Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T03:06:44.809Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Explaining Capital Account Liberalization in Latin America: A Transitional Cost Approach

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2011

Sarah M. Brooks
Affiliation:
Ohio State University
Get access

Abstract

In the past three decades governments around the world have lowered barriers to international capital flows. This movement is widely attributed to the forces of globalization, as developed nations moved toward relative convergence on international financial openness. Yet developing nations with much to gain from openness to foreign investment moved only hesitantly and inconsistently in this direction. Analysis of two decades of capital account liberalization in Latin America and the OECD reveals that nations in Latin America with weaker domestic financial sectors face higher risks of transitional dislocations following liberalization and move less aggressively toward openness. In the OECD, by contrast, financial weakness is associated with greater movements toward capital account opening, as transitional costs are lower and governments are better equipped to ameliorate them. Examination of the transitional costs of liberalization thus helps to explain how market pressures may impede, rather than promote, market-oriented reform in Latin America.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Trustees of Princeton University 2004

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 The capital account is that portion of a country's balance of payments on which flows of capital (debt, equity, direct and real estate investment) are recorded across borders. Eichengreen, Barry et al. , “Liberalizing Capital Movements: Some Analytical Issues,” Economic Issues 17 (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 1999), 2.Google Scholar

2 Goodman, John B. and Pauly, Louis W. “The Obsolescence of Capital Controls? Economic Management in an Age of Global Markets,” World Politics 46 (October 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Keohane, Robert and Nye, Joseph, “Globalization: What's New? What's Not? (And So What?),” Foreign Policy 118 (Spring 2000)Google Scholar; Solomon, Robert, Money on the Move: The Revolution in International Finance since 1980 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999), 110-11Google Scholar.

3 These transactions refer to international currency, over-the-counter, and derivative transactions; Bank of International Settlements, “Consolidated International Banking Statistics for End-1997” (Basel, Switzerland: Bank for International Settlements, May 1998)Google Scholar, available at http://www.bis.org/publ/r_hy9805.htm.

4 See Edison, H., Klein, M., Ricci, L., and Sloek, T., “Capital Account Liberalization and Economic Performance,” Working Paper 9100 (Cambridge, Mass.: NBER, 2002), 6;CrossRefGoogle Scholar Klein, Michael and Olivei, Giovanni, “Capital Account Liberalization, Financial Depth and Economic Growth,” Working Paper 7384 (Cambridge, Mass.: NBER, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 I am grateful to Leo Bartolini for generously sharing these data. See Bartolini, Leonardo and Drazen, Allan, “When Liberal Policies Reflect External Shocks, What Do We Learn?” Journal of International Economics 42 (May 1997)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 At the same time, the European Union's exchange rate mechanism and OECD accords conduced toward this end. Goodman and Pauly (fn. 2); Boix, Carles, “Partisan Governments, the International Economy, and Macroeconomic Policies in Advanced Nations, 1960-93,” World Politics 53 (October 2000), 40;CrossRefGoogle Scholar Quinn, Dennis and Inclan, Carla, “The Origins of Financial Openness,” American Journal of Political Science 41 (July 1997)Google Scholar; Alesina, Alberto, Grilli, Vittorio, and Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, “The Political Economy of Capital Controls,” Working Paper 4353 (Cambridge, Mass.: NBER, 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Grilli, Vittorio and Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, “Economic Effects and Structural Determinants of Capital Controls,” Working Papers 95/31 (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 1995)Google Scholar; Oatley, Thomas, “How Constraining Is Capital Mobility?” American Journal of Political Science 43 (October 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Solomon (fn.2), 5.

7 Boix (fn. 6), 40.

8 Griffith-Jones, Stephany, Gottschalk, Ricardo, and Cailloux, Jacques, Preface, in Griffith-Jones, Stephany, Gottschalk, Ricardo, and Cailloux, Jacques, eds., International Capital Flows in Calm andTurbu-lant Times (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2003), xvii.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 Here underdeveloped financial sector implies poor regulatory and oversight structures. Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache find that where prudential regulations are weak or inoperative, financial liberalization is more likely to result in banking crisis. Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Enrica Detragiache, “Financial Liberalization and Financial Fragility,” Working Paper 1917 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, May 1998).

10 Przeworki, Adam, Democracy and the Market (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 Eichengreen, Barry and Mussa, Michael, “Capital Account Liberalization and the IMF,” Finance and Development 35 (December 1998)Google Scholar.

12 To make matters worse, the real economy suffered from foreign competition rooted in the overvalued exchange rate sustained by heavy inflows of capital. Ffrench-Davis, Ricardo, Economic Reforms in Chile: From Dictatorship to Democracy (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 2002), 114CrossRefGoogle Scholar, 104.

13 Lending within major economic groups in Chile led furthermore to a vast concentration of resources. Ffrench-Davis (fn. 12), 122.

14 Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos, “Goodbye Financial Repression, Hello Financial Crash,” Journal of Development Economics 19 (1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Fischer, Bernhard and Reisen, Helmut, “Toward Capital Account Convertibility,” OECD Development Centre, Policy Brief 4 (1992), 10Google Scholar. To opponents of the market-oriented economic program, the collapse and nationalization of the banking sector was dubbed “the Chicago road to socialism.”

15 Baldacci, Emanuele, Mello, Luiz de, and Inchauste, Gabriela, “Financial Crises, Poverty and Income Distribution,” Working Paper 02/4 (Washington, D.C: International Monetary Fund, 2002)Google Scholar.

16 See Bartolini and Drazen (fn. 5).

17 Leblang, David “Domestic and Systemic Determinants of Capital Controls in the Developed and Developing World,” International Studies Quarterly 41 (September 1997)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Haggard, Stephan and Maxfield, Sylvia, “The Political Economy of Financial Internationalization in the Developing World,” International Organization 50 (Winter 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lukauskas, Arvid and Minushkin, Susan, “Explaining Styles of Financial Market Opening in Chile, Mexico, South Korea and Turkey,” International Studies Quarterly 44 (March 2000)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bartolini and Drazen (fn. 5).

18 There are net private capital flows to developing countries; Solomon (fn. 2), 113. Low international interest rates account for a significant portion of capital movements to developing countries during this period.

19 Guitian, Manuel, “Reality and the Logic of Capital Flow Liberalization,” in Ries, Christine and Sweeny, Richard, eds., Capital Controls in Emerging Economies (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1997)Google Scholar; Williamson, John, “Orthodoxy Is Right: Liberalize the Capital Account Last,” in Ries, and Sweeny, , 1316Google Scholar; Calvo, Guillermo and Mendoza, Enrique, “Contagion, Globalization and the Volatility of Capital Flows,” in Edwards, Sebastian, ed., Capital Flows and the Emerging Economies (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000)Google Scholar.

20 Baldacci, de Mello, and Inchauste (fn. 15).

21 According to Edison et al. (fn. 4), among the developing countries that had “any experience with open capital accounts over the period 1976-95, the only countries where capital accounts were not closed after having been opened were Indonesia and Malaysia.” Subsequently, during the Asian financial crisis, Malaysia closed its capital account (p. 6).

22 Outflows of capital may include residents' purchases of foreign assets or repayment of foreign loans, while inflows include nonresidents' assets such as loans and investments in property and financial instruments; Eichengreen et al. (fn. 1).

23 Bartolini and Drazen (fn. 5).

24 Dailami, Mansoor, “Managing Risks of Capital Mobility” (Manuscript, World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1999), 22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

25 Goodman and Pauly (fn. 2); Lukauskas and Minushkin (fn. 17), 699-700.

26 Simmons, Beth “”The Internationalization of Capital,” in Kitschelt, Herbert et al. , Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999)Google Scholar.

27 Caprio, Gerald, Hanson, James, and Honohan, Patrick, “Introduction and Overview: The Case for Liberalization and Some Drawbacks,” in Caprio, Gerald, Honohan, Patrick, and Stiglitz, Joseph E., eds., Financial Liberalization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 Solomon (fn. 2).

29 Dailami (fn. 24); Guitián (fn. 19), 23; Bartolini and Drazen “Capital Account Liberalization as a Signal,” Working Paper 5725 (Cambridge, Mass.: NBER, 1996); Richard Sweeny, “The Information Costs of Capital Controls,” in Ries and Sweeny (fn. 19); Sebastian Edwards, “Capital Mobility and Economic Performance: Are Emerging Economies Different?” Working Paper 8076 (Cambridge, Mass.: NBER, 2001); McKibbin, Warwick J., International Capital Flows, Financial Reform and Consequences of Changing Risk Perceptions in APEC Economies, Brookings Discussion Papers in Internationa Economics 148 (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, September 1999)Google Scholar.

30 See Hirschman, Albert O., Exit, Voice and Loyalty (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970)Google Scholar; Lindblom, Charles, Politics and Markets (New York: Basic Books, 1977)Google Scholar; Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael, “Structural Dependence of the State on Capital,” American Political Science Review 82 (March 1988)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bates, Robert and Lien, Donald, “A Note on Taxation, Development, and Representative Government,” Politics and Society 14, no. 1 (1985), 59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

31 Andrews, David, “Capital Mobility and State Autonomy,” International Studies Quarterly 38 (June 1994)Google Scholar; Kurzer, Paulette, Business and Banking (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993)Google Scholar; Moses, Jonathan, “The Abdication from National Autonomy,” Politics and Society 22 (1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Webb, Michael, The Political Economy of Policy Coordination (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1995)Google Scholar.

32 Garrett, Geoffrey and Lange, Peter, “Political Responses to Interdependence: What's Left for the Left?” International Organization 45 (Autumn 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Garrett, Geoffrey, Partisan Politics in the Global Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mosley, Layna, “Room to Move: International Finance and National Welfare States,” International Organization 54 (2000)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Boix (fn. 6); Oatley (fh. 6); Weiss, Linda, The Myth of the Powerless State (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1998).Google Scholar

33 Lukauskas and Minushkin (fn. 17).

34 Stallings, Barbara, “International Influence on Economic Policy,” in Haggard, Stephan and Kaufman, Robert, eds., The Politics of Economic Adjustment (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992)Google Scholar.

35 Gnndle, Menlee S. and Thomas, John W., Public Choices and Policy Change: The Political Economy of Reform in Developing Countries (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991)Google Scholar; Williamson, John, ed., Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1990)Google Scholar.

36 Haggard and Maxfield (fn. 17). The time series in their analysis ends, however, in 1990.

37 Chile reduced its unremunerated reserve requirements to zero in 1998 as economic conditions improved, but it has kept them on the books for future use; see Sebastian Edwards, “Capital Flows, Real Exchange Rates and Capital Controls,” in Edwards (fn. 19); Francisco Nadal-De Simone and Prirtta Sorsa, “A Review of Capital Account Restrictions in Chile in the 1990s,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper 52 (Washington, D.C.: IMF, April 1999). Lukauskas and Minushkin (fn. 17) argue that “strong economic conditions gave Chile's government the confidence to reopen its financial markets on its own terms” (p. 716).

38 Quinn, Dennis, “The Correlates of Change in International Financial Regulation,” American Political Science Review 91 (September 1997)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Alesina, Grilli, and Milesi-Ferretti (fn. 6).

39 Lopez-Meji'a, Alejandro, “Large Capital Flows: Causes, Consequences and Policy Responses,” Finance and Development 36 (September 1999)Google Scholar.

40 On political will, see Alesina, Grilli, and Milesi-Ferretti (fn. 6); on motivation, see Bartolini and Drazen (fn. 5).

41 For analysis of varying market constraints, see Mosley, Layna, Global Capital and National Governments (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

42 Przeworski (fn. 10) differentiates transitional and permanent effects of economic reform. For this study the distinction is set aside, as it becomes difficult for voters and investors to distinguish between the effects (p. 146).

43 See, however, Hellman, Joel S., “Winners Take All: The Politics of Partial Reform in Postcom-munist Transitions,” World Politics 50 (January 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Brooks, Sarah, “Social Protection and Economic Integration: The Politics of Pension Reform in an Era of Capital Mobility,” Comparative Political Studies 35 (June 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

44 Przeworski (fn. 10), 147; Hellman (fn. 43); Brooks (fn. 43); Mesa-Lago, Carmelo and Müller, Katharina, “The Politics of Pension Reform in Latin America, “Journal of Latin American Studies 34 (August 2002)Google Scholar.

45 Fernando Lefort and Eduardo Walker, “The Past and the Future of Domestic Financial Markets in Latin America” (Paper presented at the Conference on Domestic Finance and Global Capital in Latin America, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, November 1-2,2001), 3, available at www.frbatlanta. org.

46 Williamson (fn. 19), 15; Klein, and Olivei, (fn. 4); Calvo, Guillermo and Mendoza, Enrique, “Capital-Markets Crises and Economic Collapse in Emerging Markets: An Informational-Frictions Approach,” American Economics Association Papers and Proceedings 90 (May 2000), 5964Google Scholar; Bhagwati, Jagdish, “The Capital Myth: The Difference between Trade in Widgets and Dollars,” Foreign Affairs (May-June 1998), 712CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rodrik, Dani, “Who Needs Capital-Account Convertibility?” (Manuscript, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, 1998)Google Scholar.

47 Eichengreen, Barry and Leblang, David, “Capital Account Liberalization and Growth: Was Mr. Mahathir Right?” NBER Working paper 9427 (Cambridge, Mass.: NBER January 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli and Detragiache, Enrica, “The Determinants of Banking Crises: Evidence from Industrial and Developing Countries,” Policy Research Working Paper 1828 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1997)Google Scholar; Easterly, William, Islam, Roumeen, and Stiglitz, Joseph, “Shaken and Stirred: Explaining Growth Volatility” (Paper presented at the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics, World Bank, Washington, D.C., April 2000)Google Scholar.

48 Hausmann and Gavin found the standard deviation of international trade in Latin America has been approximately twice as high as that in industrialized countries over the past twenty years; Hausmann, Ricardo and Gavin, M., “Securing Stability and Growth in a Shock Prone Region: The Policy Challenge for Latin America,” Working Paper 315 (Washington, D.C.: Inter-American Development Bank, 1996)Google Scholar.

49 On the exogenous sources of capital inflows, see Calvo, Guillermo, Leiderman, Leonardo, and Reinhart, Carmen, “Inflows of Capital to Developing Countries in the 1990s,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 (Spring 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Fernandez-Arias, Eduardo, “The New Wave of Private Capital Inflows: Push or Pull?” Journal of Development Economics 48 (March 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 For the inflationary effects of openness, see Guitian, Manuel, “The Challenge of Managing Global Capital Flows,” Finance and Development 35 (June 1998)Google Scholar.

51 Countries are no less vulnerable to external shocks where the governments has committed to a peg or currency board. In this case, quelling outflows of capital involves either drawing down foreign currency reserves or raising domestic interest rates. While the former constrains the ability of the government to defend the currency peg, the latter increases the likelihood of default in the domestic financial sector. To the extent that increased volatility in terms of trade diminishes the ability of domestic producers to service existing loans, higher interest rates threaten to push the domestic financial sector further toward crisis. Goldstein, Morris and Turner, Phillip, “Banking Crises in Emerging Economies: Origins and Policy Options,” BIS Economic Papers 46 (October 1996), 9.Google Scholar

52 Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria and Razin, Assaf, “Current Account Reversals and Currency Crisis-Empirical Regularities,” IMF Working Papers 98/89 (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

53 Kaminsky, Graciela and Reinhart, Carmen, “The Twin Crises: Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems,” American Economic Review 89 (June 1999), 4CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Myriam Quispe-Agnoli and Elizabeth McQuerry, “Measuring Financial Liberalization in Latin America” (Paper presented at the Conference on Domestic Finance and Global Capital in Latin America, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, November 1-2,2001), 23.

54 Williamson (fn. 19).

55 Higher fiscal deficits may also be harmful to domestic banks, as increased interest rates prevent access to credit by potential private sector borrowers; Quispe-Agnoli and McQuerry (fn. 53), 4.

56 Like terms of trade fluctuations, foreign-exchange volatility for developing countries is typically much greater than it is for industrialized countries in the wake of financial liberalization; see Haus-mann and Gavin (fn. 49). Procyclical flows exaggerate the effects of these shocks. Rogerio Studart, “The Banking System and Credit in Argentina, Brazil, Chile and Mexico” (Paper presented at the Conference on Domestic Finance and Global Capital in Latin America, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, November 1-2,2001), 1.

57 Goldstein and Turner (fn. 51) found that fluctuations in international interest rates explain one-half to one-third of the variation in capitalflowsto emerging markets in the 1990s (p. 10).

58 This may be either a liquidity crisis or a financial crisis, depending upon the situation; Studart (fn. 56).

59 Bartolini and Drazen (fn. 29).

60 Author interview with Amaury Bier, executive secretary of the Ministry of Finance (Ministério da Fazenda), Brasilia, Brazil, June 1999.

61 The structural pension reform would create a financing gap in the pay-as-you-go system, as workers began diverting payroll contributions to individual accounts. Author interviews with officials in Social Security and Finance Ministries and with authors of the pension reform proposal, Brasilia and Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 1998-99.

62 Indicators focus on macroeconomic criteria, including country income, inflation history, government finances, and political risk; see Cantor, Richard and Packer, Frank, “Determinants and Impacts of Sovereign Credit Ratings,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Research Paper 9608 (New York: FRBNY, 1996)Google Scholar; International Monetary Fund, International Capital Markets (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 1999)Google Scholar.

63 Sobel, Andrew, State Institutions, Private Incentives, Global Capital (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Haque, Nadeem Ul, Mathieson, Donald, and Mark, Nelson, “Rating the Raters of Country Creditworthiness,” Finance and Development 34 (March 1997), 1013.Google Scholar

64 Reinhart found that in the twelve months following a crisis, credit-rating downgrades for developing countries were five times greater than for developed nations; Carmen Reinhart “Sovereign Credit Ratings before and after Financial Crises” (Manuscript, February 2001), www.puaf.umd. edu/papers/reinhart.htm.

65 The price refers to the interest rate spread over the LIBOR (London Inter-Bank Offered Rate). Ul Haque, Mathieson, and Mark (fn. 63).

66 IMF, Private Market Financing for Developing Countries, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 1992), 64.Google Scholar

67 For strength of the financial sector, see Klein and Olivei (fn. 4).

68 Meyer, Lawrence, “Financial Stability in Emerging Markets: What Have We Accomplished and What Remains to Be Done?” BIS Review 102 (2001), 1.Google Scholar

69 Inter-American Development Bank, “Legacy the MIF Inherited: The Context of Financial Reform and Capital Markets,” Multilateral Investment Fund, vol. 2, Inter-American Development Bank (2002), http://www.iadb.org/mif/V2/, p.3, emphasis in original.

70 Eichengreen and Leblang (fn. 47), 2.

71 Mever (fn. 68).

72 Goldstein and Turner (fn. 51), 7-8.

73 Sterilization involves measures by the central bank to offset the effects of capital inflows on domestic monetary variables (such as money supply and interest rates). Purchases or sales of domestic securities, for instance, are offset by sales or purchases of foreign exchange by the central bank. Kaminsky, Graciela, Lizondo, Saul, and Reinhart, Carmen, “Leading Indicators of Currency Crises,” IMF Staff Papers 45 (Washington, D.C.: IMF, March 1998)Google Scholar; Cantor and Packer (fn. 62).

74 Goodman and Pauly (fn. 2), 57.

75 Haggard and Maxfield (fn. 17), 37; Goodman and Pauly (fn. 2).

76 See Organización Internacional del Trabajo, Panorama Laboral (Lima, Peru: Oficina Regional para Las Americas, 1999)Google Scholar, http://www.oit.org.pe/. Quinn and Inclan (fn. 6) argue that even in the developed world, wage benefits for unskilled workers are difficult to obtain and are modest relative to those of highly skilled laborers (p. 776). On inequality, see Quinn (fn. 38); Kose, Prasad, andTerrones report that while output volatility declines in morefinanciallyintegrated economies, consumption volatility increases; see Ayhan Kose, M., Prasad, Eswar, and Terrones, Marco, “Financial Integration and Macroeconomic Volatility” (Paper presented at third annual IMF Research Conference on Capital Flows and Global Governance, Washington, D.C., November 7-8, 2002), 2,Google Scholar www.imf.org.

77 Rodrik, Dani and Ypersele, Tanguy van, “Capital Mobility, Distributive Conflict and International Tax Coordination” (Manuscript, 1999), 1.Google Scholar

78 Kessler, Timothy P., “Political Capital: Mexican Financial Policy under Salinas,” World Politics 51 (October 1998), 64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

79 Garrett (fn.32).

80 Murillo, M. Victoria, “Political Bias in Policy Convergence: Privatization Choices in Latin America,” World Politics 54 (July 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

81 Quinn and Inclán (fn. 6). Similarly, Rodrik and van Ypersele (fn. 72) argue that without international coordination on capital taxation, capital mobility may not be a political equilibrium when workers are politically influential.

82 In July 2002 Brazil's EMBI+ spread over comparable U.S. Treasuries went beyond 2400 basis points, far above the 830 bps in January 2002. After the first round of voting, the bond spread reached 2250 bps. Charles Roth, “Emerging Market Giants Distance Themselves from Brazil Woes,” Dow Jones Newswires (October 11,2002), http://www.latinpetroleurn.com/article_214.shtml.

83 Boix (fn. 6), 57.

84 Chinn, Menzie and Ito, Hiro, “Capital Account Liberalization, Institutions and Financial Development: Cross-Country Evidence” (Manuscript, University of California, Santa Cruz, May 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

85 Major alternatives to Chinn and Ito's index, which include more than one region or decade, include Klein and Olivei's SHARE, which measures the proportion of years in which capital controls are present (fn. 4), and Quinn's index, which measures intensity of capital controls in a 0-4 point scale. Quinn's data are not coded for continuous years, however, and thus are not amenable to time-series analysis employed in this study, see Quinn (fn. 38).

86 Beck, Thorsten, Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, and Levine, Ross, “A New Database on Financial Development and Structure” (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, June 1999)Google Scholar. This variable has also been used by King, Robert and Levine, Ross, “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 3 (August 1993), 108Google Scholar; Levine, Ross, Loayza, Norman, and Beck, Thorsten, Financial Intermediation and Growth: Causality and Causes, World Bank Policy Research Paper 2059 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, February 1998)Google Scholar; Klein and Olivei (fn. 4); Chinn and Ito (fn. 84).

87 Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (fn. 86).

88 Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache (fn. 47); Kaminsky and Reinhart (fn. 53).

89 Kaufman, Robert R. and Segura-Ubiergo, Alex, “Globalization, Domestic Politics, and Social Spending in Latin America: A Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis, 1973-97,” World Politics 53 (July 2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

90 See Swank, Duane, “Codebook for 21-Nation Pooled Time-Series Data Set: Political Strength of Political Parties by Ideological Group in Capitalist Democracies,” http://www.marquette.edu/ polisci/Swank.htm (accessed November 6, 2003)Google Scholar.

91 Where social protection systems are better funded in Latin America, increased spending in one area, such as unemployment, will on average leave more resources available to fund other social policies, such as job training, disability, and pensions.

92 Importantly, this measure is included in all specifications of the empirical model along with the ratio of private sector assets.

93 Eichengreen and Leblang (fn. 47), 2.

94 A notable exception is Venezuela, which issued rated sovereign debt since 1977; Standard and Poor's, “Sovereign Ratings History since 1975” (December 2002), www.standardandpoors.com.

95 Cantor and Packer (fn. 62).

96 Grilli and Milesi-Feretti (fn. 6); Chinn and Ito (fn. 84) also argue that rapid price changes can cause distortions in economic decision making and that high and moderate inflation discourage financial intermediation.

97 I am grateful to an anonymous reviewer for this observation.

98 See Goodman and Pauly (fn. 2); Klein and Olivei (fn. 4); Bartolini and Drazen (fn. 5); Edison et al. (fn. 4); and also Johnson, Barry and Tamirisa, Natalia, “Why Do Countries Use Capital Controls?” IMF Working Paper 98/181 (Washington, D.C.: IMF, December 1998)Google Scholar.

99 An important drawback of this measure, however, is its failure to capture the government's ability to finance budgetary outlays. Indeed, high government consumption in the OECD nations may represent political commitments to social welfare, rather than simply a lack offiscaldiscipline and financial repression. A measure of the overall state budget balance as a percentage of GDP was included as a control in the empirical analysis but was dropped due to a failure of significance and high collinearity with GovCon. See Johnson and Tamirisa (fn. 98); Chinn and Ito (fn. 84).

100 For government consumption and capital controls, see also Chinn and Ito (fn. 84); Grilli and Milesi-Feretti (fn. 6); Klein and Olivei (fn. 4), 17.

101 Haggard and Maxfield (fn. 17), 37.

102 Chinn and Ito (fn. 84), 4.

103 Grilli and Milesi-Feretti argue that low real interest rates are a sign offinancialmarket repression and thus of the weakness of the domestic financial sector; Grilli and Milesi-Feretti (fn. 6); see also Johnson and Taminsa (fn. 98).

104 Klein and Olivei (fn. 4) 15.

105 Bias might arise from the evidence that financial crises have strongly deleterious effects on domestic banking sectors, and may also alter government disposition toward capital account liberalization. See Klein and Olivei (fn. 4); for debate on the effect of crisis on capital regulation, see also Haggard and Maxfield (fn. 17).

106 Klein and Olivei (fn. 4) and Chinn and Ito (fn. 84) include country and region fixed effects. However, the drawback to using fixed effects is that such measures treat nation-specific heterogeneity as a constant over the period of observation.

107 An alternative to censored regression for analyzing continuous, but bounded dependent variables is the use of a logistic transformation ln(x/l - x). There are several reasons why such a transformation is not optimal in this case, however, including the absence of theoretical grounding for the imposition of the logistic functional form on the data. At the same time, OLS regression on logistic transformations of bounded dependent variables has been shown to be inefficient and biased. See Manning, Richard, “Logit Regressions with Continuous Dependent Variables Measured with Error,” Applied Economics Letters 3 (1996), 183–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sapra, Sunil, “Bias and Inefficiency of an Ordinary Least Squares Estimator for Logit Regressions with Continuous Dependent Variables Measured with Error,” Applied Economics Letters 5 (1998), 745–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

108 For the standard Tobit, where data are censored at 0, the extent and direction of bias can be shown to be downward and in proportion to the degree of censoring. This proof does not hold in the case of censoring at a point other than zero, as in the case of the present analysis. Sigelman, Lee and Zeng, Langche, “Analyzing Censored and Sample-Selected Data with Tobit and Heckit Models,” Political Analysis 8, no. 2 (2000), 175.Google Scholar For the bias introduced by OLS regression on censored data, see also Greene, William, “On the Asymptotic Bias of the Ordinary Least Squares Estimator of the Tobit Model,” Econometrica 49 (March 1981), 505–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

109 For discussion of the likelihood model of the two-limit Tobit, see Maddala, G. S., Limited Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1983), 160–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

110 This is an unconditional fixed effects Tobit model, which can be estimated with country indicator variables with Stata 7, which does not have a command for a parametric conditional fixed-effects model; Stata 7, vol. 4 [Su-Z] (2001), 474.

111 Sigelman and Zeng (fn. 108), 170; Long, J. Scott, Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables (Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage, 1997), 207–8Google Scholar.

112 Maddala, G. S., Introduction to Econometrics, 2nd ed. (New York: Macmillan, 1992), 341;Google Scholar cf. Sigel-man and Zeng (fn. 108), 170. Sigelman and Zeng demonstrate that the use of the Tobit in the absence of censoring can produce biased estimates, dramatically altering patterns of significance. In this case, Tables 1 and 2 estimate both the OECD and the Latin America core model specifications in Tobit and FGLS, and the patterns of significance remain the same. Nevertheless, based on Maddala's proof, we assume that the FGLS estimates for Latin America are unbiased and efficient, while the Tobit estimates are the same for the OECD.

113 Given the well-known characteristics of time-series data, namely, temporally and spatially correlated errors, ordinary least squares methods may be problematic for the regression analysis. I employ a variant of feasible generalized least squares (FGLS) regression that produces point estimates on the basis of estimations of the autocorrelation parameter. In this case, I assume an AR(1) process and correct for country-specific heteroskedasticity. This method produces coefficients that are interpretable just as OLS estimates. Beck, Nathaniel and Katz, Jonathan, “What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data,” American Political Science Review 89 (September 1995)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kmenta, J., Elements of Econometrics, 2nd ed. (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997), 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar All confidence intervals reported are two-tailed.

114 I follow Chinn and Ito (fn. 84) in the use of lags of the independent variables to diminish the possibility of reverse causation and to diminish cyclical correlations.

115 Greene, William H., Econometric Analysis (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1993), 435.Google Scholar

116 Edison et al. (fn. 4).

117 Quinn and Inclan (fn. 6); Kastner, Scott and Rector, Chad “Partisan and Electoral Cycles in Capital Controls Policies” (Manuscript, 2002)Google Scholar. Alternatively, the coefficient on partisanship in the OECD may reveal the effect of a missing variable, such as unionization. As Garrett and Lange argue (fn. 32), the context of high union density and centralization allows governments of the left to adopt more market-oriented measures than right governments can in the same contexts.

118 Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (fn. 86) point out that in developing countries, the central bank typically plays a more important role than private institutions in allocating resources in the economy.

119 Cameron, David, “The Expansion of the Public Economy,” American Political Science Review 72, no. 4 (1978)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Katzenstein, Peter, Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Eurcpe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1985)Google Scholar.

120 In the OECD nations, by contrast, the level of foreign currency reserves (Reserves) is negatively and significantly associated with capital account openness across specifications in Table 1, lending evidence to the view that balance-of-payments needs generate an important source of pressure for inter-nationalfinancialopening; see Johnson andTamirisa (fn. 98).

121 Quinn (fn. 38), 534.

122 Diaz-Alejandro (fn. 14), 10–11.