Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T04:08:53.292Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Social Market Economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 June 2009

Norman Barry
Affiliation:
Politics, University of Buckingham

Extract

The collapse of Communism in the regimes in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union has brought forth a plethora of alternative political and economic models for the reorganization of those societies. The vacuum that has been left could be regarded as an ideal laboratory for the testing of competing theories, and the temptations to experiment with the more benign forms of constructivist rationalism are likely to prove irresistible. If liberal capitalism is to be successfully created, it will clearly not have the same biography as it has had in the Western European and Anglo-American countries, where its emergence was the result of slow evolution: often its appearance and survival were due to a quite fortuitous combination of circumstances. In those countries it was not the result of any deliberate democratic choice but the outcome of a happy confluence of traditional rules and customary practices, and the participants in them had little idea of the form of the system that they were creating. Indeed, ideological sanctification was almost an afterthought, and democratic approval was belated and in most cases not enthusiastic. Britain was a liberal capitalist society, and possessed the necessary body of private law, some time before the franchise was significantly democratized (which did not occur until 1867). It is, of course, recent theoretical and empirical research which has revealed that the political choice mechanisms that developed haphazardly after the success of the market are a potential threat to it.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Social Philosophy and Policy Foundation 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 “Constructivist rationalism” designates that style of thinking which supposes that it is possible to impose on a social system a pattern of social and economic organization which is derived from a notion of human reason uninformed by experience and the lessons of tradition. It is most clearly exemplified in systems of centralized economic planning which dispense with the price signals provided by spontaneous markets. Constructivist rationalism presupposes that a single mind or institution is capable of organizing the necessarily dispersed knowledge in society. Its most articulate critic is F. A. Hayek, who does not limit his critique to rationalistic economic planning but includes refutations of attempts to design whole legal systems from a priori principles. See his Rules and Order, vol. 1Google Scholar of Law, Legislation, and Liberty (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1973).Google Scholar

2 Though, of course, the U.S. has been, with the exception of slavery, a liberal democracy since 1789.

3 James Buchanan's innovative works are especially relevant here. See his The Limits of Liberty (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975)Google Scholar, and Fiscal Theory and Political Economy (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1960)Google Scholar; Buchanan, James and Tullock, Gordon, The Calculus of Consent (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1962)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Buchanan, James and Wagner, Richard, Democracy in Deficit (New York: Academic Press, 1977).Google Scholar See also Tullock, Gordon, The Vote Motive (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1976).Google Scholar

4 von Mises, Ludwig, “Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth,” in Collectivist Economic Planning, ed. von Hayek, Friedrich (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1935), pp. 87130Google Scholar; Hayek, , “Socialist Calculation,”Google Scholar in Hayek, , Individualism and Economic Order (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1948), pp. 119208Google Scholar; Lavoie, Don, Rivalry and Central Planning: The Socialist Calculation Debate Reconsidered (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985).Google Scholar

5 See Galbraith, John Kenneth, The New Industrial State (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1978).Google Scholar

6 See reports in Express and Chronicle, Moscow, 03 3–10, 1992.Google Scholar

7 Kirzner, Israel, Discovery. Capitalism, and Distributive Justice (Oxford: Blackwell, 1989).Google Scholar

8 The most recent argument for market socialism is contained in Miller, David, Market, State, and Community: Theoretical Foundations of Market Socialism (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1989).Google Scholar

9 See Chiplin, Brian, Coyne, John, and Sire, Ljubo, Can Workers Manage? (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1977).Google Scholar

10 de Jasay, Antony, Market Socialism: A Scrutiny (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1991), p. 22.Google Scholar

11 Brodin, Eric, “Collapse of the Swedish Myth,” Economic Affairs, 02 1992, pp. 1422.Google Scholar

12 Swedish socialist thinkers (including Gunnar and Alva Myrdal) regarded the bourgeois family as an obstacle to the full realization of the welfare state. Hence, a whole range of family services, including home allowances, child care, and home care for the ill and elderly, are provided by the state. In addition to zero-priced medical care, everyone on sick leave gets 90 percent of their wage without a doctor's certification. Furthermore, incentives exist for unmarried motherhood, the right of parental discipline is severely restricted by law, and social workers have extensive powers to interfere with family life.

13 See Stein, Gabriel, “The Death of the Swedish Model,” Policy, vol. 7, no. 1 (1991), pp. 25.Google Scholar

14 Ibid., p. 4.

15 Quoted in Braum, Hans-Joachim, The German Economy in the Twentieth Century (London: Routledge, 1990), p. 178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 Most of the major works of the Ordo group are now available in English. See Standard Texts on the Social Market Economy (New York: Ludwig Erhard Institute. 1982).Google Scholar Especially important individual works are: Eucken, Walter, The Foundations of Economics (Edinburgh: William Hodge, 1951)Google Scholar, and This Unsuccessful Age (Edinburgh: William Hodge, 1951)Google Scholar; Röpke, Wilhelm, The Social Crisis of Our Time (Edinburgh: William Hodge, 1950)Google Scholar, and A Humane Economy (London: Wolf, 1960).Google Scholar

See also Zweig, Konrad, The Origins of the German Social Market Economy (London: Adam Smith Institute, 1980)Google Scholar; Germany's Social Market Economy: Origins and Evolution, ed. Peacock, Alan and Willgerodt, Hans (London: Macmillan, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and German Neo-Liberals and the Social Market Economy, ed. Peacock, Alan and Willgerodt, Hans (London: Macmillan, 1989).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17 For a historical account, see Stolper, Gustav, The German Economy: 1870 to the Present, new edition, revised by Hauser, Karl and Borchadt, Knut (London: Weidenfeld and Nicholson, 1967), pp. 219–72.Google Scholar

18 The three military governments had little idea what to do about the West German economy but probably favored the continuation of the controls. Erhard simply went ahead with the liberalization without asking their permission. He gambled that the success of the measures would make them irreversible. See Willgerodt, Hans, “Planning in West Germany: The Social Market Economy,” in The Politics of Planning, ed. Chickering, A. Lawrence (San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies, 1976), pp. 6182.Google Scholar

19 Quoted in ibid., p. 64.

20 See Gruchy, A., Comparative Economic Systems (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1977), ch. 5.Google Scholar

21 Tax incentives were offered to encourage investment, especially for house-building. There were also subsidies to agriculture and selected industries.

22 Olson, Mancur Jr., The Rise and Decline of Nations (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1982), pp. 129–33.Google Scholar

23 Braum, , German Economy in the Twentieth Century (see n. 15 above), ch. 8.Google Scholar

24 This was achieved by the Equalization of Burdens Act passed in 1952. For a description of the currency reform, see Bark, Dennis L. and Gress, David R., A History of West Germany: Vol. 1, From Shadow to Substance (Oxford: Blackwell, 1989), pp. 198209.Google Scholar

25 Lenel, Hans, “Does Germany Still Have a Social Market Economy?” in Germany's Social Market Economy (see n. 16 above), ch. 17.Google Scholar

26 See Hayek, Friedrich, “What is Social? What Does it Mean?” in Hayek, , Studies in Philosophy, Politics, and Economics (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1967), pp. 237–44.Google Scholar

27 Lenel, Hans, “Evolution of the Social Market Economy”, in German Neo-Liberals (see n. 16 above), ch. 2.Google Scholar

28 Müller-Armack, Alfred, “The Principles of the Social Market Economy”, German Economic Review, vol. 3, no. 1 (1965), p. 94.Google Scholar See also his “Economic Systems from a Social Point of View”, in Economy and Development, ed. Thesing, J. (Mainz: Konrad Adenauer-Stiftung, 1979), pp. 95122.Google Scholar

29 Röpke, , Social Crisis of Our Time (see n. 16 above), p. 119.Google Scholar

30 Erhard, Ludwig, Prosperity Through Competition (London: Thames and Hudson, 1958), p. 102.Google Scholar

31 Eucken, , This Unsuccessful Age (see n. 16 above), p. 93.Google Scholar

32 Ibid., pp. 31–33.

34 Röpke, , Social Crisis of Our Time, p. 4.Google Scholar

34 Quoted in Friedrich, C. J., “Political Thought of Neo-Liberalism”, American Political Science Review, vol. 49, no. 4 (1955), pp. 509–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35 See Böhm, Franz, “The Rule of Law”, in Germany's Social Market EconomyGoogle Scholar (see n. 16 above), ch. 4.

36 Eucken, , Foundations of Economics (see n. 16 above), pp. 80121.Google Scholar

37 See Kirzner, Israel, Competition and Entrepreneurship (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1973).Google Scholar

38 For a brilliant analysis of this issue, see Tumlir, Jan, “Franz Böhm and the Development of Economic-Constitutional Analysis”, in German Neo-LiberalsGoogle Scholar (see n. 16 above), ch. 6.

39 See Möschel, Werner, “Competition Policy from an Ordo Point of View”, in German Neo-LiberalsGoogle Scholar, ch. 7. For the argument that cartelization was not a serious problem for the German economy, see Wallich, H. C., Mainsprings of the Gennan Revival (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1955), p. 139.Google Scholar

40 Smith, Eric Owen, The West German Economy (London: Croom Helm, 1963), ch. 7.Google Scholar

41 Ibid., p. 213.

42 This is Eucken's instructive phrase; see his Foundations of Economics, pp. 8590.Google Scholar

43 Federalism seems to exist in the U.S. only in a “representational” form; i.e., the states are represented in Congress but lack the original constitutional protection of their authority. This seems to have been confirmed in a U.S. Supreme Court decision in 1985 (Garcia v. San Antonio Transit Authority). See Dye, Thomas R., American Federalism: Competition Among Governments (Lexington: D. C. Heath, 1990), ch. 1.Google Scholar

44 See Hamm, Walter, “The Welfare State at Its Limit”, in Germany's Social Market EconomyGoogle Scholar, ch. 12. For a philosophical critique of the welfare state, see Röpke, , Humane Economy (see n. 16 above), pp. 156–80.Google Scholar

45 See Kloten, Norbert, “The Role of the Public Sector in the Social Market Economy”, in German Neo-Liberals (see n. 16 above), ch. 4.Google Scholar

46 Röpke, , Social Crisis of Our Time (see n. 16 above), pp. 160–62.Google Scholar For a critique of marktkonform, see Radnitzky, Gerard, “The Social Market and the Constitution of Liberty”, in Britain's Cofistitutional Future, ed. Vibert, Frank (London: Institute of Economics, 1991), pp. 68.Google Scholar

47 Eucken, , Foundations of Economics, p. 29.Google Scholar

48 See McKinnon, Ronald, The Order of Economic liberalization (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991).Google Scholar

49 See Shlaes, Amity, “Germany's Treuhand – A Too Visible Hand,” Wall Street Journal Europe, 01 3, 1992.Google Scholar

50 See Passell, Peter, “A Capitalist Free-for-All in Czechoslovakia”, New York Times 04 12, 1992.Google Scholar

51 At the time of writing, it is apparent that the Czechoslovak republic is about to break up into Czech and Slovak entities. The future Slovak republic is almost certain to be less market-oriented and more nationalistic than its erstwhile partner.

52 See Bark, and Gress, , History of West Germany (see n. 24 above), p. 385.Google Scholar

53 Co-determination, i.e., the involvement of workers' representatives in the management of companies, was an early innovation in the West German economy. However, the power of final decision on key issues is left with the owners. See ibid., pp. 269–70.