Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T01:59:04.396Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Credibility, Costs, and Institutions: Cooperation on Economic Sanctions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2011

Lisa L. Martin
Affiliation:
Harvard University
Get access

Extract

The conditions under which states will cooperate to impose economic sanctions are of both theoretical and practical interest. Generally, when sanctions are used, one state takes the lead in organizing and imposing them. Other states have incentives to free ride on the “leading sender's” efforts. To gain cooperation, the leading sender uses tactical issue-linkage in the form of either threats or side payments. The success of cooperation depends on the credibility of these issue-linkages. The use of high-cost sanctions and international institutions raises the potential for high audience costs if the leading sender reneges. These policies thus indicate credible commitments. Data on ninety-nine cases of post-1945 economic sanctions show that costly measures coincide with high levels of international cooperation.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Trustees of Princeton University 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Jentleson, Bruce, Pipeline Politics: The Complex Political Economy of East-West Energy Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1986)Google Scholar; Blinken, Antony J., Ally versus Ally: America, Europe, and the Siberian Pipeline Crisis (New York: Praeger, 1987)Google Scholar; Crawford, Beverly and Lenway, Stefanie, “Decision Modes and International Regime Change: Western Collaboration on East-West Trade,” World Politics 37 (April 1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Baldwin, David A., Economic Statecraft (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1985), 278–89.Google Scholar

2 Knorr, Klaus, “International Economie Leverage and Its Uses,” in Knorr, and Trager, Frank N., eds., Economic Issues and National Security (Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 1977)Google Scholar; Paarlberg, Robert L., “Food, Oil, and Coercive Resource Power,” International Security 3 (Fall 1978)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wolff, OttoAmerongen, von, “Economic Sanctions as a Foreign Policy Tool?International Security 5 (Fall 1980).Google Scholar

3 Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, Schott, Jeffrey J., and Elliott, Kimberly Ann, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2d ed., 2 vols. (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1990).Google Scholar

4 See Dobson, Alan P., “The Kennedy Administration and Economic Warfare against Communism,” International Affairs (Autumn 1988)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stern, Paula, Water's Edge (Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press, 1979)Google Scholar; Haig, Alexander, Caveat: Reagan, Realism, and Foreign Policy (New York: Macmillan, 1984), 248–52.Google Scholar

5 Martin, Lisa L., “Institutions and Cooperation: Sanctions during the Falkland Islands Conflict,” International Security 16 (Spring 1992).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6 Hufbauer, Schott, and Elliott (fn. 3), 2:247–59.

7 Schoultz, Lars, Human Rights and United States Policy toward Latin America (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1981), chaps. 57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 This result may be due in part to selection bias that results from only examining realized cases of economic sanctions. There may have been cases in which such asymmetry did not obtain, no state took the lead in imposing sanctions (in hopes that someone else would), and no sanctions were imposed. Given this kind of collective action problem, it is possible that sanctions never get organized without a leading sender even if they are Pareto-superior to no action. If this is so, situations without a leading sender will never make it into a data set on economic sanctions, which yields the empirical pattern found in studies of sanctions.

9 Baldwin (fn. 1), 174–89.

10 Keohane, Robert O., After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984)Google Scholar; Oye, Kenneth A., ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986)Google Scholar; Axelrod, Robert, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984)Google Scholar; Krasner, Stephen D., ed., International Regimes (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983)Google Scholar; Stein, Arthur A., Why Nations Cooperate: Circumstance and Choice in International Relations (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990).Google Scholar For a review of the literature on cooperation, see Milner, Helen, “International Theories of Cooperation among Nations: Strengths and Weaknesses,” World Politics 44 (April 1992).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

11 Kindleberger, Charles P., The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973)Google Scholar; Krasner, Stephen D., “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics 28 (April 1976)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Keohane, Robert O., “The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Changes in International Economic Regimes, 1967–1977,” in Holsti, Ole et al., Change in the International System (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1980)Google Scholar; Snidai, Duncan, “The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory,” International Organization 39 (Autumn 1985)Google Scholar; Russett, Bruce, “The Mysterious Case of Vanishing Hegemony: Or, Is Mark Twain Really Dead?International Organization 39 (Spring 1985).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 Grieco, Joseph M., Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990)Google Scholar; Krasner, Stephen D., “Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier,” World Politics 43 (April 1991).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 In addition to the work of political scientists on credibility, there is a large economic literature on this subject. See, e.g., Spence, Michael, Market Signaling (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1974)Google Scholar; Persson, Torsten and Tabellini, Guido, Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics (New York: Harwood Academic Publishers, 1990)Google Scholar; Alesina, Alberto, “Credibility and Policy Convergence in a Two-Party System with Rational Voters,” American Economic Review 78 (September 1988)Google Scholar; Kreps, David M., “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory,” in Alt, James E. and Shepsle, Kenneth A., eds., Perspectives on Positive Political Economy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990).Google Scholar

14 Martin, Lisa L., Coercive Cooperation: Explaining Multilateral Economic Sanctions (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992), chap. 2.Google Scholar

15 Stein, Arthur A., “The Politics of Linkage,” World Politics 33 (October 1980).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 Tollison, Robert D. and Willett, Thomas D., “An Economic Theory of Mutually Advantageous Issue Linkage in International Negotiations,” International Organization 33 (Autumn 1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sebenius, James K., “Negotiation Arithmetic: Adding and Subtracting Issues and Parties,” International Organization 37 (Spring 1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17 Oye, Kenneth A., “The Domain of Choice: International Constraints and Carter Administration Foreign Policy,” in Oye, , Rothchild, Donald, and Lieber, Robert J., eds., Eagle Entangled: U.S. Foreign Policy in a Complex World (New York: Longman, 1979).Google Scholar

18 Axelrod, Robert and Keohane, Robert O., “Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions,” in Oye (fn. 10), 240.Google Scholar

19 Ibid.; Schelling, Thomas C., The Strategy of Conflict (New York: Oxford University Press, 1960), 3132Google Scholar; Haas, Ernst B., “Why Collaborate? Issue-Linkage and International Regimes,” World Politics 32 (April 1980), 372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

20 Putnam, Robert D., “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics,” International Organization 42 (Summer 1988).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

21 Firms lobbied their representatives heavily to decrease the stringency of sanctions, which suggests that escalating the conflict to a trade war would not receive legislative support. In fact, bills were introduced calling for an end to the unilateral U.S. measures. See Congressional Record, 97th Cong., 2d sess., July 22,1982, p. E3429; Congressional Quarterly, August 14, 1982, p. 1961; Congressional Record, 97th Cong., 2d sess., September 29, 1982, pp. H7927–30; Congressional Quarterly, October 2, 1982, p. 2467.

22 For a rigorous development of a similar argument about audience costs in the context of deterrence and the original development of the concept of audience costs, see James D. Fearon, “Deterrence and the Spiral Model: The Role of Costly Signals in Crisis Bargaining” (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, August 30-September 2, 1990).

23 Paarlberg (fn. 2).

24 Carter, Barry E., International Economie Sanctions: Improving the Haphazard U.S. Legal Regime (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 3.Google Scholar

25 Young, Oran R., “Political Leadership and Regime Formation: On the Development of Institutions in International Society,” International Organization 45 (Summer 1991), 291–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

26 Fearon (fn. 22).

27 Schelling, Thomas C., Arms and Influence (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966), 150.Google Scholar

28 However, when state interests are not as conflictual as in the case under consideration here, “cheap talk” may have a significant effect on outcomes. See Morrow, James D., “Modeling International Regimes” (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, August 30-September 2, 1990).Google Scholar

29 The model developed here focuses on a rational-choice approach to costs and credibility. This subject has also received attention from those adopting a psychological approach. See Jervis, Robert, The Logic of Images in International Relations (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1970)Google Scholar; Larson, Deborah Welch, “Order under Anarchy: The Emergence of Convention in U.S.-Soviet Relations” (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, Ga., August 31-September 3, 1989)Google Scholar; Hermann, Margaret G., Hermann, Charles F., and Hutchins, Gerald L., “Affect,” in Callahan, Patrick, Brady, Linda P., and Hermann, Margaret G., eds., Describing Foreign Policy Behavior (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1982).Google Scholar

30 Baldwin (fn. 1), 107–8.

31 Stern, Jonathan, East European Energy and East-West Trade in Energy (London: Policy Studies Institute, 1982), 78.Google Scholar

32 Keohane (fn. 10); Axelrod and Keohane (fn. 18), 226–54.

33 Rodrik, Dani, “Credibility of Trade Reform: A Policy Maker's Guide,” World Economy 12 (March 1989).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

34 Martin (fn. 5); Latin American Bureau, Falklands/Malvinas: Whose Crisis? (London: Latin American Bureau, 1982), 112.Google Scholar

35 Lipson, Charles, “Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?International Organization 45 (Autumn 1991), 509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar See also Baldwin (fn. 1), 108.

36 Keohane (fn. 10), 97.

37 Krasner, Stephen D., “Regimes and the Limits of Realism: Regimes as Autonomous Variables,” in Krasner (fn. 10), 364Google Scholar; Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S., Power and Inter-dependence (Boston: Little, Brown, 1977), 55.Google Scholar

38 Schelling (fn. 19), 51.

39 Sanford, Jonathan E., U.S. Policy and the Multilateral Banks: Politicization and Effectiveness, Staff Report to the U.S. Senate Foreign Relations Subcommittee on Foreign Assistance, May 1977Google Scholar; Schoultz (fn. 7), chap. 7.

40 This game could also be modeled with State A deciding whether to make side payments if B does impose sanctions. The equilibria are similar to those in this threat game.

41 This is one conclusion that clearly differs from what we would find in a signaling game. With incomplete information, one usually finds some equilibria that include the carrying out of threats.

42 New YorK Times, September 1, 1982, p. A1.

43 Although it is the most comprehensive descriptive study of sanctions to date, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered (fn. 3) has been criticized for some of its methods. Other students of economic sanctions have questioned in particular the definition and measurement of success. Hufbauer, Schott, and Elliott define success narrowly as a desired policy change in the target country; they constructed a 16-point scale that captures varying degrees of success. Baldwin, for one, disagrees with this definition; see Baldwin (fn. 1), 130–34. The 16-point scale also takes into account the contribution of sanctions to the observed change in policy, which perhaps is better left as a separate variable. Economic Sanctions Reconsidered also exhibits some weaknesses from a statistical perspective. Because the 16-point success scale is constructed by the multiplication of two 4-point scales, it is impossible for any case to achieve certain values, such as 7, 13, 14, and so forth. The results also do not meet the usual standards of statistical significance and examine only bivariate rather than multivariate relationships, so that correlations among the independent variables make the observed relationships unreliable. In this study, I do not use the success score but use only Hufbauer, Schott, and Elliott's measures of some independent variables, along with additional variables added to their data set. I also develop statistical techniques appropriate for the kinds of data used, rather than relying on bivariate correlations.

44 Note that COST is not intended as a direct measure of audience costs. Instead, it is an indicator of the strategy adopted by the leading sender, with higher levels of COST indicating a higher-cost strategy. This is assumed to lead to higher audience costs in case of reneging.

45 Hufbauer, Schott, and Elliott (fn. 3), 1:35

46 McKelvey, Richard and Zavoina, William, “A Statistical Model for the Analysis of Ordinal Dependent Variables,” Journal ofMathematical Sociology 4, no. 1 (1975).Google Scholar

47 Ordered probit assumes that the dependent variable, cooperation, is an unobserved linear function of the independent variables. While the precise level of cooperation is unobserved, ordered probit assumes that we can split the cooperation continuum into four parts and observe in which of the four each case lies. See King, Gary, Unifying Political Methodology: The Likelihood Theory of Statistical Inference (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989), 115–17.Google Scholar Thus, the third column in Table 2 refers to the expected score on the unobserved cooperation scale, while the fourth column translates this score into an expected value for the observed variable COOP.

48 King, Gary, “Event Count Models for International Relations: Generalizations and Applications,” International Studies Quarterly 33 (June 1989).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

49 King (fn. 47), 218–20.

50 Ibid., 126–29.

51 These values are calculated by substituting the estimated parameters and specified values of COSTD and INST into the systematic component of the negative binomial model as given in Equation 1.

52 As discussed above, the positive coefficient of gamma indicates positive contagion, thus making precise predictions of the expected number of cooperating countries impossible. This is reflected in large confidence intervals around the expected value of NUMBER. For example, in all cases in Table 4, the lower bound of a 95% confidence interval would include NUMBER = 1. Thus, the fitted values should not be taken as precise estimates but only illustrative of the logic of the event count model. More important for interpretive purposes are the estimated parameter coefficients.

53 Martin (fn. 14), chaps. 5–8.