Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T19:09:27.638Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Size, Composition, and Dynamics of the Russian State Bureaucracy in the 1990s

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2017

Abstract

In this paper Robert J. Brym and Vladimir Gimpelson analyze changes in the size and social composition of the Russian state bureaucracy in the 1990s based on official data. Although the Russian state bureaucracy grew somewhat at the regional level in the 1990s, it actually shrank at the federal level. Comparing the Russian state bureaucracy to the Weberian ideal type of bureaucratic efficiency, the authors also demonstrate the existence of strong gender and age segregation, with women and young people concentrated at lower levels and men and older people concentrated at higher levels. Furthermore, because many public officials were formally educated in the pre-perestroika era, they are poorly adapted to the needs of a modern state. Finally, circulation of new personnel through the bureaucracy, or bureaucratic “renewal,” is slow and occurs mainly at low-status levels. Circulation of personnel at high-status levels is practically nonexistent. Consequentiy, young recruits have little incentive to remain in state service and older officials confront little competition from either below or outside the state bureaucracy. Much of the inefficiency of the Russian state bureaucracy stems from these realities.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Association for Slavic, East European, and Eurasian Studies. 2004

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

This article was written within the framework of the project “Young Experts in the Russian Civil Service,” whose principal investigators were Vladimir Magun (Institute of Sociology, Russian Academy of Science) and Robert J. Brym (Department of Sociology, University of Toronto). The project is funded by the University of Calgary-Gorbachev Fund, Calgary, Canada. We are grateful to Vladimir Magun, whose focused and detailed comments did much to improve this paper. We also wish to thank T. Gorbacheva, R. Kapeliushnikov, L. Kosals, and G. Monusova, who offered many useful comments on and criticisms of our work. All errors, of course, remain ours alone.

1. Orlovsky, Daniel T., “Recent Studies on the Russian Bureaucracy,” Russian Review 35(1976): 453 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2. Mommsen, Wolfgang J., “Max Weber and the Regeneration of Russia,” Journal of Modern History 69(1997): 1-17 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3. Max, Shachtman, The Bureaucratic Revolution: The Rise of the Stalinist State(New York, 1962)Google Scholar.

4. Milovan, Djilas, The New Class: An Analysis of the Communist System(New York, 1957)Google Scholar.

5. Friedrich, Carl J.and Brzezinski, Zbigniew K., Totalitarian Dictatorship and Autocracy(Cambridge, Mass., 1956)Google Scholar.

6. Nystrom, Scott V.and Nystrom, Luella C., “Bureaucracy in Prehistory: Case Evidence from Mammoth Bone Dwellers in the Russian Steppes,” International Journal ofPublic Administration 21(1998): 7-23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7. Izvestiia, 22 August 2001, as reported in “Russian President Sets Up Commission to Reform State Bureaucracy,” BBC Monitoring Former Soviet UnionPolitical, 23 August 2001.

8. In Weber's usage, patrimonialism is a form of authority in which a ruler owns all property and regulates his subordinates through his personal beneficence. He exchanges favors for loyalty. Patrimonialism was rife in tsarist Russia, where thepractice of kormlenie(“feeding“) allowed the civil service to collect taxes and keep part of the revenue for itself. In a different form, it was virulent in Soviet Russia. It is a source of corruption and inefficiency today. According to Donald Jensen, recent instances of patrimonialism include the privatization of state property to insiders, loans-for-shares transactions, and state reliance on private banks to handle its money. Max, Weber, “Patriarchalism and Patrimonialism,“in Guenther, Rothand Claus, Wittich, eds., Economy and Society, trans., Ephraim, Fischoffet al. (New York, 1968), 3:1006-69Google Scholar; Jensen, Donald N., “Patrimonialism in Post- Soviet Russia,” Radio Free Europe/Radio Liberty,vol. 1, no. 75, pt. I (17July 1997)Google Scholar, also available at http://www.friends-partners.org/friends/news/omri/1997/07/970717l.html(last consulted 19 November 2003).

9. Fred, Weir, “Putin's Duel with the Bureaucrats,” Christian Science Monitor, 22February 2002 Google Scholar, reprinted in Center for Defense Information Russia Weekly, no. 194, available at http://www.cdi.org/russia/194-2.cfm(last consulted 19 November 2003).

10. Ibid.

11. Peter, Evansand Rauch, James E., “Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross-National Analysis of the Effects of'Weberian’ State Structures on Economic Growth,” American Sociological Review 64(1999): 748-65Google Scholar;James E. Rauch and Peter B. Evans, “Bureaucratic Structure and Bureaucratic Performance in Less Developed Countries/'/owrwaZ of Public Economics75 (2000): 49-71.

12. Obolonskii, A. V, ed., Gosudarstvennaia sluzhba(Moscow, 2000), 10 Google Scholar.

13. On the requirements associated with different groups, see “Federal'nyi zakon ot 31 iiuliia 1995 g. No. 119-F3 ‘Ob osnovakh gosudarstvennoi sluzhby Rossiiskoi Federatsii,'“ in Matirko, V. I.et al., comp., Gosudarstvennaia sluzhba: Sbornik normativnykh dokumenlov, 2-eizd., ispravlennoe i dopolnennoe(Moscow, 2001), 29-52 Google Scholar.

14. “Federal'nyi zakon ot 18 fevralia 1999 g. No. 35-F3 ‘Ob osnovakh gosudarstvennoi sluzhby Rossiiskoi Federatsii,'” in Matirko et al., comp., Gosudarstvennaia sluzhba, 52-53.

15. The most detailed is Sostav rabotnikov, zameshchavshikh gosudarstvennye i munitsipal'nye dolzhnosti, popolu, vozraslu, stazhu raboty, urovniu obrazovaniia na 1 ianvaria 2001 goda, 4 vols. (Moscow, 2001). A shorter version is presented in Statisticheskii biulleten’4, no. 78 (2001).

16. Trud v SSSR(Moscow, 1988), 30.

17. Ibid.; “Trud i zaniatost’ v Rossii,” Statisticheskii sbornik(Moscow, 1999).

18. “Trud i zaniatost'v Rossii,” 20.

19. Ibid.

20. Gimpelson, V.and Treisman, D., “Fiscal Games and Public Employment: A Theory with Evidence from Russia,” World Politics 54(2002): 145-83CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

21. Statisticheshii biulleten’4, no. 78 (2001): 8

22. Kulikov, M., “Reforma gosudarstvennogo upravleniia v ispolnitel'noi vlasti,” Ekonomicheskaia Elispertnaia Gruppa(Moscow, 2001), 3 Google Scholar, available at http://www.eeg.ru/PUBLICATIONS/p21.html (last consulted 19 November 2003)

23. Salvatore, Schiavo-Campo, Giulio de, Tommaso, and Amitabha, Mukherjee, “An International Statistical Survey of Government Employment and Wages,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1806(Washington, D.C., 1997)Google Scholar, available at http://www.eeg.ru/ PUBLICATIONS/p21.html">http://www.worldbank.org/html/ dec/Publications/Workpapers/WPS1800series/wpsl806/wpsl806.pdf">http://www.eeg.ru/ PUBLICATIONS/p21.html(last consulted 19 November 2003)

23. Salvatore, Schiavo-Campo, Giulio de, Tommaso, and Amitabha, Mukherjee, “An International Statistical Survey of Government Employment and Wages,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1806(Washington, D.C., 1997)Google Scholar, available at http://www.worldbank.org/html/ dec/Publications/Workpapers/WPS1800series/wpsl806/wpsl806.pdf (last consulted 19 November 2003).

24. In a separate analysis we found that the size of the state bureaucracy is considerably more sensitive to type of political regime (liberal, social-democratic, or former communist) if we include government employment in the education and health sectors. This suggests that some sectors of state bureaucracy are more sensitive to political forces than others.

25. Magun, V., Brym, R., Gimpel'son, V., Morozkov, S., and Chirikova, A., Molodye spetsialisty na Rossiiskoi gosudarstvennoi i munitsipal'noi sluzhbe: Nauchnyi otchet po itogam issledovaniia oblastnykh i gorodskikh administratsii(Moscow, 2003)Google Scholar, available at http://2001.isras.ru/Publications/Magun/YoungFunc/Young_Funcs_Title.htm(last consulted 19 November 2003).

26. Ibid.

27. Doeringer, Peter B.and Piore, Michael J., Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis(Lexington, Mass., 1971)Google Scholar.

28. Peter, Evans, “The State as Problem and Solution: Predation, Embedded Autonomy, and Structural Change,”in Haggard, S.and Kaufman, R., eds., The Politics of Economic Adjustment: International Constraints, Distributive Conflicts, and the State(Princeton, 1992), 139-81Google Scholar.

29. Statisticheskii biulleten’ 4, no. 78 (2001): 57.

30. Gimpelson, Vand Lippoldt, D., The Russian Labour Market: Between Transition and Turmoil(Lanham, Md., 2001)Google Scholar; Kapeliushnikov, R., Rossiiskii rynok truda: Adaptatsiia bez restrukturizatsii(Moscow, 2001)Google Scholar.

31. Transition Report 1999(London, 1999), 106; Ivan, Szelenyiand Glass, C., “Winners of the Reforms: The New Economic and Political Elite”(unpublished paper, University of California, 2000)Google Scholar.

32. Gimpelson and Lippoldt, Russian Labour Market. The 18 percent estimate includes both the formal and the informal economies. The figure for the formal economy alone would be considerably less than 18 percent.

33. Putin, V., Kontseptsiia: Reformirovanie gosudarstvennoi sluzhby Rossiiskoi Federatsii(Moscow, 2001)Google Scholar.

34. For an example of such research, see Magun, Brym, Gimpel'son, Morozkov, and Chirikova, Molodye spetsialisty na Rossiiskoi gosudarstvennoi i munitsipal'noi sluzh