Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T06:38:40.709Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The part-time wage penalty: Does bargaining coverage outweigh regional differences in Spain?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

Raul Ramos*
Affiliation:
Universitat de Barcelona, España
Esteban Sanromá
Affiliation:
Universitat de Barcelona, España
Hipólito Simón
Affiliation:
Universidad de Alicante, España
*
Raul Ramos, Department d’Econometria, Estadística i Economia Aplicada, Universitat de Barcelona, Av. Diagonal 690, 08034 Barcelona, España. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The use of part-time jobs is steadily increasing in most advanced economies. Previous literature has concluded that part-time workers suffer a wage penalty, but its magnitude varies across studies and countries. The part-time penalty is the otherwise unexplained element of the gap between full-time and part-time hourly earnings. One potential factor accounting for international differences in this penalty is the coverage of collective bargaining. This article outlines research examining wage differences between part-time and full-time male and female workers in Spain, a country with a very high level of coverage of collective agreements but very heterogeneous regional labour markets. Results are obtained using an econometric decomposition specifically adapted to matched employer–employee data. They show that intra-firm wage differentials for part- and full-time workers with the same characteristics are negligible. But results that are perhaps less expected are those based on the regional analysis – an unprecedented perspective compared with the previous literature. These results show that despite very significant differences in economies and labour markets, observed wage gaps between part-time and full-time workers in each Spanish region are also mainly explained by different endowments of individual, job and firm characteristics. Overall, our evidence highlights the over-riding role of wage setting mechanisms, specifically collective bargaining coverage, in minimising inter-regional differences in the wage penalty of part-time workers.

Type
Rethinking Precariousness and Flexibility
Copyright
© The Author(s) 2016

Introduction

The number of part-time jobs has increased slightly but continuously in most advanced economies over the last decades. The ratio over total employment of part-time workers in the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) increased from 13.9% in 1988 to 17.1% in 2013. Driving this type of employment are demand factors, such as the increasing importance of the service sector and fixed costs per employee, and also supply factors, like increasing women’s labour participation (Reference Euwals and HogerbruggeEuwals and Hogerbrugge, 2006; Reference MontgomeryMontgomery, 1988). Furthermore, many governments have seen part-time jobs as a way of responding to economic crisis and have propelled their growth, given that they offer greater flexibility to firms in the use of their labour force while at the same time facilitating job creation.

Part-time employment is usually considered as a component of the secondary labour market that grants flexibility to firms while providing opportunities for workers with low qualifications or less closely linked to employment. However, the international literature concludes that part-time workers suffer a wage penalty that differs across countries, probably owing to differences in the wage determination process and the characteristics of collective bargaining. In fact, in countries with lower coverage of the collective bargaining, the wage penalty is usually higher. The part-time wage penalty is defined as that proportion of the raw gap between the hourly wage of full-time and part-time employees that is not explained by other factors such as worker, job, firm or regional characteristics.

Figure 1 shows a clear relationship between the wage penalty found by different studies (summarised below) and the coverage of collective bargaining in the considered countries. Taking this into account, the objective of this article is twofold: first, to analyse the existence (or not) of a wage penalty for part-time workers in the Spanish labour market; second, to check whether there are differences in the penalty between Spanish regions. According to the previous exposition, our hypothesis is that, due to the high coverage of the collective bargaining, the wage penalty for part-time workers would be reduced, and moreover, if the size of this penalty is mainly driven by differences in labour market institutions related to collective wage bargaining, relevant regional differences would not be observed.

Figure 1. Average unexplained component of wage differentials between part-time and full-time workers and coverage of collective bargaining.

Country averages of wage penalties found in the literature for male part-time workers with similar specifications. Collective bargaining data refer to 2010 and have been obtained from ILOStat.

We begin by comparing changes in the incidence of part-time employment in Spain and Europe and by providing analysis of the Spanish regulatory framework and regional diversity, establishing the rationale for the investigation. A review of the relevant literature then provides the conceptual tools used to analyse the contribution to the size of the part-time wage penalty of collective bargaining coverage, relative to other factors. The fourth section presents the database and the econometric methodology. The fifth section outlines the findings, and the last section summarises the conclusions of the analysis.

Context and rationale

In Spain, although the incidence of part-time employment has traditionally been low (it increased from 4.2% in 1987 to 6.8% in 1995), it accelerated over more recent decades (10.8% in 2007 and 15.7% in 2015), propelled by a legal change approved in late 2013 allowing more flexibility in the number of working hours (International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2015). The recent economic crisis has represented a significant loss of jobs in Spain. Between 2008 and 2014, more than 3 million jobs (15% of 2008 employment levels) were destroyed. However, during these years, the number of part-time jobs increased by more than 350,000 people (a 14.7% increase over a 6-year period) (Instituto Nacional de Estadística (INE), 2016).

From an international perspective, the share of part-time workers in Spain is still a moderate figure, lower than the averages for the OECD (17.1%), the EU (European Union) (19.6%) and the Eurozone (21.5%). The traditionally low presence of part-time jobs in Spain is probably explained because its regulation has not been clear until very recently (Reference Fernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-PlanasFernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-Planas, 2010; Reference Muñoz de Bustillo, Fernández and AntónMuñoz de Bustillo et al., 2008), but also because Spanish firms have usually tended to achieve flexibility mainly through fixed-term contracts. On the other hand, it must be noted that a prominent characteristic of part-time employment in Spain is that, in contrast to most developed countries, it is mainly involuntary. Thus, according to Eurostat (2016a) figures for 2014, 64% of total part-time work in Spain was involuntary (70% for men and 62% for women), whereas the averages for the OECD, the EU and the Eurozone were 21% (23% for males and 20% for females), 29% (40% for males and 26% for females) and 32% (42% for males and 29% for females), respectively.

Although largely involuntary, part-time employment in Spain is on the whole highly regulated. The Spanish labour market follows the so-called Mediterranean model (Reference SapirSapir, 2005). Union density is relatively low (16%), but the coverage of collective agreements is very high, close to 80% (International Labour Office (ILO), 2015), as a result of the legal extension of collective agreements. Sectoral collective bargaining predominates, covering the 90% of employees covered by agreements, while firm level bargaining represents only 10%, although it has been clearly promoted by the 2012 labour reform. Regarding sectoral bargaining, although there are national sectoral collective agreements that apply throughout the Spanish territory, most sectoral agreements are negotiated at regional (NUTS (Nomenclature of Units for Territorial Statistics) 2 level) or, especially, provincial levels (NUTS 3). These agreements apply to all companies and workers in the sector and territory so that the coverage of collective bargaining is in general very high in all Spanish regions. The minimum wage accounts for 36% of the average wage, Spain being one of the advanced countries with the lowest percentage together with the United States, Estonia and the Czech Republic. However, Spain is the European country with the lowest percentage (0.2%) of workers earning less than 105% of the minimum wage (Eurostat, 2016b).

Wage differentials in Spain have traditionally been small, as in most continental Europe countries, owing to the high coverage of collective agreements. However, during the crisis, wage inequality in Spain increased due to the wage devaluation suffered by those workers who have had to change jobs during the last years, mostly temporary workers (Reference Font, Izquierdo and PuenteFont et al., 2015). After Poland, Spain is the second European country with the largest presence of temporality (26% of employees) (Eurostat, 2016a). This high figure is usually explained by the characteristics of the Spanish productive structure, with a high specialisation in activities such as services and construction, and the high costs of firing permanent workers (Reference JaumotteJaumotte, 2011).

The employment rate of Spanish women is 50%, 10 points below men and 9 points below the employment rate for European women. However, women now represent 45% of total Spanish employment. Female workers are predominant in several service activities (retail, hospitality, health and other services) and in two manufacturing sectors (clothing and the pharmaceutical industry) (INE, 2016). We will thus analyse wage penalisation for part-time workers in the Spanish labour market, distinguishing among men and women.

Spain’s recent increasing trend in part-time employment, which will probably continue in the future, together with the mainly involuntary nature of this type of employment, clearly justifies interest in analysing the main characteristics of part-time jobs in Spain, including wages. Although economic theory gives reasons to expect a wage penalisation for part-time employees and previous studies for other countries show that this is a stylised fact in the labour markets of other advanced countries, research on the Spanish case is rather scarce and inconclusive, which justifies interest in advancing knowledge of the consequences of part-time employment for wages in this economy. Moreover, owing to the high coverage of collective bargaining in Spain (close to 80%), we expect that the size of the wage penalty associated with part-time work will be relatively low.

Next, we carry out a regional analysis of the wage penalty for part-time workers – as far as we know, a novel approach in the international literature. The Spanish case is especially attractive from this perspective, given that regional differences in the incidence of part-time employment are rather important, and observed wage differences between part-time and full-time workers also exhibit a significant regional heterogeneity. In Spain, regional labour markets and regional economies have traditionally exhibited very important differences, including unemployment rates (Reference Bande, Fernández and MontuengaBande et al., 2008; Reference López-Bazo, Del Barrio and ArtísLópez-Bazo et al., 2005) and demographic trends. For instance, while some regions concentrate most of the population, in others it is dispersed (Reference Ayuda, Collantes and PinillaAyuda et al., 2010; Reference Goerlich and MasGoerlich and Mas, 2008). The regional capacity to attract foreign workers has also been unequal (Reference González and OrtegaGonzález and Ortega, 2011), while internal migratory flows have remained subdued (Reference BentolilaBentolila, 1997). As discussed by Reference Cuadrado-Roura and MarotoCuadrado-Roura and Maroto (2016), clear specialisation patterns are present in Spanish regions. While some regions such as Madrid, the Basque Country, Navarre and Catalonia are specialised in manufacturing and market services, the rest of regions are mainly specialised in construction, non-commercial services and energy and primary services activities. These industries have higher sensitivity to business cycles and suffered more during the last recession. R&D activities and innovative capacities are also geographically concentrated in a few regions (Reference Coronado and AcostaCoronado and Acosta, 1997). The high level of decentralisation (according to the IMF Government Finance Statistics Yearbook 2010, the sub-national share in total government expenditure is 48% and regional authorities are responsible for active labour market policies) is another distinguishing feature of the Spanish political system that has to be taken into account in this context.

All in all, the nature of the wage differentials observed between full-time and part-time workers, together with the structural differences between Spanish regions and their labour markets and the high coverage of wage bargaining, makes the analysis particularly interesting. While high bargaining coverage suggests that differences in regional wage penalties will be reduced, the high level of regional heterogeneity casts some doubts about this prediction. Taking into account that there are no previous studies looking at the regional dimension in this context, our analysis tries to provide novel evidence regarding which forces predominate in the process of wage determination. Our empirical analysis for the Spanish economy relies on the use of a matched employer–employee dataset, the Spanish Encuesta de Estructura Salarial (Survey of Earnings Structure; hereafter SES). The use of such matched employer/employee data is rare in most previous studies in the topic (some exceptions can be found in Reference Mumford and SmithMumford and Smith, 2009; Reference O’Dorchai, Plasman and RycxO’Dorchai et al., 2007). Moreover, an econometric decomposition specifically adapted for use with this kind of data that allows controlling for the effect of unobserved firm heterogeneity on wages is employed.

Literature review

Part-time employment is usually seen as another component of the secondary labour market that grants flexibility while providing employment for persons with low qualifications or less closely linked to the labour market (students or young adults, women limited by familial responsibilities, advanced age adults or those approaching retirement, among others). The characteristics usually associated with part-time jobs include lower wages, high temporality and, in the case of certain countries or modalities of partial employment, fewer worker rights (such as paid holidays, remuneration for medical leave or firing costs). Part-time employees are presented as having reduced access to social security benefits (Reference Houseman, Machiko, O’Reilly and FaganHouseman and Machiko, 1998), fewer labour progress opportunities (Reference Russo and HassikRusso and Hassik, 2008; Reference TillyTilly, 1990), smaller pensions (Reference Ginn, Arber, O’Reilly and FaganGinn and Arber, 1998; Reference O’Connell and GashO’Connell and Gash, 2003), less labour stability (Reference Fernández-Kranz, Paul and Rodríguez-PlanasFernández-Kranz et al., 2014; Reference Muñoz de Bustillo, Fernández and AntónMuñoz de Bustillo et al., 2008) and a lower unionisation rate (Reference BelousBelous, 1989).

The issue that has garnered the most attention of researchers is the study of wage differences. The stylised facts of this international literature (summarised in Supplementary Table A.1, see http://elr.sagepub.com/content/by/supplemental-data) suggest that there is in general a negative wage difference (in terms of hourly wage) for part-time employees when compared to full-time employees Footnote 1 and that part of this raw wage gap is explained by differences between each group in worker characteristics, whether observable or unobservable. Moreover, the characteristics of the job and the firm contribute to explaining the wage differential significantly, given that many part-time workers are engaged in low-wage occupations, industries and firms (Reference HirschHirsch, 2005, among others). However, despite adding multiple explanatory factors, an unexplained part of the wage differential usually persists, which is considered the wage penalty associated with working part-time. This wage penalty could be null for young people accessing their first job (Reference Russo and HassikRusso and Hassik, 2008), while there is abundant evidence that the differential increases with age and especially with years worked in part-time positions (Reference WolfWolf, 2014) and that wage increases over time are also lower for part-time workers (Reference Fernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-PlanasFernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-Planas, 2011). While abundant gender analyses agree that the wage penalty is usually greater for women than for men, studies making disaggregated estimations are scarce. Studies disaggregating by levels of qualification conclude that the wage penalty is greater for the most qualified workers, as they suffer more from the effects of occupational degradation (Reference Connolly and GregoryConnolly and Gregory, 2009). Empirical evidence differentiating by labour market segments finds that the wage penalty is almost entirely due to the concentration of part-time employment in the secondary labour market (Reference O’Connell and GashO’Connell and Gash, 2003). On the other hand, studies with regional disaggregation have rarely been conducted. Only two previous studies examine a territorial level lower than the national level: Reference HarrisHarris (1993) examines the issue for women in Northern Ireland, finding a penalty of 19%, and Reference WolfWolf (2014) distinguishes between West and East Germany, obtaining similar results for both parts of the country.

Studies for the Spanish economy are rather scarce and present very dissimilar results, so additional evidence is needed. A first generation of papers, working with the European Community Household Panel (ECHP), estimate positive wage premiums for both genders, whether controlling or not for self-selection with probits (Reference Cebrián, Gash, Moreno, O’Reilly, Cebrián and LallementCebrián et al., 2000; Reference PagánPagán, 2007; Reference Pissarides, Garibaldi, Olivetti, Boeri, Del Boca and PissaridesPissarides et al., 2005). More recently, using data from the Continuous Sample of Working Histories (Muestra Continua de Vidas Laborales (MCVL) in Spanish), Reference Fernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-PlanasFernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-Planas (2011) obtain (for 25- to 45-year-old women only) a wage penalty of 11.4 points, controlling for occupations and adding firm fixed effects. In more recent work with the same database, Reference Fernández-Kranz, Paul and Rodríguez-PlanasFernández-Kranz et al. (2014) estimate that part-time women aged 23–45 have wage penalties of 6.1 logarithmic points if they have indefinite contracts and of 9.0 points if the contract is temporary.

Data and methodology

Data

This research is based on cross-section microdata from the most recent available wave of the SES, corresponding to 2010. The SES is a nationally representative survey on firms, covering employees at establishments of any size. It encompasses the bulk of the Spanish private sector, excluding only specific industries such as agriculture and domestic service.

Because the survey design is based on a two-stage sampling of employees working in firms, one of its most important features is the inclusion of matched employer–employee microdata. Moreover, it provides information about each of the 17 Spanish regions in which surveyed establishments are located, allowing for regional analysis which is a central part of this research.

The survey provides detailed information on wages and characteristics of workers, jobs and firms. Workers are classified as part-time or full-time according to the information provided by the firm. The wage concept used in this research is the gross hourly wage and in its calculation any payment by companies that has been incorporated. The analysis is carried out separately for men and women. The explanatory variables considered include characteristics of individuals and attributes of their jobs and firms. The former are controls relating to the nationality of the individual (i.e. differentiating between Spaniards vs non-Spaniards); the level of general education (primary, secondary or tertiary education); and age. The characteristics of the job are years of seniority in the current job (including its quadratic form); type of contract (indefinite or fixed-term); and occupation (unskilled, semi-skilled or skilled occupations), while attributes of the firms are industries of activity (12 categories); size (4 categories); type of collective agreement (firm, national sector, or sub-national sector agreements); and region of location of the firm.

The SES has some advantages over other surveys also used in the analysis of wage differentials between part- and full-time workers for the Spanish case, such as the MCVL. Although the MCVL presents a larger size and contains highly reliable administrative registers and longitudinal information, the SES contains matched employer–employee data that provide rich information on different variables that are crucial in explaining wage differentials and do not suffer from severe measurement error in the MCVL (namely, educational level and occupation). Moreover, unlike the MCVL, the SES contains uncensored wages without maximum and minimum limits and includes information regarding the number of hours worked, permitting the use of hourly wages as dependent variable.

Regarding potential limitations of the dataset, note that with the SES it is not possible to take into account in the empirical analysis the potential selection bias associated with the selection of working part- or full-time by individuals. The usual form to correct this problem, apart from being controversial, requires the use of valid exclusion restrictions that are not available in the SES. However, the fact that most part-time employment in Spain is involuntary reduces the scope of this limitation in the Spanish context. In any case, the potential impact in our results of not being able to control for selection bias cannot be easily assessed. In the light of the results obtained in the available studies, it is extremely difficult to assess the effect of not controlling for self-selection. No clear pattern emerged from the literature review: in some papers, after controlling for self-selection, the wage penalty is reduced; in others, there is no effect or the penalty even increases.

Observations with missing values on key variables and those for individuals aged less than 16 years or over 65 years have been filtered. As most previous studies on the relative wage treatment of part-time workers limit the analysis to private sector employees, observations corresponding to the public sector have been removed. The final sample is formed by 152,099 observations, 89,344 men and 62,755 women, and the regional samples range between 2152 and 28,382 employees. The descriptive statistics of the samples can be consulted in Supplementary Table A.2, see http://elr.sagepub.com/content/by/supplemental-data.

Methodology

In the empirical analysis, we use an extension of the Reference Juhn, Murphy and PierceJuhn et al. (1993) decomposition, specifically adapted for use with matched employer–employee data. This technique departs from the estimation of the following semi-logarithmic wage equation

(1) w i j = X i β + ε i j + a j

wherein wij is the natural log of hourly wage of individual i in workplace j, Xi is a vector of controls including individuals’ characteristics and those of their jobs and the firms employing them, β is a vector of parameters to be estimated (including an intercept), ϵij is a stochastic error term and aj is an error component corresponding to workplace j and invariant for all individuals working in the same workplace.

Following the recommendation of Reference Oaxaca and RansomOaxaca and Ransom (1994) and Reference NeumarkNeumark (1988), as a first step of our decomposition analysis, equation (1) is estimated for the pool of workers (i.e. full- and part-time workers). Identification of workplace effects is guaranteed, given that there is more than one observation per workplace in the dataset. Since the result of Hausman’s contrast indicates that workplace-specific effects are correlated to the rest of the explanatory variables in equation (1), the model is estimated by fixed effects (which is equivalent to estimating by ordinary least squares with a set of workplace dummies). Relying on the properties of the ordinary least squares estimator, after the estimation of equation (1) with the pooled data, the average wage of the subgroup of workers s (s=full- or part-time workers) can be expressed as

(2) w ¯ s = X ¯ s β ^ + σ θ ¯ s + η λ ¯ s where θ ¯ ~ ( 0 , 1 ) , λ ¯ ~ ( 0 , 1 )

where w ¯ s stands for the mean natural log of the hourly wage of a given group s, X ¯ s is a vector of the average of the set of explanatory variables for group s, β ^ is the vector of coefficients estimated with equation (1) and the pooled data, σ is the estimated standard deviation of wage residuals of the pool of workers, θ ¯ s is the average standardised residual of group s, η is the estimated standard deviation of workplace effects of the pool of full- and part-time workers and λ ¯ s is the average standardised workplace effect of group s.

Using the pooled wage structure as the market price reference in the decomposition, the wage gap between part- and full-time workers can be written as follows

(3) w ¯ p w ¯ f = ( X ¯ p X ¯ f ) β ^ + ( θ ¯ p θ ¯ f ) σ + ( λ ¯ p λ ¯ f ) η = Δ X ¯ β ^ + Δ θ ¯ σ + Δ λ ¯ η

where the subscript p is for part-time workers and f is for full-time workers, and a Δ prefix denotes the average difference between both groups in the subsequent variable.

In brief, equation (3) provides a decomposition of the part-time/full-time wage gap that quantifies the extent to which average wage differences between part-time and full-time workers are related to (a) differences in observed characteristics ( X ¯ p X ¯ f ) valued at market prices β ^ (b) the influence of unobserved elements measured as the impact of differences between part- and full-time workers on the average standardised residual ( θ ¯ p θ ¯ f ) multiplied by the money value per unit difference in the standardised residual (σ), which determines the specific wage penalty suffered by the disadvantaged group; and (c) the influence of workplace-related factors, namely, the product of the difference in the average standardised workplace effect of part- and full-time workers ( λ ¯ p λ ¯ f ) which measures the intensity of part-time workers’ segregation into low-wage workplaces, and the dispersion of wage differentials across workplaces (η), which determines the degree of the wage penalty for part-time workers resulting from this segregation. Note that the second term of the decomposition corresponds to an estimation of the average intra-firm wage differential in the Spanish economy between part- and full-time employees with the same observed characteristics and working in the same firm.

Results

Table 1 provides information on the wage differential between part- and full-time workers (measured as the logarithm of the wage per hour) and on the incidence of part-time work for Spain and the Spanish regions, distinguishing between male and female workers. A negative (positive) wage differential corresponds to a wage disadvantage (advantage) of part-time workers, whereas the incidence of part-time is measured on the total number of employees. This evidence shows that in Spain, there is a significant negative average wage differential for part-time workers, with a gap substantially lower in the case of men (−0.104 logarithmic points) than women (−0.254 logarithmic points), and that the incidence of part-time employment is much higher in the case of women (27.7% of total employees) than men (8.7%), as is usual in most advanced economies.

Table 1. Incidence of part-time work and wage differences between part-time and full-time workers in Spanish regions.

The incidence of part-time work is measured over total employees, whereas the wage gap corresponds to the differential of the logarithm of the hourly wage between part- and full-time workers.

* p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.

Supplementary Table A.2 (http://elr.sagepub.com/content/by/supplemental-data) contains the descriptive statistics for the samples used in the analysis. Footnote 2 They reveal significant differences in observed characteristics of full- and part-time workers in Spain, which tend to be in general detrimental for part-time workers’ wages. So, without being exhaustive, the comparison between the characteristics of full- and part-time workers reveals that, for both genders, the latter have on average lower endowments of education (and of seniority in the firm just in the case of females); higher incidence of immigrants and temporary contracts; greater presence in occupations associated with lower levels of qualification and in construction and, especially, services; and, finally, greater representation in smaller firms and firms covered by sectoral agreements (the latter being true only in the case of females). Conversely, part-time workers only exhibit better relative endowments of age, and just in the case of males.

On the other hand, the magnitude of the average wage differential associated with part-time work exhibits a significant regional heterogeneity, and regional differences in the incidence of part-time employment are also rather important (Table 1). Regarding the former, in the case of female workers, the magnitude of the differential exceeds the national average in regions like Andalusia, Extremadura or Madrid, whereas in others like Navarra or The Rioja, the differential is notably lower (the maximum and minimum values of the wage differential are −0.315 log points for Extremadura and −0.071 for The Rioja, with a standard deviation of 0.071, and all the wage differentials estimated for Spanish regions are statistically significant at conventional levels). Regional differences are in general also important in the case of male workers (with an extreme value of the differential of −0.299 log points for Madrid and a standard deviation of 0.100), although in this case wage differentials are not statistically significant for most regions. With regard to the incidence of part-time employment, as a matter of example among men the percentage of part-time workers in the Canary Islands (11.1%) doubles that of Asturias (5.5%), while among women, Navarra (31.4%) is ahead of Madrid (20.8%) by 11 percentage points.

The results of applying the extension of the Reference Juhn, Murphy and PierceJuhn et al. (1993) methodology for the decomposition of the differentials in average wages between part-time and full-time workers in Spain are shown in Table 2, distinguishing between males (left panel) and females (right panel). In particular, the first row of the table shows the value of the raw differential in log hourly wages between the two groups of workers, while the rest of the rows show the value of the different terms of the decomposition (where a negative value indicates that the factor has a negative effect on the relative wages of part-time workers). For each case, we consider four specifications of the wage equation (1). The first specification (model 1) includes only explanatory variables related to the socio-demographic characteristics of the individuals (i.e. nationality, education and age). The second specification (model 2) includes the same individual characteristics along with characteristics related to job and firm (seniority, type of contract, region, industry, size and type of collective agreement). The third specification (model 3) includes also categorical variables for occupation. Footnote 3 The last specification (model 4) includes firm fixed effects instead of observed firm characteristics and thus allows controlling for the effect on wages of unobserved firm heterogeneity. The results of models 1–3 are equivalent to those that would be obtained from a standard decomposition in two components (characteristics and returns) à la Oaxaca–Blinder, whereas results from model 4 also include the third component of the right side of equation (3).

Table 2. Decomposition of the differential in average wages between part- and full-time workers: Juhn–Murphy–Pierce decomposition.

The table shows the results obtained after applying equation (3) to the 2010 wave of the Encuesta de Estructura Salarial. Model 1 corresponds to a specification of the wage equation that includes individual characteristics (nationality, age and education); models 2 and 3 incorporate to the specification attributes of jobs and firms (tenure, type of contract, occupation, region, sector, size and type of collective agreement), whereas model 4 includes individual and job attributes and firm fixed effects instead of firm attributes. The percentage of the wage differential explained by each term appears in brackets.

* p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.

The results of model 1 reveal that when only individual characteristics are considered, the lower wage levels of part-time workers cannot be explained by their relative endowments of characteristics, but essentially by a different wage treatment. In the case of male workers, the component associated with characteristics takes a negligible value of 0.002 log points – not significantly different from zero – while most of the origin of the wage differential (−0.104) corresponds to the unexplained part (−0.106). In the case of female workers, observed individual characteristics explain a relevant part of the differential (−0.104 log points or around 41% of the raw gap), but again most of the differential (−0.254) is related to the unexplained part (−0.150). Overall, this evidence suggests that when considering just individuals with the same socio-demographic observed characteristics, the average part-time wage penalty in the Spanish labour market is of −10.6 logarithmic points for males and of −15.0 points for female workers.

The inclusion of additional explanatory variables related to the characteristics of jobs and firms (model 2) substantially increases the contribution of the explained component for both genders. In the case of male workers, lower educational levels and seniority, a higher incidence of fixed-term contracts and a higher presence in low-wage industries arise as relevant explanatory factors of the wage disadvantage of part-time male workers, whereas the factor with a more significant positive effect for this group is their higher relative age. Footnote 4 For female workers, the factors explaining lower wages of part-time employees are also related to lower endowments of education and seniority and higher presence in low-wage industries. Nevertheless, the most remarkable result of the evidence obtained from model 2 is that, in contrast with results with model 1, a very important part of the wage gap between part-time and full-time workers is now explained: the contribution of the explained part of the differential increases to 66% of the raw gap for men and to 82% for women. The unexplained part (or wage penalty) is of only −0.036 log points for men and −0.046 log points for women, representing 35% and 18% of the total gap, respectively. When including also occupation as an explanatory variable (model 3), occupational segregation arises as a very relevant explanatory factor of the wage gaps between full- and part-time workers, especially for females Footnote 5 (this factor alone explains 0.053 log points or 51% of the gap for males and 0.116 log points or 46% for females); although the rest of the results are overall rather similar, the unexplained components of the decomposition almost halve for both males (−0.016) and females (−0.024). These latter values are very different from the wage premium for part-time workers previously found for Spain by Reference Cebrián, Gash, Moreno, O’Reilly, Cebrián and LallementCebrián et al. (2000), Reference Pissarides, Garibaldi, Olivetti, Boeri, Del Boca and PissaridesPissarides et al. (2005) and Reference PagánPagán (2007) using the ECHP, but are close to the results obtained by Reference O’Dorchai, Plasman and RycxO’Dorchai et al. (2007) with the 1995 SES for men (−0.06 log points), and lower than those obtained by Reference Fernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-PlanasFernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-Planas (2011) and Reference Fernández-Kranz, Paul and Rodríguez-PlanasFernández-Kranz et al. (2014) using the MCVL (between −0.06 and −0.13 log points) and a similar set of explanatory factors. It is worth mentioning that the estimated penalty according to model 3 (with similar controls to those included in the models summarised in Figure 1) is very close to the one expected when regressing the wage penalty on the coverage of collective bargaining: around 4 percentage points. This result is another sign of the importance of this variable to explain cross-country differences in the wage penalty of part-time workers.

The relevance of differences in characteristics as the main explanatory factor of the wage differential between part- and full-time workers is reinforced when observed firm level variables are replaced by firm fixed effects (model 4). According to this additional evidence, for both genders the wage disadvantage of part-time workers is almost fully explained now by their relative endowments of individual and job characteristics (the first term of the decomposition explains 31% of the raw gap for men and 57% for women) and, especially, by their relative segregation in low-wage firms (according to the second term, the unequal distribution by firms of part- and full-time workers explains 69% of the gap for men and 42.5% for women). As a consequence, the third component associated with the wage residuals has a minimum influence to explain the gap: actually, it is not statistically different from zero both for male and female workers. Given that this term is an estimation of the average intra-firm wage differential between part- and full-time employees with the same characteristics, this last result shows that part- and full-time workers who possess the same observed characteristics and who work in the same type of job (including occupation) and in the same firm overall tend to receive a similar wage treatment in the Spanish labour market (i.e. there is no evidence of direct wage discrimination). This result is consistent with the high coverage of collective bargaining in Spain.

On the other hand, Table 3 shows the results of the Reference Juhn, Murphy and PierceJuhn et al. (1993) decomposition of average wages between part-time and full-time workers for each of the 17 Spanish regions (the upper panel refers to males and the lower panel to females) corresponding to model 4 (i.e. including firm fixed effects). The obtained results show marked differences among regions, particularly for female workers. As regards component (1) of the decomposition, differences in endowments of observed characteristics are in the case of females systematically unfavourable for part-time workers in all considered regions and they are a relevant explanatory factor for the negative wage gap for part-time female workers in almost every region, whereas for males the first component of the decomposition has positive or negative values depending on the region. As regards the effect of the second component, it is observed that both for males and females the different relative distribution of full- and part-time workers among firms tends to be a relevant explanatory factor of wage differentials in every region (this component is statistically significant for most regions, both for males and females). Finally, with a few exceptions, the values of the third component are for most Spanish regions not statistically different from zero for both males and females, so wage penalties against part-time workers are practically non-existent at regional level. Overall, this evidence suggests that in most Spanish regions the bulk of the observed wage gap between full- and part-time workers is mainly explained by their different endowments of individual, job and firm characteristics and, therefore, that the significant regional heterogeneity observed for the Spanish regions in the magnitude of the wage differential between full- and part-time employees is essentially not explained by regional specific factors. So, the absence of wage penalties to part-time workers, even in the presence of such big differences, can probably be explained by the wage determination process operating in Spain with a high level of coverage of collective agreements in all regions.

Table 3. Decomposition of the differential in average wages between part- and full-time workers: Juhn–Murphy–Pierce decomposition and regional disaggregated analysis.

The table shows the results obtained after applying equation (3) to the 2010 wave of the Encuesta de Estructura Salarial with a specification of the wage equation that includes individual and job characteristics and firm fixed effects (model 4).

* p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01.

Conclusion

This article has examined wage differentials between part- and full-time workers in Spain, distinguishing by gender. It has contributed to the relevant literature by introducing a fully novel regional perspective into the analysis and by using an econometric decomposition method that takes advantage of the use of a matched employer–employee dataset. This technique allows, inter alia, estimating intra-firm wage differentials for part- and full-time workers with similar observed characteristics as well as assessing the impact, in the part-time wage penalty, of the segregation of part-time workers in low-wage firms.

The obtained evidence has shown that part-time workers in Spain experience a significant average wage disadvantage and that this disadvantage is significantly higher for female workers. The results of the econometric decompositions have also shown that the wage penalty associated with part-time workers, both males and females, is almost fully explained by their relative characteristics and, in particular, by the significant segregation of part-time workers in low-wage firms. In fact, intra-firm wage differences between full- and part-time workers with similar observable productive characteristics working in the same firm are negligible for both genders, which suggests a similar wage treatment by Spanish firms of full- and part-time workers; hence, the absence of direct wage discrimination against part-time workers – a result that is probably related to the high coverage of collective agreements in the Spanish labour market.

From a regional perspective, in the case of Spain it has been observed that regional differences in the incidence of part-time employment are rather significant and that observed wage differences between part-time and full-time workers also exhibit a very significant regional heterogeneity. The empirical evidence regarding the origin of the wage differential suggests, nevertheless, that in the majority of the Spanish region, most of the observed average wage differential between part- and full-time workers tends to be explained by worker endowment factors so that wage penalties do not usually exist at a regional level. This absence of wage penalties for part-time workers supports the hypothesis that a high coverage of wage bargaining prevents discriminatory practices against part-time workers and reinforces the idea that one of the major sources of cross-country differences in the wage penalty of part-time workers is differences in labour market institutions such as collective bargaining.

Funding

This work was supported by the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness under grants ECO2013-41022-R, ECO2013-41310-R, 2014 SGR-420 and CSO2014-55780-C3-2-P (National R&D&I Plan).

Footnotes

Supplementary Material

Supplemental Material accompanying this article is available at: http://elr.sagepub.com/content/by/supplemental-data

1. In countries like Australia and South Africa, a positive wage bonus for part-time workers is observed by Reference Booth and WoodBooth and Wood (2008) and Reference Posel and MullerPosel and Muller (2007), while Reference RodgersRodgers (2004) does not observe a premium or a penalty in Australia.

2. To conserve space, they correspond to the whole samples for the overall Spanish economy. Descriptive statistics of the samples for every Spanish region are available from the authors on request.

3. The reason for separating out this variable in the analysis is that it potentially suffers from endogeneity in relation to the distribution of individuals between full- and part-time jobs, to the extent that part-time employment is often limited to low-wage occupations (see, e.g. Reference Manning and PetrongoloManning and Petrongolo, 2008).

4. This finding is consistent with the fact that in Spain, a significant part of job contracts among part-time male workers is related to partial retirement (Reference Muñoz de Bustillo, Fernández and AntónMuñoz de Bustillo et al., 2008).

5. Obtained evidence suggests that the specific contribution to the full-time/part-time wage gap of certain variables such as industry, and especially, occupation is much higher in the case of females than in the case of male workers. The main reason is that part-time females are significantly segregated into low-wage occupations and industries (Supplementary Table A.2, see http://elr.sagepub.com/content/by/supplemental-data), a finding that is consistent with the fact that occupation and industry segregation are very relevant determinants of female relative wages everywhere (see, for example, Reference Ponthieux, Meurs, Atkinson and BourguignonPonthieux and Meurs, 2015).

References

Ayuda, MI, Collantes, F and Pinilla, VJ (2010) Long-run regional population disparities in Europe during modern economic growth: a case study of Spain. Annals of Regional Science 44(2): 273295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bande, R, Fernández, R and Montuenga, V (2008) Regional unemployment in Spain: disparities, business cycle and wage setting. Labor Economics 15(5): 885914.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belous, R (1989) The Contingent Economy: The Growth of the Temporary, Part-Time and Subcontracted Workforce. Washington, DC: National Planning Association.Google Scholar
Bentolila, S (1997) Sticky labor in Spanish regions. European Economic Review 41(3–5): 591598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Booth, AL and Wood, M (2008) Back-to-front down under? Part-time/full-time wage differentials in Australia. Industrial Relations 47(1): 114135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cebrián, I, Gash, V, Moreno, G, et al . (2000) Peripheral labour in peripheral markets? Mobility and working time within transitional labour markets among women in Ireland and Spain. In: O’Reilly, J, Cebrián, I and Lallement, M (eds) Working-Time Changes: Social Integration Through Transitional Labour Markets. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 205250.Google Scholar
Connolly, S and Gregory, M (2009) The part-time pay penalty: earnings trajectories of British women. Oxford Economic Papers 61(S1): i76i97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coronado, D and Acosta, M (1997) Spatial distribution of patents in Spain: determining factors and consequences on regional development. Regional Studies 31(4): 381390.Google Scholar
Cuadrado-Roura, JR and Maroto, A (2016) Unbalanced regional resilience to the economic crisis in Spain: a tale of specialisation and productivity. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 9(1): 153178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eurostat (2016a) Labour force statistics. Available at: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/lfs/data/database (accessed 1 June 2016).Google Scholar
Eurostat (2016b) Minimum wage statistics. Available at: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Minimum_wage_statistics (accessed 1 June 2016).Google Scholar
Euwals, R and Hogerbrugge, M (2006) Explaining the growth of part-time employment: factors of supply and demand. Labour 20(3): 533557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández-Kranz, D and Rodríguez-Planas, N (2010) El contrato a tiempo parcial. Papeles de Economía Española 124: 148163.Google Scholar
Fernández-Kranz, D and Rodríguez-Planas, N (2011) The part-time penalty in a segmented labor market. Labour Economics 18(5): 591606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández-Kranz, D, Paul, M and Rodríguez-Planas, N (2014) Part-time work, fixed-term contracts, and the returns to experience. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 77(4): 512541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Font, P, Izquierdo, M and Puente, S (2015) Real wage responsiveness to unemployment in Spain: asymmetries along the business cycle. Working paper no. 1504. Madrid: Banco de España.Google Scholar
Ginn, J and Arber, S (1998) How does part-time work lead to low pension income? In: O’Reilly, J and Fagan, C (eds) Part-Time Prospects: An International Comparison of Part-Time Work in Europe, North America and the Pacific Rim. London: Routledge, pp. 156173.Google Scholar
Goerlich, F and Mas, M (2008) Empirical evidence of population concentration in Spain during 1900–2001. Population 63(4): 635649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
González, L and Ortega, F (2011) How do very open economies adjust to large immigration flows? Evidence for Spanish regions. Labour Economics 18(1): 5770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R (1993) Part-time female earnings: an analysis using Northern Ireland NES data. Applied Economics 25: 112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirsch, BT (2005) Why do part-time workers earn less? The role of workers and job skills. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 58(4): 525551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houseman, S and Machiko, O (1998) What is the nature of part-time work in the United States and Japan? In: O’Reilly, J and Fagan, C (eds) Part-Time Prospects: An International Comparison of Part-Time Work in Europe, North America and the Pacific Rim. London: Routledge, pp. 232251.Google Scholar
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (INE) (2016) Encuesta de Población Activa. Resultados detallados, Media de los cuatro trimesters. Available at: http://www.ine.es/jaxiT3/Tabla.htm?t=4877&;L=0 (accessed 1 June 2016).Google Scholar
International Labour Office (ILO) (2015) Labour relations and collective bargaining. Issue brief no. 1, October. Geneva: ILO.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2015) Spain selected issues. IMF Country report, 15/223, 14 August. Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
Jaumotte, F (2011) The Spanish Labor Market in a Cross-Country Perspective. IMF working paper 11/11. Available at: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp1111.pdf (accessed 1 June 2016).Google Scholar
Juhn, C, Murphy, K and Pierce, B (1993) Wage inequality and the rise in returns to skill. Journal of Political Economy 101(3): 410442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López-Bazo, E, Del Barrio, T and Artís, M (2005) Geographical distribution of unemployment in Spain. Regional Studies 39(3): 305318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manning, A and Petrongolo, B (2008) The part-time pay penalty for women in Britain. Economic Journal 118(526): F28F51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, M (1988) On the determinants of employer demand for part-time workers. The Review of Economics and Statistics 70(1): 112117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mumford, K and Smith, PN (2009) What determines the part-time and gender earnings gaps in Britain: evidence from the workplace. Oxford Economic Papers 61(suppl 1): i56i75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muñoz de Bustillo, R, Fernández, E and Antón, JI (2008) El trabajo a tiempo parcial en España en el contexto de la Unión Europea. Características, condiciones de trabajo y perspectivas. Colección Informes y Estudios, Serie Empleo n 36. Madrid: Ministerio de Trabajo e Inmigración.Google Scholar
Neumark, D (1988) Employer’s discriminatory behavior and the estimation of wage discrimination. Journal of Human Resources 23(3): 279295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oaxaca, R and Ransom, M (1994) On discrimination and the decomposition of wage differentials. Journal of Econometrics 61(1): 522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Connell, PJ and Gash, V (2003) The effects of working time, segmentation and labour market mobility on wages and pensions in Ireland. British Journal of Industrial Relations 41(1): 7195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Dorchai, S, Plasman, R and Rycx, F (2007) The part-time wage penalty in European countries: how large is it for men? International Journal of Manpower 28(7): 571603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pagán, R (2007) Diferencias salariales entre el empleo a tiempo completo y parcial. Revista de Economía Aplicada 15(43): 548.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C, Garibaldi, P, Olivetti, C, et al . (2005) Women in the labor force: how well is Europe doing? In: Boeri, T, Del Boca, D and Pissarides, C (eds) Women at Work: An Economic Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 9120.Google Scholar
Ponthieux, S and Meurs, D (2015) Gender inequality. In: Atkinson, AB and Bourguignon, F (eds) Handbook of Income Distribution (Volume 2). Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 9811146.Google Scholar
Posel, D and Muller, C (2007) Is there evidence of a wage penalty to female part time employment in South Africa? ERSA working paper no. 61. Durban, South Africa: University of Kwazulu-Natal.Google Scholar
Rodgers, JR (2004) Hourly wages of full-time and part-time employees in Australia. Australian Journal of Labour Economics 7(2): 231254.Google Scholar
Russo, G and Hassik, W (2008) The part-time wage gap: a career perspective. De Economist 156(2): 145174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, C (1990) Short Hours, Short Shrift: Causes and Consequences of Part-Time Work. Washington, DC: The Economic Policy Institute.Google Scholar
Wolf, E (2014) The German part-time wage gap: bad news for men? SOEP papers 663/2014. Available at: https://www.diw.de/documents/publikationen/73/diw_01.c.466650.de/diw_sp0663.pdf (accessed 1 June 2016).Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Average unexplained component of wage differentials between part-time and full-time workers and coverage of collective bargaining.Country averages of wage penalties found in the literature for male part-time workers with similar specifications. Collective bargaining data refer to 2010 and have been obtained from ILOStat.

Figure 1

Table 1. Incidence of part-time work and wage differences between part-time and full-time workers in Spanish regions.

Figure 2

Table 2. Decomposition of the differential in average wages between part- and full-time workers: Juhn–Murphy–Pierce decomposition.

Figure 3

Table 3. Decomposition of the differential in average wages between part- and full-time workers: Juhn–Murphy–Pierce decomposition and regional disaggregated analysis.

Supplementary material: File

Ramos et al. supplementary material
Download undefined(File)
File 50.7 KB