Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T18:58:41.307Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Special and Differential Treatment of Developing Countries in the WTO

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 January 2015

PAOLA CONCONI*
Affiliation:
Université Libre de Bruxelles (ECARES), Brussels and the Centre for Economic Policy Research, London
CARLO PERRONI*
Affiliation:
University of Warwick, Coventry

Abstract

In this paper, we examine the theoretical rationale for WTO rules on the special and differential treatment (SDT) of developing countries. We describe a model of bilateral trade between a small country and a large trading partner, in which the small country suffers from a domestic commitment problem in trade policy. This problem arises because investors in the import-competing sector lobby the government to enact and maintain protectionist policies. We show that a reciprocal trade agreement, in which the large country lowers its tariffs conditionally on the small country doing the same, creates a ‘carrot and stick’ mechanisms that helps the small country to overcome its commitment problem. If capacity in the import-competing sector can only be reduced gradually, the agreement may need to allow the small country to delay the implementation of its trade liberalization commitments, in line with SDT provisions in the WTO. Our analysis suggests that, if reconciled with the principle of reciprocity, SDT can help developing countries to liberalize and improve their trading prospects.

Type
Review Article
Copyright
Copyright © Paola Conconi and Carlo Perroni 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Bagwell, K. and Staiger, R. (1999), ‘An Economic Theory of GATT’, American Economic Review, 8: 215248.Google Scholar
Bagwell, K. and Staiger, R. (2014), ‘Can the Doha Round be a Development Round? Setting a Place at the Table’, in Feenstra, R. C. and Taylor, A. M. (eds.), Globalization in an Age of Crisis: Multilateral Economic Cooperation in the Twenty-First Century, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Baldwin, R. (2012), ‘WTO 2.0: Global Governance of Supply-chain Trade’, CEPR Policy Insight No. 64.Google Scholar
Beshkar, M., Bond, E., and Rho, Y. (2012), ‘Tariff Binding and Overhang: Theory and Evidence’, mimeo.Google Scholar
Bond, E. and Park, J.-H. (2002), ‘Gradualism in Trade Agreements with Asymmetric Countries’, Review of Economic Studies, 69: 379406.Google Scholar
Bora, B., Lloyd, J., and Pangestu, M. (2000), ‘Industrial Policy in the WTO’, The World Economy, 23: 543559.Google Scholar
Bown, C. and Hoekman, B. (2008), ‘Developing Countries and Enforcement of Trade Agreements: Why Dispute Settlement is not Enough’, Journal of World Trade, 42: 177203.Google Scholar
Brainard, S. and Verdier, T. (1994), ‘Lobbying and Adjustment in Declining Industries’, European Economic Review, 38: 586595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunetti, A., Kisunko, G., and Weder, B. (1998), ‘Credibility of Rules and Economic Growth: Evidence from a Worldwide Survey of the Private Sector’, World Bank Economic Review, 12: 353384.Google Scholar
Chisik, R. (2003), ‘Gradualism in Free Trade Agreements: A Theoretical Justification’, Journal of International Economics, 59: 367397.Google Scholar
Coates, D. and Ludema, R. (2001), ‘A Theory of Trade Policy Leadership’, Journal of Development Economics, 65: 129.Google Scholar
Conconi, P. and Perroni, C. (2012), ‘Conditional versus Unconditional Trade Concessions for Developing Countries’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 45: 613631.Google Scholar
Finger, J. and Schuler, P. (2000), ‘Implementation of Uruguay Round Commitments: The Development Challenge’, World Economy, 23: 511525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furusawa, T. and Lai, E. (1997), ‘Adjustment Costs and Gradual Trade Liberalization’, Journal of International Economics, 49: 333361.Google Scholar
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1994), ‘Protection for Sale’, American Economic Review, 84: 833850.Google Scholar
Kehoe, P. (1989), ‘Policy Cooperation among Benevolent Governments May Be Undesirable’, Review of Economic Studies, 56: 289296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreuger, A. (1997), ‘Trade Policy and Economic Development: How We Learn’, American Economic Review, 87: 122.Google Scholar
Limão, N. (2007), ‘Are Preferential Trade Agreements with Non-trade Objectives a Stumbling Block for Multilateral Liberalization?’, Review of Economic Studies, 74: 821855.Google Scholar
Maggi, G. and Rodríguez-Clare, A. (1998), ‘The Value of Trade Agreements in the Presence of Political Pressures’, Journal of Political Economy, 106: 574601.Google Scholar
Maggi, G. and Rodríguez-Clare, A. (2007), ‘A Political-Economy Theory of Trade Agreements’, American Economic Review, 97: 13741406.Google Scholar
Matsuyama, K. (1990), ‘Perfect Equilibria in a Trade Liberalization Game’, American Economic Review, 80: 480492.Google Scholar
Michalopoulos, C. (2000), ‘Trade and Development in the GATT and WTO: The Role of Special and Differential Treatment for Developing Countries’, World Bank Working Paper 2388.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Özden, C. and Reinhardt, E. (2004), ‘The Perversity of Preferences: GSP and Developing Country Trade Policies, 1976–2000’, Journal of Development Economics, 78: 121.Google Scholar
Perroni, C. and Whalley, J. (1996), ‘The New Regionalism: Trade Liberalization or Insurance?’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 33: 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perroni, C. and Whalley, J. (2000), ‘How Severe is Global Retaliation Risk under Increasing Regionalism?’, American Economic Review, 86: 5761.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. (1992), ‘The Limits of Trade Policy Reform in Developing Countries’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6: 87105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roessler, (1998), ‘Domestic Policy Objectives and the Multilateral Trade Order: Lessons from the Past’, in Krueger, A. O. (ed.), The WTO as an International Organization, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Staiger, R. and Tabellini, G. (1987), ‘Discretionary Trade Policy and Excessive Protection’, American Economic Review, 77: 823837.Google Scholar
Stokey, N. (1989), ‘Reputation and Time Consistency’, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 79: 134139.Google Scholar
Subramanian, A. and Wei, S.-J. (2007), ‘The WTO Promotes Trade, Strongly but Unevenly’, Journal of International Economics, 72: 151175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tang, M.-K. and Wei, S.-J. (2009), ‘The Value of Making Commitments Externally: Evidence from WTO Accessions’, Journal of International Economics, 78: 216229.Google Scholar
Whalley, J. (1998), ‘Why Do Countries Seek Regional Trade Agreements?’, in Frankel, J. (ed.), The Regionalization of the World Economy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, Chapter 3.Google Scholar