Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T05:29:00.643Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Employee stock ownership plans and firm productivity in China

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

Haitong Li
Affiliation:
Renmin University of China, China
Ziang Lin*
Affiliation:
Renmin University of China, China
Bo Huang
Affiliation:
Renmin University of China, China
*
Ziang Lin, School of Business, Renmin University of China, China, No. 59 Zhongguancun Street, Haidian District, Beijing, 100872, China. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

A growing number of Chinese firms motivate their employees through employee stock ownership plans (ESOPs). Using a sample of listed firms in China, this paper examines the impact of ESOPs on firms’ total factor productivity (TFP), as well as the mechanisms of ESOPs. The empirical results show that ESOPs have a positive impact on firm TFP. The mechanism tests convey that ESOPs increase firm TFP by promoting research and development (R&D) investment and mitigating agency costs. These results are robust after accounting for endogeneity and using alternative metrics of TFP. In addition, we find that the positive effect of ESOPs on firm TFP is more pronounced in non-state-owned firms and firms with a less severe free-riding problem. Furthermore, the effect on firm TFP is positively associated with the subscription proportion of non-executive employees in ESOPs. Overall, the results of this study underscore the important role of employee ownership in firms’ productivity improvement.

Type
Original Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s) 2022

Introduction

Beginning in the United States, ESOPs are widely adopted by enterprises in developed countries, and have also recently appeared in many emerging markets, including China. ESOPs, also known as employee stock purchase plans, allow employees to obtain stock shares, either through compensation or via subscription plans offered by their employers. Proponents of ESOPs argue that employee equity ownership improves firm performance by improving corporate governance (Reference Faleye, Mehrotra and MorckFaleye et al., 2006), attracting and retaining employees (Reference Chen, King and WenChen et al., 2020), cultivating job satisfaction and organisational commitment (Reference Dong, Bowles and HoDong et al., 2002), and enhancing peer monitoring (Reference Jones and KatoJones and Kato, 1995) and interest alignment (Reference Jones and KatoJones and Kato, 1993; Reference Robinson and WilsonRobinson and Wilson, 2010). However, critics of ESOPs suggest that employees’ ownership earnings are exposed to higher capital market risk; hence, making it difficult to stimulate employee productivity (Reference Conyon, Gregg and MachinConyon et al., 1995). Also, as an incentive to rank-and-file employees, ESOPs are insufficient to improve firm productivity when there are too many participants to mitigate free-riding problems (Reference Kim and OuimetKim and Ouimet, 2014).

Existing literature presents mixed results on the link between ESOPs and firm performance. In addition, little is known about the effect of employee ownership firms in emerging countries. Although Reference Ren, Xiao and YangRen et al. (2019) have provided evidence that ESOPs facilitate corporate performance in China, existing literature does not provide convincing evidence on how ESOPs in emerging countries affect productivity. This study attempts to help fill this gap in the literature. We explore how ESOPs affect a firm’s total factor productivity (TFP, hereafter), and investigate the channel through which ESOPs exert influence on firms’ TFP. Firm TFP is analysed, because TFP is a measure of a firm’s efficiency, which in turn has been recognised as a critical factor in firms’ survival and competitiveness (Reference Lieberman and DhawanLieberman and Dhawan, 2005).

In recent years, the rapid development of ESOPs in emerging capital markets has attracted widespread attention, especially in China. To standardise the implementation of ESOPs, the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) issued the ‘Guiding Opinions on the Implementation of Pilot ESOPs by listed firms’ (henceforth referred to as ‘The Guidance’) in 2014. This document sets out the basic principles of information disclosure. Since then, many listed firms have adopted ESOPs. More than 430,000 employees participated in ESOPs by the end of 2019. Remarkably, whether state-owned or private-owned, China’s listed firms usually have an overly-concentrated ownership structure, in which controlling shareholders hold the majority of shares, while employees hold very few. Hence, many of China’s firms suffer from agency problems and tunnelling issues (Reference Jefferson and SuJefferson and Su, 2006; Reference Jiang and KimJiang and Kim, 2015), which reduce staff productivity. Based on these facts, studying the economic consequences of Chinese firms’ ESOPs has theoretical value and practical significance. This study provides suggestions, not only for Chinese firms, but also for many emerging capital markets.

This study’s primary research design is based on ESOPs for Chinese publicly traded firms. First, the empirical results suggest that the implementation of ESOPs is linked to an increase in firms’ productivity, as measured by TFP. These results still hold after conducting a series of robustness checks. Second, this article further broadens the focus on the possible mechanism through which these effects may be exerted. The results suggest that ESOPs promote firms to invest in research and development (R&D) activities and alleviate agency problems. This is achieved by stimulating employees to adopt long-term interests and by binding their benefits to the firm’s financial performance. Third, this study further investigates the economic consequences of ESOPs in firms with different characteristics and finds that the impact of ESOPs on firm productivity is more pronounced in non-state-owned enterprises (non-SOEs), as well as in firms with a less severe free-riding problem measured by the number of employees. Fourth, we find that an increase in firm TFP positively associates with the subscription proportion of non-executive employees in ESOPs.

This study contributes to the existing literature by examining the role of employee ownership on firm productivity. First, it builds on previous literature on the economic functions of employee ownership. To our knowledge, no previous work systematically links ESOPs with TFP using a large-scale analysis in an emerging market. This is despite the existing evidence that employee ownership is an efficient way to improve corporate governance. We document that an essential function of employee ownership is to foster firm productivity. Also, this research discovers the effects of and the specific channels through which ESOPs affect firm productivity. Based on the findings, this study complements the research of Reference Jones and KatoJones and Kato (1995), and Reference Kim and OuimetKim and Ouimet (2014), both of which confirmed the positive impact of ESOPs on corporate performance and innovation. Second, this paper also contributes to the existing literature on firm productivity. Corporate literature has paid close attention to ways in which to improve firm productivity (see, e.g., Reference Ferrando and RuggieriFerrando and Ruggieri, 2015; Reference Le, Pieri and ZaninottoLe et al., 2019; Reference Liu and MaoLiu and Mao, 2019; Reference Wye and BahriWye and Bahri, 2021), especially through labour policy (Reference EllemEllem, 2021; Reference Wye and BahriWye and Bahri, 2021). We focus on the role of ESOPs in this field, in order to provide new ideas on how to improve the productivity of Chinese enterprises. Third, this paper contributes to the current literature on Chinese ESOPs (Reference Feng, Yu, Nan and CaiFeng et al., 2022; Reference Ren, Xiao and YangRen et al., 2019). Since China now officially allows listed firms to adopt ESOPs, a growing number of Chinese firms are motivating employees through such plans, though the literature on Chinese ESOPs is scarce. Hence, this research provides insights into the economic outcomes in which Chinese enterprises’ ESOPs are adopted.

The rest of this article is structured as follows: in the section ‘Institutional background and hypothesis development’, a review of the institutional background related to ESOPs in China is performed, and hypotheses are proposed. The section ‘Research design’ introduces the empirical strategy with our sample selection, variable construction, and regression model. Then, the ‘Empirical results’ section reports empirical findings, including the tests for the hypotheses, moderation analysis, further analysis, and robustness checks. Finally, the ‘Conclusion’ section presents a summary of the findings.

Institutional background and hypothesis development

Ever since ESOPs originated in the US, similar plans have been adopted by many enterprises around the world. The CSRC in China issued ‘The Guidance’, which formulates the main content, information disclosure, adoption procedures, and regulatory requirements. This document formally launched ESOPs for public traded firms in China. Compared to common equity incentives, ESOPs include a larger group of employees, as well as different implementation methods. According to our statistics based on all ESOPs announced by Chinese A-share firms before 2019, these ESOPs account for 1.59% of their firms’ shares. For the subscribed shares in these ESOPs, 74.97% of shares were purchased by non-executive employees on average, while the remaining shares belonged to executives. The average number and proportion of employees participating in these ESOPs are 469 and 15.68%. In addition, since many Chinese SOEs do not allow their officials to hold shares, only 9.74% of ESOPs are adopted by Chinese SOEs. As required by the CSRC, the shares subscribed by employees in ESOPs are centrally managed by an organisation elected by employees, and rights to shares are allocated to employees as agreed in the terms of subscription. However, shares cannot be sold for a designated period – on average 1.39 years. Listed firms need to release the specific progress and purchase quantity of ESOPs, and this requirement provides reliable data for empirical research. Statistics from the Wind database show that, after ‘The Guidance’ was issued, 1,190 ESOPs were released in the Chinese capital market. Overall, ESOPs have become a common way to motivate employees in China.

Employees are believed to be one of the most important stakeholders of a firm, and they should be involved in decision-making and strategic plans (Reference Chang, Fu, Low and ZhangChang et al., 2015; Reference Chen, King and WenChen et al., 2020). In practice, ESOPs enable employees to become shareholders of their firm; ESOPs also link employee wealth to the market performance of firm stock. ESOPs motivate employees to greater work effort, thus enhancing a firm’s financial performance. Specifically, a firm can adopt an ESOP to facilitate productivity gains (Reference Kim and OuimetKim and Ouimet, 2014), encourage R&D activities (Reference Chang, Fu, Low and ZhangChang et al., 2015) and/or improve the firm’s financial performance (Reference Ren, Xiao and YangRen et al., 2019). Thus, ESOPs can boost firm TFP through different channels.

As one of the major forms of profit sharing and employee incentive, employee ownership is a compensation strategy that primarily focuses on offering shares to employees. Through these shares, employees can increase their wealth, thus more closely linking the employee to the firm’s success (Reference Aubert, Kern and HollandtsAubert et al., 2017). When employees hold firm shares, the sensitivity between the employees’ interests and the firm’s financial performance is increased. Employees may also develop a sense of identity or loyalty to the firm (Reference Jones and KatoJones and Kato, 1995). One prime motivation that underlies managerial adoption of ESOPs is to incentivise employees, and translate those positive attitudes into better performance and higher productivity. Reference FrenchFrench (1987), among others (Reference Aubert, Kern and HollandtsAubert et al., 2017; Reference Gamble, Culpepper and BlubaughGamble et al., 2002) suggested that employee ownership can successfully motivate employees and inspire them to work harder, ultimately improving firm performance and business sustainability. Based on the above considerations and evidence, we propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1:

ESOPs have a positive effect on firms’ TFP.

We believe that improved attitudes can be translated into innovation involvement, that is, employee stock ownership facilitates corporate innovation activities. It has been documented that the key to progress of research and development is talented people, namely firm employees (Reference Bradley, Kim and TianBradley et al., 2013). Reference Caramelli and BrioleCaramelli and Briole (2007) argued that employee ownership might affect worker attitudes via improved work motivation and affective commitment. Reference Chang, Fu, Low and ZhangChang et al. (2015) suggested that employee profit-sharing plans act as a group incentive scheme to enhance cooperation, information sharing, and social learning between innovators, thus promoting R&D activities. In addition, employee motivation plays a decisive role in a firm’s development and growth, especially in long-term R&D activities. Since ESOPs usually last for at least 1 year and require employees to stay within their firm’s employ, such plans can improve the stability of employees, in turn ensuring the continuity of the firm’s R&D activities. Theoretically, firm productivity is the Solow residual and is driven by innovation activities (Reference SolowSolow, 1957). Hence, this study assumes that ESOPs play a positive role in improving TFP, particularly by promoting corporate R&D activities (Reference SyversonSyverson, 2011). To sum up, the following hypothesis is proposed:

Hypothesis 2a:

ESOPs improve firms’ TFP by promoting R&D investment.

Employee ownership can enhance employees’ sense of ownership and make the interests of employees and shareholders more consistent, improving work enthusiasm and strengthening supervision over managers. According to agency cost theory, the consistency of employees’ interests can reduce a firm’s agency cost, which is conducive to reducing opportunistic behaviour by management and promoting firm development. Furthermore, the effect on staff stability is also associated with greater corporate productivity. Prior research supports the idea that ESOPs reduce agency costs. For instance, Reference Chen and HuangChen and Huang (2006) suggested that employee ownership can alleviate the agency problem between management and shareholders; and reduce information asymmetry between employees and shareholders. Reference Hochberg and LindseyHochberg and Lindsey (2010) pointed out that stock-based compensation establishes the common goals of employees at all levels; employee teamwork is also enhanced. To sum up, the next hypothesis is proposed as follows:

Hypothesis 2b:

ESOPs improve firms’ TFP by mitigating agency costs.

Studies indicate that a firm’s ownership nature affects business behaviour (Reference Jefferson and SuJefferson and Su, 2006; Reference O’Toole, Morgenroth and HaO’Toole et al., 2016). The magnitude of the effect on firm productivity varies across firms with different conditions. Therefore, this study provides moderation analysis of the heterogeneous impacts of ESOPs on firm TFP.

First, the effect of ESOPs on TFP is assumed to be different in state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and non-SOEs. On the one hand, when a firm is controlled by the government, its objective function is likely to be muddled with various non-economic considerations. Political inference will inevitably distort the firm’s competitive strategy (Reference Abrami, Kirby and McfarlanAbrami et al., 2014; Reference Shleifer and VishnyShleifer and Vishny, 1997). The government has tremendous power over resource allocation and often interferes in a firm’s operating activities (Reference HuHu, 2001), especially in China. Chinese state-owned enterprises have undertaken more social responsibility, for example, they work to solve unemployment issues and maintain social stability, rather than only aiming at for-profit earnings (Reference Bai, Lu and TaoBai et al., 2006). On the other hand, agency theory suggests that a firm’s state ownership damages the interests of non-state minority shareholders; such firms are associated with lower governance quality (Reference Borisova, Brockman, Salas and ZagorchevBorisova et al., 2012). Among Chinese SOEs, perverse incentive mechanisms and ineffective governance mechanisms often lead to agency conflicts (Reference Mi and WangMi and Wang, 2000). Hence, SOEs have greater resistance to promoting distribution activities than non-SOEs. When adopting ESOPs, we expect that non-SOEs, who are relatively free from government interference, will benefit from a significant positive improvement in firm productivity. Hence, the following hypothesis is proposed:

Hypothesis 3a:

The positive impact of ESOPs on firms’ TFP is more pronounced in non-SOEs.

Second, we predict that the relationship between ESOPs and firm TFP can be weakened in firms with a severe free-riding problem. If a firm has a large number of employees, the inefficient working behaviour of an individual may not have a notable effect on the firm’s overall productivity. In such circumstances, a free-riding problem is more likely to arise in the firm (Reference Chang, Fu, Low and ZhangChang et al., 2015). It has also been argued that the connection between individual performance and reward grows weaker as the number of employees in the firm grows larger (Reference Kruse and BlasiKruse and Blasi, 1995). Due to the free-riding problem measured by the number of employees, firms with a larger workforce usually have less employee involvement (Reference Hochberg and LindseyHochberg and Lindsey, 2010) and a weaker incentive effect. Hence, when a large-workforce firm facing the free-riding problem adopts an ESOP, the power of this group incentive can be diluted (Reference Chang, Fu, Low and ZhangChang et al., 2015; Reference Kim and OuimetKim and Ouimet, 2014). Conversely, efforts of individual employees can improve a firm’s productivity more significantly in a small-workforce firm; the incentive effect of ESOPs may also be more pronounced in smaller firms. Based on these findings, we expect that employee incentives provided by ESOPs have a more significant impact on firm TFP in firms with a less severe free-riding problem, as measured by the number of employees.

Hypothesis 3b:

The positive impact of ESOPs on firm TFP is more pronounced in firms with a less severe free-riding problem.

Research design

Data sources

The sample includes all publicly traded Chinese A-share firms from 2012 to 2018. Financial firms and firms in financial distress are excluded, due to their significantly distinctive financial characteristics. Firms with incomplete financial information are also excluded. Financial statement data were obtained from the China Securities Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database; ESOP information was taken from the Wind database. Both databases are widely used in research on listed firms in China. Specifically, we examined the mandatory announcements pertaining ESOPs issued by listed firms and confirm the start time, duration, purchased shares, and the proportion purchased by executives and non-executive employees in each ESOP. Then, we accordingly confirm whether a firm has ESOPs in each year. As the announcement of an ESOP is mandatory in China’s capital market, our data covered all successfully implemented ESOPs in our sample. The final study sample includes 17,401 firm-year observations.

Variable definitions

The dependent variable in this study is firms’ total factor productivity (TFP). TFP is often estimated as the Solow residual from OLS regression for a standard Cobb–Douglas production function. However, OLS estimates are likely to suffer from two endogeneity problems: simultaneity and selection bias. Simultaneity bias might be caused by the correlation between a firm’s unobserved productivity shocks and input decisions. Selection bias might result from correlation between a firm’s low productivity and its decision to exit markets.

To address these biases, this study computed firm TFP using the standard ‘control function’ approach proposed by Reference Levinsohn and PetrinLevinsohn and Petrin (2003), and Reference Olley and PakesOlley and Pakes (1996). The TFP in these two methods is denoted as TFP_LP and TFP_OP, respectively. Both methods are widely used in economics and management literature to calculate firm productivity levels (e.g., Reference Liu and MaoLiu and Mao, 2019; Reference Jola-SanchezJola-Sanchez, 2022). Briefly, both methods are introduced by considering a Cobb–Douglas production function, as presented below:

(1) y i t = a 0 + a l l i t + a k k i t + a m m i t + ω i t + ε i t

where i refers to the firm, and t refers to the year; yit refers to the output, measured by the natural logarithm of firms’ sales; lit refers to the labor, measured by the logarithm of the total number of firm’s employees; kit refers to the capital, measured by the logarithm of firms’ fixed assets; mit refers to the intermediate inputs, measured by the logarithm of firms’ current investment, according to the LP approach, and by the logarithm of firms’ cash payments for acquiring assets, according to the OP approach, respectively. Term ωit is the component affecting the relevant firm’s input choice (following, for instance, Reference Keller and YeapleKeller and Yeaple, 2009), and term εit is an error term. Then, firm TFP was computed using the following model:

(2) T F P i t = y i t a l l i t a k k i t

The dependent variable ESOP measures whether firms adopt ESOPs. An ESOP takes a value of 1 for firms with ongoing ESOPs in year t, and 0 otherwise.

To mitigate the risk of getting biased coefficients referring to ESOPs and firm TFP due to omitted variables, this study followed prior research in referring to the factors that influence a firm’s TFP; a set of control variables (Controls) has been included for firm characteristics. Specifically, we include firm size (Size), measured as the natural logarithm of the number of employees (Reference Le, Pieri and ZaninottoLe et al., 2019; Reference Schiffbauer, Siedschlag and RuaneSchiffbauer et al., 2017; Reference Tsou and YangTsou and Yang, 2019; Reference UrasUras, 2014). Firm age (Age), measured as the natural logarithm of the number of years since the firm’s establishment (Reference Min and SmythMin and Smyth, 2014). Firm profitability (ROA) is measured as the ratio of net profit to total assets; growth rate (Growth) as the annual growth rate of revenue (Reference Doerr, Raissi and WeberDoerr et al., 2018), and financial leverage (Leverage) as the ratio of debt to total assets (Reference Le, Pieri and ZaninottoLe et al., 2019; Reference UrasUras, 2014). Asset tangibility (Fixed), is measured as the ratio of fixed to total assets (Reference Kong, Tao and WangKong et al., 2020), is also controlled. The term SOE denotes state ownership, and equals 1 if the firm is state-owned, and 0 otherwise (Reference Kong, Tao and WangKong et al., 2020). Lastly, all continuous variables are winsorised at the 1st and 99th percentiles, in order to avoid the influence of extreme observations.

To test Hypothesis 2a and Hypothesis 2b, two variables are employed to a denote firm’s agency cost and R&D investment, respectively. Following previous research (Reference Ang, Cole and LinAng et al., 2000), the ratio of administrative fees to revenue is included, to measure agency cost (Agency), which in turn indicates the agency problem between a firm’s shareholders and employees, and which might be affected by ESOPs. In addition, firm R&D investment (RDinvest) is measured as the ratio of a firm’s investment in R&D activities to fixed assets.

Model specification

To analyse the impact of ESOPs on firms’ TFP, the baseline model is constructed as follows:

(3) T F P i t = β 0 + β 1 E S O P i t + Σ C o n t r o l s i t + F i r m e f f e c t s i + Y e a r e f f e c t s t + ε i t

where i and t denote firm i at year t. The dependent variable, TFPit, refers to TFP measurements of the firm. The independent variable is ESOPit, which takes a value of 1 if the firm has an ESOP in year t, and 0 otherwise. Next, Controlsit is the array of control variables mentioned above. Year fixed effects and firm fixed effects are also included. Standard errors are clustered by firm. All variables are defined in Table 1.

Table 1. Definitions of main variables.

Empirical results

Descriptive statistics

Panel A of Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for the main variables. One can note that roughly 10.3% of the firms had ESOPs in China during the 2012 to 2018 study period. During this time, TFP_LP had a mean (median) value of 8.335 (8.239), while TFP_OP had a mean (median) value of 4.145 (4.065).

Table 2. Descriptive statistics of main variables.

Source: CSMAR database, Wind database.

Panel B of Table 2 shows the descriptive statistics among firms with ESOPs and firms without. As is shown, firms working with ESOPs in place have relatively higher TFP than firms without ESOP. One can also find that firms with ESOPs are older, larger, and more likely to be non-SOEs.

Table 2, Panel C shows the industry distribution of the sample. The machinery industry has the most sample firms (3686 firm-year observations). All the industries have ESOPs, and the furniture industry has the highest proportion of firms with ESOPs (18.02%). Besides, in the electronics industry, the ‘other manufacturing industry’, and the information technology industry categories, the percentages of firms with ESOPs are all above 14%.

Baseline regressions

This section presents the empirical results. One should note that all regressions include firm dummies across all specifications. While equation (3) includes an extensive set of variables that previous studies have found to affect a firm’s TFP, the results of this study could potentially have been spurious if the baseline model omitted any variables that affect both employee ownership and firm TFP. Given this concern, a more convincing estimation strategy would include firm fixed effects in equation (3) to absorb firm-specific unobservable factors.

Table 3 reports the estimation results. In Columns (1) and (2), we regress firm TFP on the ESOP indicator without controlling variables. Both the coefficients of ESOP are significant at the 1% level. The baseline model is further re-estimated, controlling firm characteristics, and the results are reported in Columns (3) and (4). The coefficients of ESOP are 0.0599 and 0.0442, respectively, suggesting that ESOPs increase firm TFP by approximately 5.99% and 4.42%. The economic effects are similar to the results in prior research (Reference Jones and KatoJones and Kato, 1995). Overall, these findings support this study’s hypothesis that implementing ESOPs can promote enterprises’ TFP, which is consistent with the relevant literature (Reference Jones and KatoJones and Kato, 1995; Reference Kim and OuimetKim and Ouimet, 2014).

Table 3. Impact of ESOPs on firm TFP.

*** Note. *** denotes statistical significance at the 1% level.

As can be seen, the estimates for the remaining variables are mostly significant with an expected sign. The significant coefficients of return on assets (ROA) are 1.4911 and 1.4432 and sales growth rate (Growth) are 0.2368 and 0.2169, suggesting that corporate financial performance is positively correlated with firm’s productivity. Also, larger, older and more leveraged firms demonstrate a better productivity performance, which is consistent with Reference Le, Pieri and ZaninottoLe et al. (2019). Nevertheless, the ratio of fixed assets is negatively associated with firm productivity. State ownership is not significantly associated with firm productivity, which is in line with Li (2020).

Mechanism analysis

This study concludes that ESOPs have a positive effect on firm TFP. Accordingly, we further consider the potential mechanisms through which ESOPs affect firm TFP. As discussed before, ESOPs might encourage firms to promote R&D activities and ease agency conflicts. These effects might be the channels through which ESOP increases firm productivity. This study selected RDinvest and Agency as the mediating variables and employed equations (4) and (5) for mechanism analysis:

(4) R D i n v e s t i t ( A g e n c y i t ) = θ 0 + θ 1 E S O P i t + Σ C o n t r o l s i t + F i r m e f f e c t s i + Y e a r e f f e c t s t + ε i t

(5) T F P i t = φ 0 + φ 1 E S O P i t + φ 2 R D i n v e s t i t ( A g e n c y i t ) + Σ C o n t r o l s i t + F i r m e f f e c t s i + Y e a r e f f e c t s t + ε i t

where RDinvest represents the investment in R&D activities, and Agency represents the firm’s agency cost. The definitions of these mediating variables were presented in Table 1.

Table 4 presents the regression results of the mechanism analysis. Taking R&D investment and agency cost as dependent variables, Columns (1) and (2) report the results of equation (4). The coefficient of ESOP to RDinvest is significantly positive, while the coefficient of ESOP to Agency is significantly negative. These findings indicate that a firm’s ESOP can promote R&D investment and mitigate agency problems.

Table 4. Mediating effects of firms’ agency costs and R&D investment.

* Note. ***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Then, based on equation (5), Columns (3) to (6) show the TFP regressions results, referring to the independent variable (ESOP) and the intermediary variables (RDinvest and Agency). The coefficients of RDinvest are significantly positive, while the coefficients of Agency are significantly negative, indicating that both R&D investment and agency cost mediate the influence of ESOPs on firm TFP. Also, the coefficients of ESOP in Columns (3) to (6) are relatively smaller than those in the baseline regressions, illustrating the sizes of the mediating effects. We further test these mediating effects through the Sobel approach, the Sobel’s Z-statistics presented in Table 4 are significant, suggesting the mediating effects are statistically significant. These findings imply that both the promotion of R&D investment and the reduction in agency cost are conducive to improving firm TFP, which supports Hypothesis 2a and Hypothesis 2b.

Moderation analysis

To test Hypothesis 3a and Hypothesis 3b, we formulate equation (6) and examine the moderating effect of state ownership and firm size on the relationship between ESOP and firm TFP.

(6) T F P i t = α 0 + δ 1 E S O P i t + δ 2 E S O P i t × S O E i t ( S i z e i t ) + Σ C o n t r o l s i t + F i r m e f f e c t s i + Y e a r e f f e c t s t + ε i t

where SOE represents state ownership, which equals 1 if the firm is state-owned, and 0 otherwise; Size represents the degree of the severity of the free-riding problem, which equals the natural logarithm of the number of employees.

Table 5 presents the regression results of the moderation analysis. In Columns (1) and (2), we target the interaction variable of ESOP×SOE. The negative coefficients of ESOP×SOE are both significant. Therefore, for state-owned enterprises, the promoting effect of ESOP on TFP is significantly hindered. In Columns (3) and (4), the interaction variable of ESOP×Size is emphasised. The coefficients of ESOP×Size are significantly negative, indicating that, for a large number of employee firms where the free-riding problem is more prevalent, the positive impact of ESOP on firm TFP is stymied.

Table 5. Moderation analysis.

* Note. ***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Who is motivated? Executives versus rank-and-file

When a firm adopts an ESOP, both executives and non-executives are potentially included in the plan and are then motivated to work. However, the shareholding proportion of executives and non-executives may lead to differences in the impact of ESOPs on firm performance (Reference Feng, Yu, Nan and CaiFeng et al., 2022). Previous studies have maintained that the rank-and-file (namely non-executive) employees should not be marginalised, and that non-executive ownership plays an important role in mitigating agency conflicts and curbing managerial risk-taking (Reference Faleye, Mehrotra and MorckFaleye et al., 2006; Reference Chen, King and WenChen et al., 2020). Thus, this study expects that non-employee ownership in ESOPs positively relates to the impact of ESOPs on firm TFP.

We then tested the effect of the differences in ESOP participants on the association between ESOPs and firm TFP. In firms’ existing ESOPs, this study employed variables ESOP_Ex, which measured the proportion of executive subscriptions, and ESOP_Non, which measured the proportion of non-executive subscriptions in existing ESOPs. The regression model is as follows:

(7) T F P i t = α 0 + α 1 E S O P _ E x i t + α 1 E S O P _ N o n i t + Σ C o n t r o l s + F i r m e f f e c t s i + Y e a r e f f e c t s t + ε i t

where ESOP_Ex represents the proportion of executive subscriptions, and ESOP_Non represents the proportion of non-executive subscriptions.

As reported in Table 6, the coefficients of ESOP_Non are significant at the 1% level, while the coefficients of ESOP_Ex are insignificant. These results imply that the ownership of non-executive employees is the determinant of the impact of ESOPs on firm TFP. This finding supports the idea that non-executives are highly motivated by ESOPs.

Table 6. Effects of subscription proportion of executives (non-executives).

*** Note. *** denotes statistical significance at the 1% level.

Robustness checks

The first concern with this study’s baseline regressions is that the particular ESOP may not be exogenous. To address this endogeneity concern, we used the 2SLS instrumental variable framework. According to Reference Jiang, Kim, Ma, Nofsinger and ShiJiang et al. (2017), a common practice is to use the category average of the independent variable, where the category seems likely to represent the corporation. We use the province–year proportion of other firms having ESOPs in the same province in the previous year (denoted ESOP_Neighbour) as our instrumental variable. A valid instrument must meet two criteria: a strong correlation with the instrumented regressors and orthogonality with the error term. First, due to the close geographical distance between enterprises in the province, imitation behaviour exists in equity grants (Reference Kedia and RajgopalKedia and Rajgopal, 2009) and the implementation of the ESOP by neighbouring enterprises. Therefore, variable ESOP_Neighbour might be significantly related to ESOP. Second, ESOPs of other local enterprises do not directly affect the TFP of the enterprise itself. Thus, this instrument variable can capture the probability of implementing the ESOPs but is unlikely to correlate with firms’ unobserved factors.

We regressed ESOP on the instrument and the controlling variables from the baseline model. The results are documented in Table 7. In Column (1), the estimated coefficient of ESOP_Neighbour is significant at the 1% level. Moreover, the F-statistic equals 48.07, suggesting that the instrument variable does not suffer from weak identification concerns (Reference Staiger and StockStaiger and Stock, 1997). Columns (2) and (3) in Table 7 report the results of the second stage of the 2SLS estimation. The estimated coefficients of ESOP are both significantly positive, implying that this study’s main findings are robust to the application of the 2SLS method.

Table 7. Robustness checks.

* Note. ***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Second, as shown in Panel B of Table 2, the sample firms with and without ESOPs are unbalanced. Hence, the heterogeneity in a firm’s characteristics may cause selection problems in the baseline estimates. Therefore, a propensity score matching (PSM) approach was used to address the selection bias.

Specifically, the probability of having an ESOP was estimated by running a Probit model to match each ESOP firm with a control non-ESOP firm, using a one-to-one nearest neighbour. The matching variables are the control variables mentioned above, along with the year fixed effect. To confirm that the matched sample is balanced, Table 8 presents the results of the covariate balance checks by testing the differences between ESOP firms and non-ESOP firms in the matched sample. The results indicate that the differences in the firm characteristics in the matched sample are not significant. We then re-estimated the baseline model in the matched sample. In Columns (4) and (5) of Table 7, the coefficients of ESOP are significantly positive. In addition, the magnitude of the coefficients for ESOP does not significantly change from those in the baseline regressions, indicating that the main findings are robust after considering the self-selection problem.

Table 8. Covariate checks in PSM samples.

Third, there is a concern that the impact of ESOPs on firm TFP might be lagged. To ease this concern, this study employed two alternative dependent variables, TFP_LP_L and TFP_OP_L, measured as one-year-lagged TFP_LP and TFP_OP, respectively. Then, the baseline model was re-estimated using lagged firms’ TFP indicators. The regression results are reported in Columns (6) and (7) of Table 7. As the results show, the coefficients of ESOP remain significantly positive, and the values of the coefficients are slightly smaller than those in the baseline regressions, indicating that the positive effect of ESOPs on firm TFP is still robust.

Lastly, we also report results when the alternative measure of ESOP is used. This study uses the ratio of subscribed shares in ongoing ESOPs to firm’s total shares, denoted as ESOP_Share. This quantitative measure can reflect the employees’ participation in ESOPs. As the results reported in Columns (8) and (9) of Table 7 show, the coefficients of ESOP_Share remain significantly positively.

Conclusion

Boosting firm productivity has been a crucial issue, both in practice and theory, especially for firms in emerging markets. How to best design an incentive mechanism to facilitate a firm’s productivity has been argued for decades. China’s economy benefited from opening-up market-oriented system reform and the profit-sharing policy in the reform. However, ESOP, a typical form of profit sharing and employee incentive, did not formally develop in Chinese firms until recent years. Little literature exists about the role of employee ownership in the productivity of China’s firms. Therefore, this paper tries to fill this gap and provide direction to enterprises in emerging capital markets.

Using a large sample of Chinese firms, we estimate the impact of ESOPs on firm productivity, as proxied by TFP. The empirical results suggest that ESOPs significantly improve firms’ TFP, and the economic effects are similar to prior research (Reference Jones and KatoJones and Kato, 1995). Then, we find that this increase in firm TFP is achieved by increasing R&D investment and mitigating agency costs. These results concur with previous research by confirming the role of ESOP in promoting innovation activities (Reference Kruse and BlasiKruse and Blasi, 1995) and enhancing employees’ interest alignment (Reference Jones and KatoJones and Kato, 1995). We also find that the positive effect of ESOPs on TFP is more pronounced in privately-owned firms. Besides, firms with fewer employees face smaller free-riding problems, hence the improvement of their ESOPs on firm TFP is more pronounced. Moreover, further analysis shows that the effect on firm TFP is positively related to the subscription proportion of non-executive employees in ESOPs.

In summary, our findings complement the current body of literature by identifying new channels through which ESOPs improve firm productivity. Specifically, ESOPs in Chinese firms improve productivity by promoting R&D investment and mitigating agency costs. Hence, firm managers in China should realise that ESOP is an effective incentive tool to stimulate production efficiency. Of particular note is that the improvement in firm productivity is weakened in certain conditions, such as state-owned property and serious free-riding problems, and the power of this employee incentive is diluted.

Funding

The author(s) disclosed receipt of the following financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article: This work was supported by the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities, and the Research Funds of Renmin University of China (21XNH001).

Footnotes

Declaration of conflicting interests

The authors declare no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship or publication of this article.

References

Abrami, RM, Kirby, WC, Mcfarlan, FW (2014) Why China can’t innovate. Harvard Business Review 92(3): 107111.Google Scholar
Ang, JS, Cole, RA, Lin, JW (2000) Agency costs and ownership structure. The Journal of Finance 55(1): 81106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aubert, N, Kern, A, Hollandts, X (2017) Employee stock ownership and the cost of capital. Research in International Business and Finance 41: 6778.Google Scholar
Bai, CE, Lu, J, Tao, Z (2006) The multitask theory of state enterprise reform: Empirical evidence from China. American Economic Review 96(2): 353357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borisova, G, Brockman, P, Salas, JM, Zagorchev, A (2012) Government ownership and corporate governance: Evidence from the EU. Journal of Banking and Finance 36(11): 29172934.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bradley, D, Kim, I, Tian, X (2013) Do unions affect innovation? Management Science 63(7): 22512271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caramelli, M, Briole, A (2007) Employee stock ownership and job attitudes: Does culture matter? Human Resource Management Review 17(3): 290304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, X, Fu, K, Low, A, Zhang, W (2015) Non-executive employee stock options and corporate innovation. Journal of Financial Economics 115(1): 168188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, HL, Huang, Y S (2006) Employee stock ownership and corporate R&D expenditures: Evidence from Taiwan’s information-technology industry. Asia Pacific Journal of Management 23(3): 369384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, J, King, THD, Wen, MM (2020) Non-executive ownership and private loan pricing. Journal of Corporate Finance 64(C): 101638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conyon, M, Gregg, P, Machin, S (1995) Taking care of business: Executive compensation in the United Kingdom. The Economic Journal 105(430): 704714.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doerr, S, Raissi, M, Weber, A (2018) Credit-supply shocks and firm productivity in Italy. Journal of International Money and Finance 87(C): 155171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dong, XY, Bowles, P, Ho, S (2002) Share ownership and employee attitudes: Some evidence from China’s postprivatization rural industry. Journal of Comparative Economics 30(4): 812835.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellem, B (2021) Labour and megaprojects: Rethinking productivity and industrial relations policy. The Economic and Labour Relations Review 32(3): 399416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faleye, O, Mehrotra, V, Morck, R (2006) When labor has a voice in corporate governance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41(3): 489510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feng, Y, Yu, Q, Nan, X, Cai, Y (2022) Can employee stock ownership plans reduce corporate financialization? Evidence from China. Economic Analysis and Policy 73(C):140151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrando, A, Ruggieri, A (2015) Financial constraints and productivity: Evidence from Euro area companies. International Journal of Finance and Economics 23(3): 257282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
French, JL (1987) Employee perspective on stock ownership: Financial investment or mechanism of control. Academy of Management Review 12(3): 427435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gamble, JE, Culpepper, R, Blubaugh, MG (2002) ESOPs and employee attitudes: The importance of empowerment and financial value. Personnel Review 31(1): 926.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hochberg, YV, Lindsey, L (2010) Incentives, targeting, and firm performance: An analysis of non-executive stock options. Review of Financial Studies 23(11): 41484186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hu, AG (2001) Ownership, government R&D, private R&D, and productivity in Chinese industry. Journal of Comparative Economics 29(1): 136157.Google Scholar
Jefferson, GH, Su, J (2006) Privatization and restructuring in China: Evidence from shareholding ownership, 1995–2001. Journal of Comparative Economics 34(1): 146166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiang, F, Kim, KA (2015) Corporate governance in China: A modern perspective. Journal of Corporate Finance 32(3): 190216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiang, F, Kim, KA, Ma, Y, Nofsinger, JR, Shi, B (2017) Corporate culture and investment–cash flow sensitivity. Journal of Business Ethics 154(2): 425439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jola-Sanchez, AF (2022) How does warfare affect firms’ productivity? Production and Operations Management. Epub ahead of print 3 January 2022.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, DC, Kato, T (1993) Employee stock ownership plans and productivity in Japanese manufacturing firms. British Journal of Industrial Relations 31(3): 331346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, DC, Kato, T (1995) The productivity effects of employee stock-ownership plans and bonuses: Evidence from Japanese panel data. The American Economic Review 85(3): 391414.Google Scholar
Kedia, S, Rajgopal, S (2009) Neighborhood matters: The impact of location on broad based stock option plans. Journal of Financial Economics 92(1): 109127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keller, W, Yeaple, SR (2009) Multinational enterprises, international trade, and productivity growth: Firm-level evidence from the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics 91(4): 821831.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, EH, Ouimet, P (2014) Broad-based employee stock ownership: Motives and outcomes. Journal of Finance 69(3): 12731319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kong, D, Tao, Y, Wang, Y (2020) China’s anti-corruption campaign and firm productivity: Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment. China Economic Review. 63(C):101535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kruse, D, Blasi, J (1995) Employee ownership employee attitude and firm performance. NBER Working Paper No. 5277. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le, M D, Pieri, F, Zaninotto, E (2019) From central planning towards a market economy: The role of ownership and competition in Vietnamese firms’ productivity. Journal of Comparative Economics 47(3): 693716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinsohn, JA, Petrin, A (2003) Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. The Review of Economic Studies 70(2): 317341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lieberman, MB, Dhawan, R (2005) Assessing the resource base of us and Japanese auto producers: A stochastic frontier production function approach. Management Science 51(7): 10601075.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, Y, Mao, J (2019) How do tax incentives affect investment and productivity? Firm-level evidence from China. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 11(3): 261291.Google Scholar
Mi, Z, Wang, X (2000) Agency cost and the crisis of China’s SOE. China Economic Review 11(3): 297317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Min, BS, Smyth, R (2014) Corporate governance, globalization and firm productivity. Journal of World Business 49(3): 372385.Google Scholar
O’Toole, CM, Morgenroth, ELW, Ha, TT (2016) Investment efficiency, state-owned enterprises and privatisation: evidence from Vietnam in transition. Journal of Corporate Finance 37: 93108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olley, GS, Pakes, A (1996) The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica 64(6): 12631297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ren, T, Xiao, Y, Yang, H , et al. (2019) Employee ownership heterogeneity and firm performance in China. Human Resource Management 58(6): 621639.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, AM, Wilson, N (2010) Employee financial participation and productivity: An empirical reappraisal. British Journal of Industrial Relations 44(1): 3150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schiffbauer, M, Siedschlag, I, Ruane, F (2017) Do foreign mergers and acquisitions boost firm productivity? International Business Review 26(6): 11241140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A, Vishny, RW (1997) A survey of corporate governance. The Journal of Finance 52(2): 737783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, RM (1957) Technical change and aggregate production function. Review of Economics and Statistics 39(3): 312320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Staiger, D, Stock, JH (1997) Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 65(3): 557586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Syverson, C (2011) What determines productivity? Journal of Economic Literature 49(2): 326365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsou, MW, Yang, CH (2019) Does gender structure affect firm productivity? Evidence from China. China Economic Review 55(C): 1936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uras, BR (2014) Corporate financial structure, misallocation and total factor productivity. Journal of Banking and Finance 39(C): 177191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wye, CK, Bahri, ENA (2021) How does employment respond to minimum wage adjustment in China? The Economic and Labour Relations Review 32(1): 90114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Definitions of main variables.

Figure 1

Table 2. Descriptive statistics of main variables.

Figure 2

Table 3. Impact of ESOPs on firm TFP.

Figure 3

Table 4. Mediating effects of firms’ agency costs and R&D investment.

Figure 4

Table 5. Moderation analysis.

Figure 5

Table 6. Effects of subscription proportion of executives (non-executives).

Figure 6

Table 7. Robustness checks.

Figure 7

Table 8. Covariate checks in PSM samples.