Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T08:31:24.749Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

History and Economics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2016

Extract

In a well-known paper published some years ago Donald McCloskey (1976) addressed his fellow economists on the importance of history to their discipline. He argued that greater emphasis on economic history would make for better economics and for better economists. It cannot be said that McCloskey’s arguments were taken to heart. The tendency for economists to expend their effort on (and award their honors for) the refinement of mathematical models and statistical techniques has continued unabated and perhaps has increased. This has led many scholars in related disciplines, social science historians in particular, to believe that economists are uninterested in history and unreceptive to arguments based on historical evidence.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Social Science History Association 1991 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alston, Lee J. (1984) “Farm foreclosure moratorium legislation: A lesson from the past.” American Economic Review 74: 445-57.Google Scholar
Balke, Nathan S., and Gordon, Robert J. (1989) “The estimation of prewar gross national product: Methodology and new evidence.Journal of Political Economy 97: 3892.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. (1983) “Nonmonetary effects of the financial crises in the propagation of the Great Depression.” American Economic Review 73: 257-76.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael D. (1981) “The classical gold standard: Some lessons for today.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 63: 117.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael D. (1989) “The contribution of A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960 to monetary history,” in Bordo, Michael D. (ed.) Money, History, and International Finance: Essays in Honor of Anna J. Schwartz. Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 1570.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael D., and Schwartz, Anna J. (1984) A Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Brown, E. Cary (1956) “Fiscal policy in the thirties: A reappraisal.” American Economic Review 46: 857-79.Google Scholar
Cagan, Phillip (1956) “The monetary dynamics of hyperinflation,” in Friedman, Milton (ed.) Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 25117.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1974) “The lighthouse in economics.” Journal of Law and Economics 17: 357-76.Google Scholar
Conrad, Alfred H., and Meyer, John R. (1958) “The economics of slavery in the ante bellum South.Journal of Political Economy 66: 95130.Google Scholar
David, Paul A. (1985) “Clio and the economics of QWERTY.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 75: 332-37.Google Scholar
David, Paul A., and Temin, Peter (1979) “Explaining the relative efficiency of slave agri culture in the antebellum South: A comment.American Economic Review 69:213-18.Google Scholar
Davis, Lance (1965) “The investment market, 1870-1914: Evolution of a national market.” Journal of Economic History 25: 355-99.Google Scholar
DeCanio, Stephen J. (1974) Agriculture in the Postbellum South: The Economics of Production and Supply. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Edelstein, Michael (1977) “U.K. savings in the age of high imperialism and after.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 67: 282-87.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry (1984) “Mortgage interest rates in the Populist Era.” American Economic Review 74: 9951015.Google Scholar
Evans, Paul (1982) “The effects of general price controls in the United States during World War II.” Journal of Political Economy 90: 944-66.Google Scholar
Field, Elizabeth B. (1988) “The relative efficiency of slavery revisited: A translog production function approach.” American Economic Review 78: 543-49.Google Scholar
Fishlow, Albert (1965) American Railroads and the Transformation of the Antebellum Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. (1964) Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. (1966) “Railroads as an analogy to the space effort.Economic Journal 76: 1643.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. (1989) Without Consent or Contract: The Rise and Fall of American Slavery. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. (1990) “Modelling complex dynamic interactions: The role of inter- generational, cohort, and period processes and of conditional events in the political realignment of the 1850s.” Working Paper Series on Historical Factors in Long Run Growth, no. 12. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W., and Engerman, Stanley L. (1974) Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. (1977) “Explaining the relative efficiency of slave agriculture in the antebellum South.American Economic Review 67: 275-96.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. (1980) “Explaining the relative efficiency of slave agriculture in the antebellum South: Reply.American Economic Review 70: 672-90.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Schwartz, Anna Jacobson (1963) A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Stigler, George (1946) Roofs or Ceilings? The Current Housing Problem. Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: Foundation for Economic Education.Google Scholar
Galenson, David W. (1981) “The market evaluation of human capital: The case of indentured servitude.” Journal of Political Economy 89: 446-67.Google Scholar
Garber, Peter M. (1989) “Tulipmania.” Journal of Political Economy 97: 535-60.Google Scholar
Garber, Peter M. (1990) “Who put the mania in the tulipmania?” in White, Eugene N. (ed.) Crashes and Panics. Homewood, IL: Dow Jones/Irwin: 332.Google Scholar
Goldin, Claudia (1988) “Maximum hours legislation and female employment: A reassessment.” Journal of Political Economy 96: 189205.Google Scholar
Goldin, Claudia (1990) Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic History of Ameri can Women. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Goldin, Claudia, and Sokoloff, Kenneth (1984) “The relative productivity hypothesis of industrialization: The American case, 1820-1850.Quarterly Journal of Economics 99: 461-88.Google Scholar
Good, David F. (1977) “Financial integration in late nineteenth-century Austria.” Journal of Economic History 37: 890910.Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. (1982) “Price inertia and policy ineffectiveness in the United States, 1890-1980.” Journal of Political Economy 90: 10871117.Google Scholar
Greenwald, Bruce C. and Glasspiegel, Robert R. (1983) “Adverse selection in the market for slaves: New Orleans, 1830-1860.Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 479500.Google Scholar
Haskell, Thomas L. (1979) “Explaining the relative efficiency of slave agriculture in the antebellum south: A reply to Fogel and Engerman.” American Economic Review 69: 206-7.Google Scholar
Hausman, William J. (1980) “A model of the London coal trade in the eighteenth century.Quarterly Journal of Economics 94: 1—14.Google Scholar
Higgs, Robert (1977) Competition and Coercion: Blacks in the American Economy, 1865-1914. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Higgs, Robert (1987) Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hughes, Jonathan (1973) The Vital Few: American Economic History and Its Protagonists. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Irwin, Douglas A. (1988) “Welfare effects of free trade: Debate and evidence from the 184OS.” Journal of Political Economy 96: 1142-64.Google Scholar
James, John (1976a) “Banking market structure, risk, and the pattern of local interest rates in the United States, 1893-1911.” Review of Economics and Statistics: 453-62.Google Scholar
James, John (1976b) “The development of the national money market.” Journal of Economic History 36: 878-97.Google Scholar
Kahn, James A. (1985) “Another look at free banking in the United States.” American Economic Review 75: 881-85.Google Scholar
Keehn, Richard (1975) “Market power and bank lending: Some evidence from Wisconsin, 1870-1900.” Journal of Economic History 35: 591620.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1930) A Treatise on Money. London: Macmillan and Co.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1964 [ 1936]) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Harbinger, Harcourt, Brace and World.Google Scholar
Landes, Elizabeth M. (1980) “The effect of state maximum-hour laws on the employment of women in 1920.” Journal of Political Economy 88: 476-94.Google Scholar
Lazonick, William (1981) “Factor costs and the diffusion of ring spinning in Britain prior to World War I.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 96: 89110.Google Scholar
Lewis, Frank D. (1983) “Fertility and savings in the United States: 1830-1900.” Journal of Political Economy 91: 825-40.Google Scholar
Libecap, Gary D., and Wiggins, Steven N. (1985) “The influence of private contractual failure on regulation: The case of oil field Unitization.Journal of Political Economy 93: 690714.Google Scholar
Lindert, Peter H. (1986) “Unequal English wealth since 1670.Journal of Political Economy 94: 1127-62.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N. (1976) “Does the past have useful economics?Journal of Economic Literature 14: 434-61.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N. (1980) “Magnanimous Albion: Free trade and British national income, 1841-1881.Explorations in Economic History 17: 303-20.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N. (1990) “Ancients and moderns.Social Science History 14: 289303.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N., and Nash, John (1984) “Corn at interest: The extent and cost of grain storage in medieval England.American Economic Review 74: 174-82.Google Scholar
MacKay, Charles (1852) Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowds, vol. 1. 2d ed., London: Office of the National Illustrated Library.Google Scholar
McPherson, James M. (1988) Battle Cry of Freedom. New York: Ballantine.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred (1961 [1920]) Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Neal, Larry D. (1990) “How the South Sea Bubble was blown up and burst: A new look at old data,” in White, Eugene N. (ed.) Crashes and Panics. Homewood, IL: DOW Jones/Irwin: 3346.Google Scholar
O’Brien, Anthony Patrick (1989) “A behavioral explanation for nominal wage rigidity during the Great Depression.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104: 719-36.Google Scholar
Olmstead, Alan L., and Rhode, Paul (1985) “Rationing without government: The West Coast gas famine of 1920.American Economic Review 75: 1044-55.Google Scholar
Peppers, Larry C. (1973) “Full-employment surplus analysis and structural change: The 1930s.” Explorations in Economic History 10: 197210.Google Scholar
Ransom, Roger, and Sutch, Richard (1977) One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rappoport, Peter, and White, Eugene (1990) “Was there a bubble in the 1929 stock market?” Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, Rutgers University.Google Scholar
Rashid, Salim (1988) “Quality in contestable markets: A historical problem?Quarterly Journal of Economics 103: 245-50.Google Scholar
Rockoff, Hugh (1974) “The free banking era: A re-examination.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 6: 141-73.Google Scholar
Rockoff, Hugh (1985) “New evidence on free banking in the United States.American Economic Review 75: 886-89.Google Scholar
Rolnick, Arthur J., and Weber, Warren E. (1983) “New evidence on the free banking era.American Economic Review 73: 1080-91.Google Scholar
Rolnick, Arthur J., and Weber, Warren E. (1984) “The causes of free bank failures: A detailed examination of the evidence.Journal of Monetary Economics 14: 267-91.Google Scholar
Rolnick, Arthur J., and Weber, Warren E. (1988) “Explaining the demand for free bank notes.Journal of Monetary Economics 21: 4771.Google Scholar
Romer, Christina D. (1986a) “Spurious volatility in historical unemployment data.” Journal of Political Economy 94: 137.Google Scholar
Romer, Christina D. (1986b) “Is the stabilization of the postwar economy a figment of the data?American Economic Review 76: 314-34.Google Scholar
Romer, Christina D. (1989) “The prewar business cycle reconsidered: New estimates of gross national product, 1869-1908.Journal of Political Economy 97: 137.Google Scholar
Romer, Christina D. (1990) “The great crash and the onset of the Great Depression.Quarterly Journal of Economics 105: 597624.Google Scholar
Rucker, Randal R., and Alston, Lee J. (1987) “Farm failures and government intervention: A case study of the 1930s.American Economic Review 77: 724-30.Google Scholar
Schaefer, Donald, and Schmitz, Mark D. (1979) “The relative efficiency of slave agriculture: A comment.American Economic Review 69: 208-12.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore (1964) Transforming Traditional Agriculture. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Smiley, Gene (1975) “Interest rate movements in the United States, 1888-1913.” Journal of Economic History 35: 591620.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1937 [1776]) The Wealth of Nations. ed. Cannan, Edwin. New York: Modern Library.Google Scholar
Smith, Bruce (1987) “Some colonial evidence on two theories of money.” Journal of Political Economy 95: 11781211.Google Scholar
Steckel, Richard (1986) “A peculiar population: The nutrition, health, and mortality of American slaves from childhood to maturity.” Journal of Economic History 46: 721-42.Google Scholar
Sylla, Richard (1969) “Federal policy, banking market structure, and capital mobilization in the United States, 1863-1913.” Journal of Economic History 29: 657–86.Google Scholar
Temin, Peter (1976) Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression? New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Whatley, Warren C. (1985) “A history of mechanization in the Cotton South: The institutional hypothesis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 100: 11911216.Google Scholar
White, Eugene N. (1990) “When the ticker ran late: The stock market boom and crash of 1929,” in White, Eugene N. (ed.) Crashes and Panics. Homewood, IL: Dow Jones/Irwin: 143-87.Google Scholar
Wicker, Elmus (1986) “Terminating hyperinflation in the dismembered Habsburg monarchy.” American Economic Review 76: 350-64.Google Scholar
Williamson, Jeffrey G. (1990) “The impact of the Corn Laws just prior to repeal.” Explorations in Economic History 27: 123-56.Google Scholar
Wright, Gavin (1978) The Political Economy of the Cotton South. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Wright, Gavin (1979) “The efficiency of slavery: Another interpretation.American Economic Review 69: 219-26.Google Scholar
Wright, Gavin (1981) “Cheap labor and southern textiles.Quarterly Journal of Economics 96: 605-30.Google Scholar