gamma _{i,4j} z_{t-i,j}+\epsilon _{\left ( \mu -\pi \right ),t} \end{equation}

where $\epsilon _{\left ( \mu -\pi \right ),t}$ is the money demand shock.

The fifth equation characterizes the opportunity cost of holding money balances which is the user cost, ${uc}_{t}$ , as follows

(11) \begin{equation}{uc}_{t}=-a_{53}i_{t}+a_{51}(\mu _{t}-\pi _{t})+c_{5}+\sum _{i=1}^{k}\sum _{j=1}^{5}\gamma _{i,5j} z_{t-i,j}+\epsilon _{uc,t}. \end{equation}

According to Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2014, Reference Belongia and Ireland2021), an increase in the interest rate raises the cost of holding reserves from the viewpoint of commercial banks. The banks then pass the cost to consumers by lowering the return on deposits and other monetary assets, which directly increases the user cost. Moreover, the increase in the interest rate also signals a higher return on non-monetary assets in the financial market. Therefore, the opportunity cost of holding monetary assets should increase, also leading to a higher user cost. The second term in equation (11) tells that the additional creation of real money balances may impact its user cost. Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) refer to $\epsilon _{uc,t}$ as the monetary system shock.

The reduced form of model (6) is

(12) \begin{equation} z_{t}=\widetilde{\boldsymbol{C}}+\sum _{i=1}^{k}\widetilde{\boldsymbol{\Gamma}}_{t-i}z_{t-i}+\widetilde{\boldsymbol{\epsilon }}_{t} \end{equation}

where

\begin{eqnarray*} \widetilde{\boldsymbol{C}} &=& \boldsymbol{A}^{-1}\boldsymbol{C}\\ \widetilde{\mathbf{\Gamma }}_{t-i} &=& \boldsymbol{A}^{-1}\mathbf{\Gamma }_{t-i} \\ \widetilde{\boldsymbol{\epsilon }}_{t} &=&\boldsymbol{A}^{-1}\boldsymbol{\epsilon }_{t} \end{eqnarray*}

with the reduced from errors, $\widetilde{\boldsymbol{\epsilon }}_{t}$ , following the normal distribution, $\widetilde{\boldsymbol{\epsilon }}_{t}\sim N(\mathbf{0},\boldsymbol{\Omega })$ , where $\boldsymbol{\Omega }=\boldsymbol{A}^{-1}\mathbf{I}\left (\boldsymbol{A}^{-1}\right ) ^{\prime }$ .

4. The data

We use quarterly data for the United States over the period from 2006:q3 to 2023:q2.Footnote 1 For the real output series, $y_{t}$ , we use the real GDP series GDPC1 from the Federal Reserve Economic Database (FRED) maintained by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. We use the Congressional Budget Office’s estimate for potential real GDP, $\bar{y}_{t}$ , which is also retrieved from FRED. We then calculate the output gap, $\tilde{y}_{t}$ , as the difference between observed real GDP and potential real GDP expressed as a percentage of potential real GDP, $\tilde{y}_{t}=(y_{t}-\bar{y}_{t})/\bar{y}_{t}$ .

Figure 1. Impulse response functions to a money demand shock based on M1A and M1AI.

The inflation rate, $\pi _{t}$ , is the year-over-year percentage change in the personal consumption expenditures price index, retrieved from FRED (series CPIAUCSL). The nominal interest rate, $i_{t}$ , is the effective federal funds rate from FRED. However, we use the Wu and Xia (Reference Wu and Xia2016) shadow federal funds rate for the time period from 2009:q1 to 2015:q4, since the federal funds rate hit the zero lower bound during this period.

Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) take advantage of the Divisia aggregates and their theoretically coherent measures of the user cost and use the Divisia M2 monetary aggregate. In this paper, we focus on the new credit card-augmented Divisia and credit card-augmented Divisia inside monetary aggregates. In particular, we consider eight credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. They are the credit card-augmented Divisia M1 monetary aggregate (M1A), the credit card-augmented Divisia M2 monetary aggregate (M2A), the credit card-augmented Divisia M3 monetary aggregate (M3A), the credit card-augmented Divisia M4 monetary aggregate (M4A), the credit card-augmented Divisia M1 inside monetary aggregate (M1AI), the credit card-augmented Divisia M2 inside monetary aggregate (M2AI), the credit card-augmented Divisia M3 inside monetary aggregate (M3AI), and the credit card-augmented Divisia M4 inside monetary aggregate (M4AIM).Footnote 2

For a graphical presentation and brief discussion of the monthly growth rates of the conventional Divisia aggregates, the credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates, and the credit card-augmented Divisia inside monetary aggregates, see Figure 1 in Andreadis et al. (Reference Andreadis, Fragkou, Karakasidis and Serletis2023).

Table 1. Bayesian priors

Table 2. Estimates of the $a_{21}$ and $a_{34}$ parameters

Notes: Sample period, quarterly data, 2006:q3 to 2023:q2.

The posterior distribution for the parameters is reported with the median, 16th percentile, and 84th percentile.

5. Empirical evidence

We follow Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) and perform Bayesian estimation. In particular, we calibrate Bayesian prior distributions for the structural parameters of the model that reflect the New Keynesian view of the cycle, combine them with information contained in the data, and through the likelihood function characterize the posterior distributions of the same parameters. Next, we examine whether the posterior distributions of the structural parameters support specifications that allow classical channels of monetary transmission. That is, whether changes in the growth rate of nominal money balances signal more clearly than changes in the nominal interest rate whether monetary policy is contractionary or expansionary and whether changes in real money balances, together with changes in the real interest rate, affect real output.

The restrictions and other prior information of the model are presented in Table 1. For example, the $a_{21}$ coefficient in the augmented version of the New Keynesian aggregate demand curve (8), which captures the impact of nominal money growth, $\mu _{t}$ , on the output gap (via changes in the growth rate of real money balances, $\mu _{t}-\pi _{t}$ ), is assigned a zero prior mean to be consistent with the New Keynesian interest rate channel of monetary policy transmission that links the output gap only to policy-induced changes in the real short-term interest rate. Similarly, the coefficient $a_{34}$ in equation (9), which captures the effect of changes in nominal money growth on the short-term nominal interest rate, is assigned a zero prior mean to be consistent with the New Keynesian view that changes in nominal money play no role in formulation of monetary policy. We follow Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) in assigning Bayesian priors for all the other parameters not shown in Table 1—see Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) for more details.

Figure 2. Impulse response functions to a money demand shock based on M2A and M2AI.

In Table 2, we summarize posterior estimates (medians together with 16th and 84th percentiles) for the two coefficients that characterize the potential role of money in the economy— $a_{21}$ in the augmented New Keynesian aggregate demand equation (8) and $a_{34}$ in the monetary policy rule (9). For comparison purposes, we also include the Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) estimates with the original Divisia M2 monetary aggregate over their sample period, from 1967:q1 to 2017:q4, as well as our estimates with the original Divisia M2 monetary aggregate over our sample period, from 2006:q3 to 2023:q2. Consistent with the evidence in Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021), our estimates suggest that the data prefer a more classical version of both the augmented New Keynesian aggregate demand equation (8) and the monetary policy rule (9).

Moreover, the posterior median for the coefficient on real money balances in the augmented New Keynesian aggregate demand equation (8) is much higher than the one reported by Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021). In particular, it is $0.62$ with the credit card-augmented Divisia M2 (Divisia M2A) aggregate and $0.61$ with the credit card-augmented Divisia M2 inside (Divisia M2AI) monetary aggregate. On the other hand, the posterior median for the $a_{34}$ coefficient in the monetary policy rule (9) is much smaller than the estimate in Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021) although similar to our estimate when the model is estimated with Divisia M2 over the 2006:q3 to 2023:q2 sample period. It is $0.28$ with Divisia M2A and $0.27$ with Divisia M2AI compared to $1.23$ in Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021), suggesting a weaker (but nontrivial) policy-rate response to changes in the growth rate of the credit-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. Overall, our estimates suggest that the credit-augmented Divisia aggregates play an even more important role in shaping the monetary business cycle than the original Divisia aggregates. This result can be linked to the incorporation of credit payments. Credit card transaction services have been an important part of the general economic activity and include additional information when measuring monetary services. Our results highlight how such information enhances the understanding of money’s role in the business cycle.

Figure 3. Impulse response functions to a money demand shock based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 4. Impulse response functions to a money demand shock based on M4A and M4AI.

Figure 5. Impulse response functions to a monetary system shock based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure 6. Impulse response functions to a monetary system shock based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure 7. Impulse response functions to a monetary system shock based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 8. Impulse response functions to a monetary system shock based on M4A and M4AI.

Figure 9. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure 10. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure 11. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 12. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M4A and M4AIM.

Figure 13. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure 14. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure 15. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 16. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M4A and M4AIM.

To access the dynamic role of the credit-augmented Divisia aggregates in the monetary business cycle, we report selected impulse response functions in Figures 14.Footnote 3 They show the responses of inflation and the output gap to a one-standard deviation money demand shock. As can be seen, a positive money demand shock is likely to decrease inflation after about eight quarters with the narrow Divisia M1A and Divisia M1AI monetary aggregates and much earlier (about two quarters) with the broader monetary aggregates. The effect, however, on the output gap is generally statistically insignificant.

Figures 58 plot the responses of inflation and the output gap to a one-standard deviation monetary system shock. The monetary system shock captures the impacts of the creation of monetary assets on the supply side. It is interesting to see that an unexpected increase in user costs will cause a decline in inflation and the output gap. This effect is likely to appear after two quarters, and all Figures 58 show the same pattern. The intuition is that an increase in the user cost is associated with a higher interest rate which slows down economic activity, reducing inflation and output.

Finally, we report the variance decompositions in Figures 916. As can be seen (in Figures 912), money demand shocks explain less than 10% of inflation and output gap variations in the long run. On the other hand, monetary system shocks (see Figures 1316) explain around 10% of inflation variation and play an even larger role in explaining output fluctuations. As in Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021), these results point to additional classical channels of monetary transmission, captured by movements in the credit-augmented Divisia aggregates above and beyond movements in the real interest rate.

In the Appendix, we report the responses of inflation and the output gap to a positive monetary shock as well as the full set of variance decompositions based on all the credit-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. As can be seen in Appendix Figures A1A4, the responses of inflation and the output gap to a positive monetary shock are all consistent with economic theory. In particular, a contractionary monetary policy (an increase in the federal fund rate) reduces inflation and limits economic activities, and there are no output and price puzzles. Appendix Figures A5A44 show the full set of variance decompositions with all the credit-augmented Divisia aggregates. There is robust evidence (see Appendix Figures A5, A10, A15, A20, A25, A30, A35, and A40) suggesting that the aggregate supply shock dominates the fluctuations in inflation in the long run. On the other hand, the aggregate demand shock is an important factor that explains the variations in all five macroeconomic variables in the long run, based on Appendix Figures A6, A11, A16, A21, A26, A31, A36, and A41.

6. Conclusion

The main objective of this paper is to investigate whether there is a role of the credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates and credit card-augmented Divisia inside monetary aggregates, recently produced by the Center for Financial Stability, in monetary policy and business cycle analysis. We follow Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021), estimate a five-variable structural VAR using Bayesian methods, and discover monetary policy transmission channels working through interactions between the demand and supply of the credit-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. We also find that the classical monetary policy transmission channels are stronger with the credit-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates relative to the conventional Divisia aggregates.

As Belongia and Ireland (Reference Belongia and Ireland2021, pp. 362) put it, “these results call out for a new class of models, or at least substantial extensions of existing ones, that provide a richer and more realistic description of the monetary business cycle. They call out, as well, for a reconsideration of the role that measures of money play in the formation of Federal Reserve policy.”

APPENDIX A

Figure A1. Impulse response functions to a monetary shock based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure A2. Impulse response functions to a monetary shock based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure A3. Impulse response functions to a monetary shock based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure A4. Impulse response functions to a monetary shock based on M4A and M4AIM.

Figure A5. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M1A.

Figure A6. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M1A.

Figure A7. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M1A.

Figure A8. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M1A.

Figure A9. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M1A.

Figure A10. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M1AI.

Figure A11. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M1AI.

Figure A12. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M1AI.

Figure A13. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M1AI.

Figure A14. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M1AI.

Figure A15. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M2A.

Figure A16. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M2A.

Figure A17. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M2A.

Figure A18. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M2A.

Figure A19. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M2A.

Figure A20. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M2AI.

Figure A21. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M2AI.

Figure A22. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M2AI.

Figure A23. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M2AI.

Figure A24. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M2AI.

Figure A25. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M3A.

Figure A26. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M3A.

Figure A27. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M3A.

Figure A28. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M3A.

Figure A29. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M3A.

Figure A30. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M3AI.

Figure A31. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M3AI.

Figure A32. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M3AI.

Figure A33. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M3AI.

Figure A34. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M3AI.

Figure A35. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M4A.

Figure A36. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M4A.

Figure A37. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M4A.

Figure A38. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M4A.

Figure A39. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M4A.

Figure A40. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M4AIM.

Figure A41. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M4AIM.

Figure A42. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M4AIM.

Figure A43. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M4AIM.

Figure A44. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M4AIM.

Footnotes

We would like to thank William A. Barnett and two anonynous referees for comments that greatly improved the paper.

1 The quarterly Divisia series are constructed by taking the average of the monthly observations in each quarter.

2 The Center for Financial Stability does not provide the credit card-augmented Divisia M4 inside monetary aggregate (M4AI). Therefore, we choose M4AIM, which is the same as M4AI, except for excluding Treasury bills.

3 The full set of impulse response functions is available upon request.

References

Andreadis, I., Fragkou, A. D., Karakasidis, T. E. and Serletis, A. (2023) The Credit Card-augmented Divisia Monetary Aggregates: An Analysis Based on Recurrence Plots and Visual Boundary Recurrence Plots, Working paper, University of Calgary. Department of Economics.Google Scholar
Barnett, W. A. (1978) The user cost of money. Economics Letters 1(2), 145149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A. (1980) Economic monetary aggregates: an application of aggregation and index number theory. Journal of Econometrics 14(1), 1148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A. (1987). The microeconomic theory of monetary aggregation. In: New Approaches to Monetary Economics: Proceedings of the Second International Symposium in Economic Theory and Econometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 156168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A. and Serletis, A. (2000) The Theory of Monetary Aggregation. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Barnett, W. A. and Su, L. (2016) Joint aggregation over money and credit card services under risk. Economics Bulletin 36(4), A223A234.Google Scholar
Barnett, W. A. and Su, L. (2018) Financial firm production of inside money and credit card services: an aggregation theoretic approach. Macroeconomic Dynamics 24, 131.Google Scholar
Barnett, W. A. and Su, L. (2019) Risk adjustment of the credit-card augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. Macroeconomic Dynamics 23(S1), 90114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A. and Chauvet, M. (2011) Financial Aggregation and Index Number Theory. Singapore: World Scientific.Google Scholar
Barnett, W. A., Chauvet, M., Leiva-Leon, D. and Su, L. (2023) The credit-card-services augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking (forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A. and Park, S. (2023a) Forecasting inflation and output growth with credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. Journal of Forecasting, 42(2), 331–346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A. and Park, H. (2023b) Have credit card services become important to monetary aggregation? An application of sign restricted Bayesian VAR. Working papers series in theoretical and applied economics 202304, University of Kansas, Department of Economics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumeister, C. and Hamilton, J. D. (2015) Sign restrictions, structural vector autoregressions, and useful prior information. Econometrica 83(5), 19631999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumeister, C. and Hamilton, J. D. (2018) Inference in structural vector autoregressions when the identifying assumptions are not fully believed: re-evaluating the role of monetary policy in economic fluctuations. Journal of Monetary Economics 100, 4865.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belongia, M. T. (1996) Measurement matters: recent results from monetary economics reexamined. Journal of Political Economy 104(5), 10651083.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belongia, M. T. and Ireland, P. N. (2014) The Barnett critique after three decades: a new Keynesian analysis. Journal of Econometrics 183(1), 521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belongia, M. T. and Ireland, P. N. (2015) Interest rates and money in the measurement of monetary policy. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 33(2), 255269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belongia, M. T. and Ireland, P. N. (2016) Money and output: Friedman and Schwartz revisited. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 48(6), 12231266.Google Scholar
Belongia, M. T. and Ireland, P. N. (2018) Targeting constant money growth at the zero lower bound. International Journal of Central Banking 14, 159204.Google Scholar
Belongia, M. T. and Ireland, P. N. (2021) A classical view of the business cycle. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 53(2-3), 333366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dery, C. and Serletis, A. (2019) Interest rates, money, and economic activity. Macroeconomic Dynamics 25(7), 18421891.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellington, M. (2018) The case for Divisia monetary statistics: a Bayesian time-varying approach. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 96, 2641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendrickson, J. R. (2014) Redundancy or mismeasurement? A reappraisal of money. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18(7), 14371465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keating, J. W., Kelly, L. J., Smith, A. and Valcarcel, V. (2019) A model of monetary policy shocks for financial crisis and normal conditions. Journal of Money, Banking and Credit 51(1), 227259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, J. and Serletis, A. (2020) Money growth variability and output: evidence with credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 24, 111.Google Scholar
Liu, J., Dery, C. and Serletis, A. (2020) Recent monetary policy and the credit card-augmented Divisia monetary aggregates. Journal of Macroeconomics 64, 103203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCallum, B. T. and Nelson, E. (2011) Money and inflation: Some critical issues. In: B. M. Friedman and M. Woodford (eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 3A, pp. 97153. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Schunk, D. L. (2001) The relative forecasting performance of the Divisia and simple sum monetary aggregates. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 33(2), 272283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Serletis, A. (2009) A Bayesian classification approach to monetary aggregation. Macroeconomic Dynamics 13(2), 200219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Serletis, A. and Gogas, P. (2014) Divisia monetary aggregates, the great ratios, an classical money demand functions. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46(1), 229241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Serletis, A. and Rahman, S. (2013) The case for Divisia money targeting. Macroeconomic Dynamics 17(8), 16381658.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, J. C. and Xia, F. D. (2016) Measuring the macroeconomic impact of monetary policy at the zero lower bound. Journal of Econometrics 48, 253291.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Impulse response functions to a money demand shock based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure 1

Table 1. Bayesian priors

Figure 2

Table 2. Estimates of the $a_{21}$ and $a_{34}$ parameters

Figure 3

Figure 2. Impulse response functions to a money demand shock based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure 4

Figure 3. Impulse response functions to a money demand shock based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 5

Figure 4. Impulse response functions to a money demand shock based on M4A and M4AI.

Figure 6

Figure 5. Impulse response functions to a monetary system shock based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure 7

Figure 6. Impulse response functions to a monetary system shock based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure 8

Figure 7. Impulse response functions to a monetary system shock based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 9

Figure 8. Impulse response functions to a monetary system shock based on M4A and M4AI.

Figure 10

Figure 9. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure 11

Figure 10. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure 12

Figure 11. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 13

Figure 12. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M4A and M4AIM.

Figure 14

Figure 13. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure 15

Figure 14. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure 16

Figure 15. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 17

Figure 16. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M4A and M4AIM.

Figure 18

Figure A1. Impulse response functions to a monetary shock based on M1A and M1AI.

Figure 19

Figure A2. Impulse response functions to a monetary shock based on M2A and M2AI.

Figure 20

Figure A3. Impulse response functions to a monetary shock based on M3A and M3AI.

Figure 21

Figure A4. Impulse response functions to a monetary shock based on M4A and M4AIM.

Figure 22

Figure A5. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M1A.

Figure 23

Figure A6. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M1A.

Figure 24

Figure A7. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M1A.

Figure 25

Figure A8. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M1A.

Figure 26

Figure A9. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M1A.

Figure 27

Figure A10. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M1AI.

Figure 28

Figure A11. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M1AI.

Figure 29

Figure A12. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M1AI.

Figure 30

Figure A13. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M1AI.

Figure 31

Figure A14. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M1AI.

Figure 32

Figure A15. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M2A.

Figure 33

Figure A16. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M2A.

Figure 34

Figure A17. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M2A.

Figure 35

Figure A18. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M2A.

Figure 36

Figure A19. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M2A.

Figure 37

Figure A20. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M2AI.

Figure 38

Figure A21. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M2AI.

Figure 39

Figure A22. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M2AI.

Figure 40

Figure A23. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M2AI.

Figure 41

Figure A24. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M2AI.

Figure 42

Figure A25. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M3A.

Figure 43

Figure A26. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M3A.

Figure 44

Figure A27. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M3A.

Figure 45

Figure A28. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M3A.

Figure 46

Figure A29. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M3A.

Figure 47

Figure A30. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M3AI.

Figure 48

Figure A31. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M3AI.

Figure 49

Figure A32. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M3AI.

Figure 50

Figure A33. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M3AI.

Figure 51

Figure A34. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M3AI.

Figure 52

Figure A35. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M4A.

Figure 53

Figure A36. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M4A.

Figure 54

Figure A37. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M4A.

Figure 55

Figure A38. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M4A.

Figure 56

Figure A39. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M4A.

Figure 57

Figure A40. Variance decomposition for aggregate supply shocks based on M4AIM.

Figure 58

Figure A41. Variance decomposition for aggregate demand shocks based on M4AIM.

Figure 59

Figure A42. Variance decomposition for monetary shocks based on M4AIM.

Figure 60

Figure A43. Variance decomposition for money demand shocks based on M4AIM.

Figure 61

Figure A44. Variance decomposition for monetary system shocks based on M4AIM.