Published online by Cambridge University Press: 05 August 2009
The interpretation of Edmund Burke as a laissez-faire economist has a long pedigree but is inaccurate. Rather, Burke is best seen as a moderate Whig who believed that governmental social and economic policy should be based on pragmatic and prudential considerations. However, utilitarian rule-making makes most sense when the rules can be formulated in terms of realizing some more abstract goal. This goal Burke obtained from his reading of the Scotch moral sense writers, who convinced him that man has an innate moral nature which can be improved through association with other men in society. Consideration of Burke's writings on a variety of specific economic and social issues, ranging from poor relief and economic reform to the slave trade, confirms this instrumental interpretation of Burke's economic thought.
1 Cobban, Alfred, Edmund Burke and the Revolt Against the Eighteenth Century (New York: Barnes and Noble, 1960)Google Scholar, for example, was able to interpret Burke as a precursor of the Romantics without noting their extensive disagreement on practical political issues and social policy.
2 Namier, Lewis, The Structure of Politics at the Accession of George III (New York: Macmillian and Company, 1928).Google Scholar
3 A good example is Pares, Richard, King George III and the Politicians (New York: Oxford University Press, 1970)Google Scholar, who believes that foreign policy offered some exception to Namier's general rules.
4 On Burke as a laissez-faire economist, see Barrington, Donald Patrick Michael, “Edmund Burke as an Economist,” Economica, New Series, 21 (1954): 252–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Petrella, Frank Jr., “Edmund Burke: A Liberal Practioner of Political Economy,” Modern Age 8 (1963–1964): 52–60Google Scholar. The Burke-Smith relationship is reviewed in Dunnes, W. L., “Adam Smith and Burke: Complementary Contemporaries,” Southern Economic Journal 7 (1941): 330–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Fay, C. R., The World of Adam Smith (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1950), chap. 1Google Scholar. The case for Adam Smith as a laissez-faire thinker is presented in Viner, Jacob, “Adam Smith and Laissez-Faire,” The Long View and the Short: Studies in Economic Theory and Policy (Glencoe, Illinois, 1958)Google Scholar; Skinner, Andrew, Adam Smith and the Role of the State (Glasgow, 1974)Google Scholar; Hayek, Fredrich, Individualism and Economic Order (London, 1948)Google Scholar; and Cropsey, Joseph, Political Economy: An Interpretation of the Principles of Adam Smith (The Hague, 1957).Google Scholar
5 Stanlis, Peter J., Edmund Burke and the Natural Law (Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press, 1958).Google Scholar
6 Gandy, Clara I. and Stanlis, Peter J., Edmund Burke A Bibliography of Secondary Studies to 1982 (New York: Garland Publishing, Inc., 1983), p. 213.Google Scholar
7 Himmelfarb, Gertrude, The Idea of Poverty (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1984), pp. 66–73.Google Scholar
8 Ibid., p. 43.
9 Ibid., p. 66 ff.
10 Macpherson, C. B., Burke (New York: Hill and Wang, 1980).Google Scholar
11 Ibid., p. 50.
12 See especially Kramnick, Isaac, “The Left and Edmund Burke,” Political Theory 11 (05 1983): 189–214Google Scholar. Oddly, Kramnick stresses Woodrow Wilson's praise of Burke: “for Wilson, Burke was the embodiment of racial wisdom, the instinctive common sense and practical soul of the Anglo-Saxon” (p. 197). Burke was, of course, not Anglo-Saxon. See also Kramnick, 's The Rage of Edmund Burke (New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1977), passim.Google Scholar
13 Pocock, J. G. A., “Burke's Analysis of the French Revolution,” in Virtue, Commerce, and History (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985), pp. 193–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
14 Burke, Edmund, The Correspondence of Edmund Burke (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1958–1978), vol. 2Google Scholar, to Smith, Adam, 10/09/1759, pp. 129–130.Google Scholar
15 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Smith, Adam, 7/12/1786, 5:296.Google Scholar
16 Burke, Edmund, “Letter to a Noble Lord,” The Works of the Right Honorable Edmund Burke (Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1889 – ), 5:174 ff.Google Scholar
17 Ibid., p. 189.
18 Winch, Donald, Adam Smith's Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1978), pp. 46 ffCrossRefGoogle Scholar. Also see Campbell, T. D., Adam Smith's Science of Morals (Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Littlefield, 1971), p. 205 ff.Google Scholar
19 See, for example, Bryson, Gladys, Man and Society: the Scottish Inquiry of the 18th Century (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1945).Google Scholar
20 Hutcheson, Francis, “A Short Introduction to Moral Philosophy,” Collected Works of Francis Hutcheson (Hildesheim: George Olms, 1969), vol. 4.Google Scholar
21 Ibid., p. 4.
22 Ibid., pp. 16–17.
23 Ibid., p. 36 ff. See especially, p. 56
24 Campbell, , Adam Smith's Science of Morals, p. 232.Google Scholar
25 Quoted in Burke, , Correspondence, 1:129.26.Google Scholar
26 Burke, Edmund, A Philosophical Enquiry into the Origin of Our Ideas of the Sublime and Beautiful (Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press, 1958), p. 13.Google Scholar
27 Ibid., p. 23.
28 Burke, Edmund, “Appeal From the New to the Old Whigs,” Works, 6:57–215Google Scholar; 166. See pp. 164–69.
29 Campbell, , Adam Smith's Science of Morals, p. 205.Google Scholar
30 Ibid., p. 213.
31 Burke, Edmund, “An Appeal from the New to the Old Whigs,” p. 81.Google Scholar
32 Burke, , Reflections On the Revolution in France (Bobbs-Merrill), pp. 194–95.Google Scholar
33 Campbell, , Adam Smith's Science of Morals, p. 214.Google Scholar
34 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to O'Hara, Charles, 26/07/1775, 3:182.Google Scholar
35 Winch, , Adam Smith's Politics, p. 172.Google Scholar
36 Smith, Adam, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (New York: Random House, Inc., 1937), p. 653 ff.Google Scholar
37 Ibid., p. 716 ff.
38 Ibid., p. 769 ff.
39 Ibid., p. 859 ff.
40 Ibid., p. 308.
41 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Charles-Jean-Francois Depont, Nov./1789, 6: 46.
42 Burke, Edmund, “Thoughts and Details on Scarcity,” Works, 5:131–69.Google Scholar
43 Macpherson, , Burke, p. 52 ff.Google Scholar
44 Ibid., p. 53.
45 Burke, , “Thoughts and Details on Scarcity,” especially pp. 134–37 and 141–42.Google Scholar
46 Ibid., p. 165.
47 Ibid., p. 135–36.
48 Ibid., p. 134.
49 Ibid., p. 137.
50 Ibid., p. 157.
51 Ibid., p. 142.
52 Ibid., p. 135.
53 Ibid., p. 146.
54 Ibid.
55 Ibid., p. 154.1
56 Ibid., p. 166.
57 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Windham, William, 9/06/1795, 8:265.Google Scholar
58 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Windham, William, 17/11/1795, 8:341 ff.Google Scholar; and to Dundas, Henry, 6/12/1795, 8:353ff.Google Scholar
59 Burke, , “Thoughts and Details on Scarcity,” p. 164.Google Scholar
60 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Woodford, Captain Emperor John Alexander, 9/12/1796, 9:155.Google Scholar
61 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Ridge, John, 23/04/1763, 3:169.Google Scholar
62 Burke, Edmund, “Speech to the Electors at Bristol,” Works, 2:385.Google Scholar
63 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to O'Hara, Charles, 26/07/1775, 3:181–82.Google Scholar
64 Townsend, Joseph, A Dissertation on the Poor Laws (Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1971), p. 19 ff.Google Scholar
65 Smith, , Wealth of Nations, p. 413.Google Scholar
66 Townsend, , Dissertation on Poor Laws, p. 24.Google Scholar
67 Ibid., p. 27.
68 Ibid., p. 40.
69 Smith, , Wealth of Nations, p. 79.Google Scholar
70 Ibid., p. 66 and p. 87 ff.
71 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Pitt, William, 7/11/1795, 8:337.Google Scholar
72 Ibid., p. 337.
73 Kramnick, , Rage of Edmund Burke, p. 161.Google Scholar
74 Ibid., p. 161.
75 Macpherson, , Burke, p. 29.Google Scholar
76 Burke, Edmund, “Speech on Presenting to the House of Commons a Plan for the Better Security of the Independence of Parliament, and the Economic Reformation of the Civil and Other Establishments,” Works, 2:265–364.Google Scholar
77 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Harford, Joseph, 4/04/1780, 4:219–20.Google Scholar
78 Burke, , “Letter to a Noble Lord,” p. 195.Google Scholar
79 Ibid., p. 195.
80 Burke, , “Economic Reformation,” pp. 286–87.Google Scholar If one examines Burke's seven rules of procedure, one finds extensive discussion of the importance of order and system and very little of cost-cutting.
81 Ibid., p. 334.
82 Ibid., p. 335.
83 Ibid., p. 291.
84 Ibid., p. 298.
85 Ibid., p. 310.
86 Ibid., p. 311.
87 Ibid., p. 351.
88 Ibid., p. 310–11. Macpherson's comment is at Burke, pp. 29–30.Google Scholar
89 Burke, , “Economic Reformation,” p. 311.Google Scholar
90 For the significance of the American Indians in eighteenth-century sociology, see Meek, Ronald L., Social Science and the Ignoble Savage (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1976), pp. 37 ff.Google Scholar
91 Burke, Edmund, An Account of the English Settlements in America, 2 Vol. (New York: Research Reprints, Inc., 1970), 1:167–68.Google Scholar
92 Ibid., p. 31. See also, p. 257.
93 Burke, , Account, 2:128.Google Scholar
94 Ibid., pp. 128–29.
95 Ibid., pp. 130–31.
96 Ibid., p. 131.
97 Burke, Edmund, “Sketch of a Negro Code,” Works, 6:262–89.Google Scholar
98 Ibid., p. 262.
99 Ibid., p. 263 ff.
100 Ibid., p. 265 ff.
101 Ibid., p. 273 ff.
102 Ibid., p. 275 ff.
103 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Dundas, Henry, 9/04/1792, 7:122.Google Scholar
104 Ibid., p. 123.
105 Ibid., p. 124.
106 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Windham, William, 28/03/1796, 8:451.Google Scholar
107 See the editorial note following the letter to Dundas, , Correspondence, 7:125.Google Scholar
108 Ibid.
109 Burke's evaluation of the Navigation Acts may be found at “Speech on American Taxation,” Works, 6:31 ff.Google Scholar A more critical view is in “Observations on a Late Publication Entitled “The Present State of the Nation,” Works, 1:269–432; 394 ff.Google Scholar
110 For an application of the natural law thesis to Burke's view of Civil liberties, see Wilkins, Burleigh T., The Problem of Burke's Political Philosophy (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1967), esp. pp. 42 ff.Google Scholar
111 Burke, Edmund, “Fragments of a Tract Relative to the Laws Against Popery in Ireland,” Works, 6:299–360.Google Scholar
112 For Anglophone conservative, see Preece, Rod, “The Political Economy of Edmund Burke,” Modern Age 24 (1980): 266–73.Google Scholar
113 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Robertson, William, 9 or 10/06/1777, 3:350–52.Google Scholar The work in question was Robertson, 's History of AmericaGoogle Scholar.
114 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Dupont, Adrien-Jean-Francois, Post 29/03/1790, 6:108.Google Scholar
115 Burke, , CorrespondenceGoogle Scholar, to Markham, William, 9/11/1771, 2:282.Google Scholar