Published online by Cambridge University Press: 13 June 2011
Stephen D. Krasner's article in this journal in 1976, “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” defined the agenda for years of scholarship by being both lucid and problematic. Krasner presented a clear puzzle but manifestly failed adequately to answer the questions that he raised. His key proposition, that strong international economic regimes depend on hegemonic power, was supported by only half of the six cases that he discussed. Yet the cogency of Krasner's formulation of the argument, and the pungency of his rhetoric, led “State Power” to serve as a focal point in a coordination game among three major constituencies in the international political economy field. Liberal transnationalists, statist realists, and their audiences all benefited from Krasner's lucid specification of the issues. As a result of research prompted by Krasner's article, we understand the relationship between international political structure and economic openness much better than we did before it appeared.
1 Krasner, , “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics 28 (April 1976)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
2 Kindleberger, , American Business Abroad: Six Lectures on Direct Investment (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1969), 207Google Scholar.
3 I am indebted to Ronald Rogowski for pointing out to me that strategic trade theory could support Krasner's closure–relative advantage proposition. For an early work on strategic trade policy, see Krugman, Paul R., ed., Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1986)Google Scholar. David Lake also discusses this issue, in “Leadership, Hegemony and the International Economy: Naked Emperor or Tattered Monarch with Potential? International Studies Quarterly 37 (December 1993)Google Scholar.
4 Skepticism and controversy abound over other questions: whether democratic governments actually act on the basis of strategic trade considerations (rather than principally reacting to societal pressures) and whether such governments would be capable of intelligently crafting policies along strategic trade lines.
5 I am indebted to Stephen Krasner for his observations on an earlier version of this essay, which stimulated this point.
6 Hirschman, , National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (1945; reprint, Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980), 18Google Scholar.
7 Waltz, , “The Myth of National Interdependence,” in Kindleberger, Charles P., ed., The International Corporation (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1970), 210Google Scholar.
8 Nye, Joseph S. and I expressed the same thought a year later in Power and Interdependence: “A useful beginning in the political analysis of international interdependence can be made by thinking of asymmetrical dependencies as sources of power among actors.” Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S. Jr., Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition (Boston: Little, Brown, 1977), 18Google Scholar.
9 Baldwin, , “Power Analysis and World Politics: New Trends versus Old Tendencies,” World Politics 31 (January 1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
10 Gilpin, , “The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations,” in Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S., eds., Transnational Relations and World Politics (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1972), 54–55Google Scholar. Transnational Relations and World Politics first appeared in a special issue of International Organization 25 (Summer 1971)Google Scholar.
11 See Kindleberger, , The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973Google Scholar and subsequent editions). The quotation is on page 304 of the revised and expanded edition of 1986. Krasner accepts this distinction between his work and Kindleberger's. See Webb, Michael C. and Krasner, Stephen D., “Hegemonic Stability Theory: An Empirical Assessment,” Review of International Studies 15 (April 1989), 184CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
12 Lake (fh. 3).
13 Keohane, Robert O., “The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Changes in International Economic Regimes, 1967–1977,” in Holsti, Ole et al., eds., Change in the International System (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1980), 136Google Scholar. Vinod Aggarwal most forcefully pointed out that international regimes could be illiberal. See Aggarwal, , Liberal Protectionism: The International Politics of Organized Textile Trade (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985)Google Scholar.
14 Conybeare, , “Public Goods, Prisoners’ Dilemmas and the International Political Economy,” International Studies Quarterly 28 (March 1984), 12CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
15 Gowa, , “Rational Hegemons, Excludable Goods, and Small Groups: An Epitaph for Hegemonic Stability Theory?” World Politics 41 (April 1989), esp. 312CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
16 Lake, , “Beneath the Commerce of Nations: A Theory of International Economic Structures,” International Studies Quarterly 28 (June 1984)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
17 Keohane, Robert O., After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984)Google Scholar.
18 Snidal, Duncan, “The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory,” International Organization 39 (Autumn 1985), 611CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
19 In discussing neoclassical trade theory, Krasner mentions a strategic-interaction argument of Harry Johnson: “mat the imposition of successive optimal tariffs could lead both trading partners to a situation in which they were worse off than under competitive conditions” (p. 318). Later work by Krasner has explicitly used a strategic formulation. See especially “Global Communications and National Power Life on the Pareto Frontier,” World Politics 43 (April 1991)Google Scholar. In that article he (unfairly, in my view) claims that “market failure analyses, which have dominated the literature on international regimes, pay little attention to power” (p. 342).
20 Gowa, Joanne, “Bipolarity, Multipolarity, and Free Trade,” American Political Science Review 63 (December 1989)Google Scholar; idem, Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994)Google Scholar.
21 Webb and Krasner (fn. 11), 196.
22 McKeown, , “Hegemonic Stability Theory and Nineteenth Century Tariff Levels in Europe,” International Organization 37 (Winter 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Conybeare, , “Tariff Protection in Developed and Developing Countries: A Cross-Sectional and Longitudinal Analysis,” International Organization 37 (Summer 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar,
23 McKeown, , “A Liberal Trade Order? The Long-Run Pattern of Imports to the Advanced Capitalist States,” International Studies Quarterly 35 (June 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
24 Webb and Krasner (fn. 11), 195. On the dating of the demise of hegemony, see pages 185–86.
25 Mansfield, , Power, Trade and War (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994), 179,73Google Scholar.
26 Ibid., 181.1 am especially indebted to Professor Marc Busch of Harvard for pointing out the correspondence between Mansfield's findings and Krasner's theory.
27 I claim no prescience in this respect. I recollect that my first reaction to Krasner's paper was more critical of the unsatisfactory nature of his evidence than appreciative of the lucidity with which he defined his variables and stated his key proposition. Since recollections are usually biased in favor of the reputation of the teller of the tale, this one is probably, unfortunately, correct.
28 Katzenstein, , “Introduction,” in Katzenstein, , ed., Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1978), 7, 18Google Scholar. This volume first appeared as an issue of International Organization 311 (Fall 1977)Google Scholar.
29 Ibid., esp. 86–87. Krasner made a similar argument in Defending the National Interest: Raw Materials Investments and U.S. Foreign Policy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978).
30 Gourevitch, , “The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic Politics,” International Organization 32 (Autumn 1978), 900CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also idem, Politics in Hard Times (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1986)Google Scholar. Gourevitch's arguments about the impact of the world political economy on domestic coalitions first appeared in his “International Trade, Domestic Coalitions, and Liberty: Comparative Responses to the Crisis of1873–96,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 8 (Autumn 1977)Google Scholar.
31 Outstanding works include Cameron, David R., “The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis,” American Political Science Review 72 (December 1978)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Katzenstein, Peter J., Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1985)Google Scholar; Milner, Helen V., Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1988)Google Scholar; Rogowski, Ronald, Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989)Google Scholar; and Simmons, Beth A., Who Adjusts? Domestic Sources of Foreign Economic Policy during the Interwar Years (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994)Google Scholar.
32 Cooper, , The Economics of Interdependence: Economic Policy in the Atlantic Community (New York: McGraw Hill for the Council on Foreign Relations, 1968)Google Scholar; Kindleberger (fn. 2); Vernon, , Sovereignty at Bay (New York: Basic Books, 1971)Google Scholar.
33 Cooper, Richard N., “Economic Interdependence and Foreign Policy in the Seventies,” World Politics 24 (January 1972)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
34 Keohane and Nye (fh. 10), 379.
35 Huntington, , “Transnational Organizations in World Politics,” World Politics 25 (April 1973), 368CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
36 Krasner, , “Are Bureaucracies Important?” Foreign Policy, no. 7 (1972), commenting on Allison, Graham T., Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis (Boston: Little, Brown, 1971)Google Scholar. Allison was also at Harvard.
37 As I sought to do in “The Theory of Hegemonic Stability” (fn. 13).
38 As Stephen Krasner recalls, Joseph Nye was a recently tenured member of the Harvard faculty at that time but did not stifle discussion.
39 Frieden, and Rogowski, , “The Impact of the International Economy on National Policies: An Analytical Overview,” in Keohane, Robert O. and Milner, Helen V., eds., Internationalization and Domestic Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996)Google Scholar.
40 “Ibid., 35.
41 See especially the chapters in Keohane and Milner (fn. 39) on Europe by Geoffrey Garrett, on Japan by Frances Rosenbluth, on the Soviet Union and Russia by Matthew Evangelista, and on several developing countries by Stephan Haggard and Sylvia Maxfield.
42 Garrett and Lange, “Internationalization, Institutions, and Political Change,” in Keohane and Miher(fn.39).
43 Levi, , Of Rule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988)Google Scholar, esp. chap. 2, “The Theory of Predatory Rule.”