Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-ndw9j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-02T23:08:22.572Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Why do civil wars occur? Another look at the theoretical dichotomy of opportunity versus grievance

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 June 2011

Abstract

The purpose of this article is to review major theoretical arguments with regard to the causes of civil war and identify problems associated with the conceptual juxtaposition of opportunity versus grievance that predominates in the field. While they are critical aspects of conflict processes, perception of opportunity and grievance as two mutually competing explanations or separate categories ultimately can limit, rather than facilitate, our understanding of civil conflicts. For example, we show that not all motives can be designated easily as deriving from one or the other. In addition, the existing dichotomous framework masks other important questions about the way that collective action is achieved in some circumstances and not others or the way that some factors seem to generate grievances at one stage, perhaps, but then an opportunity at another or vice versa. Thus the priority should be to develop an integrated, comprehensive approach that can account for fundamental aspects of complex conflict processes. We conclude by providing suggestions for future research on civil conflict.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © British International Studies Association 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Fearon, James D. and Laitin, David D., ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War’, American Political Science Review, 97:1 (2003), pp. 7590CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

2 In this article we use rebellion/insurgency, civil conflict, domestic/internal conflict, and armed domestic violence interchangeably, as we are reviewing a wide literature. It is important to note, however, that arguments can be made regarding the separate and distinguishing features of these conflicts.

3 Sambanis, Nicholas, ‘A Review of Recent Advances and Future Directions in the Quantitative Literature on Civil War’, Defence and Peace Economics, 13:3 (2002), p. 217CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

4 For reviews of this rapidly expanding literature, see Sambanis, ‘A Review of Recent Advances’; Sambanis, Nicholas, ‘What is Civil War? Conceptual and Emprical Complexities of an Operational Definition’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48:6 (2004), pp. 814858CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Lacina, Bethany, ‘From Side Show to Center Stage: Civil Conflict after the Cold War’, Security Dialogue, 35:2 (2004), pp. 191205CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; and Zeynep Taydas and Matthew Wilson, ‘Developing the Literature on Civil War Onset: Evolving Concepts and Model’, unpublished manuscript (2011).

5 Collier, Paul and Hoeffler, Anke, ‘On The Economic Causes of Civil Wars’, Oxford Economic Papers, 50:4 (1998), pp. 563573CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Collier, Paul and Hoeffler, Anke, ‘Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars’, Oxford Economic Papers, 56:4 (2004), pp. 563595CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

6 Collier and Hoeffler, ‘Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars’; Collier, Paul, Hoeffler, Anke and Sambanis, Nicholas, ‘The Collier-Hoeffler Model of Civil War Onset and the Case Study Project Research Design’, in Collier, Paul and Sambanis, Nicholas (eds), Understanding Civil War: Evidence and Analysis (Washington, DC: The World Bank, 2005)Google Scholar .

7 Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis (eds), Understanding Civil War; Collier and Hoeffler, ‘Greed and Grievance’; Fearon and Laitin, ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War’; Jackson, Paul, ‘The March of the Lord's Resistance Army: Greed or Grievance in Northern Uganda?’, Small Wars and Insurgencies, 13:3 (2002), pp. 2952CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Regan, Patrick M. and Norton, Daniel, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization in Civil Wars’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49:3 (2005), pp. 319336CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Thyne, Clayton L., ‘ABC's, 123's, and the Golden Rule: The Pacifying Effect of Education on Civil War, 1980–1999’, International Studies Quarterly, 50:4 (2006), pp. 733754CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; and Vinci, Anthony, ‘Greed and Grievance Reconsidered: The Role of Power and Survival in the Motivation of Armed Groups’, Civil Wars, 8:1 (2006), pp. 2545CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

8 The norm in the civil war literature is to acknowledge economic development as an opportunity, with regime type/democracy as a grievance-related factor. See Collier and Hoeffler, ‘Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars’. However, Walter places the anocracy variable under ‘opportunity theories’ and per capita income under ‘grievance theory/motives’. See Walter, Barbara F., ‘Information, Uncertainty, and the Decision to Secede’, International Organization, 60:1 (2006), pp. 120, 123, 126, 105135CrossRefGoogle Scholar tables 1, 3, and 4. By contrast, Saxton and Benson place economic development under ‘motivations’ and regime type and repression under ‘opportunities’. See Saxton, Gregory D. and Benson, Michelle, ‘Means, Motives, and Opportunities in Ethno-Nationalist Mobilization’, International Interactions, 34 (2008), p. 67CrossRefGoogle Scholar . These examples reveal the difficulty associated with implementing the dichotomy of opportunity and grievance in a consistent manner. For more on these challenges see Ballentine, Karen and Sherman, J., The Political Economy of Armed Conflict: Beyond Greed and Grievance (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 2003)Google Scholar ; Berdal, Mats and Malone, David, Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 2000)Google Scholar ; Regan and Norton, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization’; and Walter, ‘Information, Uncertainty, and the Decision to Secede’.

9 Lichbach, Mark I., ‘Contending Theories of Contentious Politics and the Structure- Action Problem of Social Order’, Annual Review of Political Science, 1 (1998), p. 404CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

10 Gurr, Ted Robert, Minorities at Risk: A Global View of Ethnopolitical Conflicts, (Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press, 1993)Google Scholar .

11 Gurr, Ted Robert, Why Men Rebel, (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1970)Google Scholar ; Rule, James B., Theories of Civil Violence, (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1988)Google Scholar .

12 Gurr, , Why Men Rebel, pp. 3637Google Scholar .

13 Regan and Norton, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization’.

14 Gurr, Ted Robert, ‘A Causal Model of Civil Strife: A Comparative Analysis Using New Indices’, American Political Science Review, 62:4 (1968), pp. 11041124CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Gurr, Why Men Rebel.

15 Gurr, ‘A Causal Model of Civil Strife’; Gurr, Why Men Rebel.

16 Regan and Norton, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization’.

17 For examples see, Midlarsky, Manus, ‘Rulers and the Ruled: Patterned Inequality and the Onset of Mass Political Violence’, American Political Science Review, 82:2 (1988), pp. 491509CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Mitchell, Edward J., ‘Inequality and Insurgency: A Statistical Study of South Vietnam’, World Politics, 20:3 (1968), pp. 421438CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Muller, Edward N., ‘Income, Inequality, Regime Repressiveness and Political Violence’, American Sociological Review, 50:1 (1985), pp. 4761CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Muller, Edward N. and Seligson, Mitchell A., ‘Inequality and Insurgency’, American Political Science Review, 81:2 (1987), pp. 425441CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Nagel, Jack H., ‘Inequality and Discontent: A Nonlinear Hypothesis’, World Politics, 26:4 (1974), pp. 453472CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Russett, Bruce M., ‘Inequality and Instability: The Relation of Land Tenure to Politics’, World Politics, 16:3 (1964), pp. 442454CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Sigelman, Lee and Simpson, Miles, ‘A Cross-National Test of the Linkage between Economic Inequality and Political Violence’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 21:1 (1977), pp. 105128CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; and Weede, Erich, ‘Income Inequality, Average Income and Domestic Violence’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 25:4 (1981), pp. 639654Google Scholar .

18 See Caprioli, Mary, ‘Primed for Violence: The Role of Gender Inequality in Predicting International Conflict’, International Studies Quarterly, 49:2 (2005), pp. 161178CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Gurr, Minorities at Risk; Gurr, Ted Robert, ‘Why Minorities Rebel: A Global Analysis of Communal Mobilization and Conflict since 1945’, International Political Science Review, 14:2 (1993), pp. 161201CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Regan and Norton, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization’; Moore, Will H., Lindstrom, Ronny and O'Regan, Valeria, ‘Land Reform, Political Violence and the Economic Inequality-Political Conflict Nexus: A Longitudinal Analysis’, International Interactions, 21:4 (1996), pp. 335363CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Gurr, Ted Robert and Moore, Will H., ‘Ethnopolitical Rebellion: A Cross-Sectional Analysis of the 1980s with Risk Assessments for the 1990s’, American Journal of Political Science, 41:4 (1997), pp. 10791103CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Melander, Erik, ‘Gender Equality and Intrastate Armed Conflict’, International Studies Quarterly, 49:4 (2005), pp. 695714CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Regan, Patrick M., Sixteen Million One: Understanding Civil War, (Boulder, CO: Paradigm Publishers, 2009)Google Scholar ; Saxton, Gregory D., ‘Repression, Grievances, Mobilization, and Rebellion: A New Test of Gurr's Model of Ethnopolitical Rebellion’, International Interactions, 31:1 (2005), pp. 87116CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Saxton and Benson, ‘Means, Motives, and Opportunities’; and Thyne, ‘ABCs, 123s’.

19 Collier and Hoeffler, ‘On the Economic Causes of Civil Wars’; Collier, Paul and Hoeffler, Anke, ‘On the Incidence of Civil War in Africa’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46:1 (2002), pp. 1328CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Collier and Hoeffler, ‘Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars’; Fearon and Laitin, ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War’; Hauge, Wenche and Ellingsen, Tanja, ‘Beyond Environmental Scarcity: Causal Pathways to Conflict’, Journal of Peace Research, 35:3 (1998), pp. 299317CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Moore, Lindstrom and O'Regan, ‘Land Reform, Political Violence and the Economic Inequality-Political Conflict Nexus’; Weede, ‘Income Inequality, Average Income and Domestic Violence’; and Weede, Erich, ‘Some New Evidence on the Correlates of Political Violence: Income Inequality, Regime Repressiveness, and Economic Development’, European Sociological Review, 3:2 (1987), pp. 97108CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

20 Regan and Norton, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization’.

21 Caprioli, ‘Primed for Violence’; Melander, ‘Gender Equality and Intrastate Armed Conflict’.

22 Nel, Philip and Righarts, Marjolein, ‘Natural Disasters and the Risk of Violent Civil Conflict’, International Studies Quarterly, 52:1 (2008), pp. 159185CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

23 Repression refers to systematic violation of political rights (like human rights and respect for people's personal integrity) and civil liberties (such as freedom of expression) of individuals or groups by the government to weaken their resistance to the will of the authorities.

24 See Collier, and Hoeffler, , ‘On the Incidence of Civil War in Africa’; Hanne Fjelde, ‘Buying Peace? Oil Wealth, Corruption and Civil War, 1985–99’, Journal of Peace Research, 46:2 (2009), pp. 199218Google Scholar ; and Jakobsen, Tor G. and Soysa, Indra De, ‘Give me Liberty, Give me Death! State Repression, Ethnic Grievance and Civil War, 1982–2004’, Civil Wars, 11:2 (2009), pp. 137157CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

25 Regan and Norton, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization’.

26 Thoms, Oskar N. T. and Ron, James, ‘Do Human Rights Violations Cause Internal Conflict?’, Human Rights Quarterly, 29:3 (2007), pp. 674705CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

27 See, for example, Muller, ‘Income, Inequality, Regime Repressiveness and Political Violence’; Weede, ‘Some New Evidence on the Correlates of Political Violence’; and Muller, Edward N. and Weede, Erich, ‘Cross-national Variation in Political Science: A Rational Action Approach’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 34 (1990), pp. 624651CrossRefGoogle Scholar . Davenport refers to these seemingly contradictory findings regarding the affect that repression has on dissent as the ‘punishment puzzle’. See Davenport, Christian, ‘State Repression and Political Order’, Annual Review of Political Science, 10:1 (2007), pp. 123CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

28 Regan and Norton, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization’.

29 Tarrow, Sidney, Struggle, Politics, and Reform: Collective Action, Social Movements, and Cycles of Protest, (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Center for International Studies, 1998), p. 8Google Scholar .

30 Eisinger, Peter. K., ‘The Conditions of Protest Behavior in American Cities’ American Political Science Review, 67 (1973), p. 11CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

31 Olson, Mancur, The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press, 1965)Google Scholar ; Tarrow, Sidney, Power in Movement: Social Movements, Collective Action and Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994)Google Scholar ; McAdam, Doug, Tarrow, Sidney and Tilly, Charles, ‘To Map to Contentious Politics’, Mobilization, 1 (1996) pp. 1734Google Scholar ; McAdam, Doug, Tarrow, Sidney and Tilly, Charles, ‘Towards an Integrated Perspective on Social Movements and Revolution’, in Lichbach, Mark Irving and Zuckerman, Alan S. (eds), Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure (Cambridge: University of Cambridge Press, 1997), pp. 142173Google Scholar ; Lichbach, Mark I., The Rebel's Dilemma (Ann Harbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 1995)CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; McCarthy, John D. and Zald, Mayer N., ‘Resource Mobilization and Social Movements: A Partial Theory’, American Journal of Sociology, 82:6 (1977), pp. 12121241CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Moore, Will H., ‘Rational Rebels: Overcoming Free-rider Problem’, Political Research Quarterly, 48:2 (1995), pp. 417454CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Muller, Edward N. and Opp, Karl-Dieter, ‘Rational Choice and Rebellious Collective Action’, American Political Science Review, 80:2 (1986), pp. 471487CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

32 Tilly, Charles, From Mobilization to Revolution, (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 1978)Google Scholar .

33 Lichbach, Mark I., ‘Will Rational People Rebel Against Inequality? Samson's Choice’, American Journal of Political Science, 34:4 (1990), pp. 10491076CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Lichbach, Mark I., ‘Rethinking Rationality and Rebellion: Theories of Collective Action and Problems of Collective Dissent’, Rationality and Society, 6 (1994), pp. 839CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Lichbach, Mark I., ‘What Makes Rational Peasants Revolutionary: Dilemma, Paradox, and Irony in Peasant Collective Action’, World Politics, 46 (1994), pp. 383418CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Lichbach, ‘Contending Theories of Contentious Politics’.

34 See Lichbach, ‘Contending Theories of Contentious Politics’; Schock, Kurt, ‘A Conjectural Model of Political Conflict: The Impact of Political Opportunities on the Relationship between Economic Inequality and Violent Political Conflict’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 40:1 (1996), pp. 98133CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Snyder, D., ‘Collective Violence: A Research Agenda and Some Strategic Considerations’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 22:3 (1978), pp. 499534CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Snyder, D. and Tilly, Charles, ‘Hardship and Collective Violence in France, 1830 to 1960’, American Sociological Review, 37 (1972), pp. 520532CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Tarrow, Struggle, Politics, and Reform; and Tilly, From Mobilization to Revolution. In addition, the opportunity approach emphasises both resource mobilisation and opportunity structures. See Jenkins, J. Craig and Perrow, Charles, ‘Insurgency of the Powerless Farm Worker Movements (1946–1972)’, American Sociological Review, 42 (1977), pp. 249268CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Snyder and Tilly, ‘Hardship and Collective Violence in France’; Tilly, Charles, ‘Revolutions and Collective Violence’, in Greenstein, F. I. and Polsby, N. W. (eds), Handbook of Political Science, 3 (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 1975), pp. 483555Google Scholar ; Muller and Opp, ‘Rational Choice and Rebellious Collective Action’; Jenkins, J. C. and Klandermans, B., The Politics of Social Protest: Comparative Perspectives on States and Social Movements (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1985)Google Scholar ; McCarthy and Zald, ‘Resource Mobilization and Social Movements’; Wilson, K. L. and Orum, A. M., ‘Mobilizing People for Collective Political Action’, Journal of Military and Political Sociology, 4 (1976), pp. 187202Google Scholar ; and Snow, David A., Rochford, E. Burke, Worden, Steven K. and Benford, Robert D., ‘Frame Alignment Processes, Micromobilization, and Movement Participation’, American Sociological Review, 51:4 (1986), pp. 464481CrossRefGoogle Scholar for more details.

35 Tilly, From Mobilization to Revolution; Tarrow, Power in Movement.

36 Political mobilisation refers to organisation and commitment of the group and acquisition of resources to sustain collective action. See McAdam, Tarrow and Tilly, ‘To Map to Contentious Politics’ and Tarrow, Power in Movement.

37 Kahl, Colin H., ‘Population Growth, Environmental Degradation, and State-Sponsored Violence: The Case of Kenya, 1991–93’, International Security, 23:2 (1998), pp. 80119CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Urdal, Henrik, ‘A Clash of Generations? Youth Bulges and Political Violence’, International Studies Quarterly, 50:3 (2006), p. 610CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

38 Sambanis, ‘A Review of Recent Advances’, p. 223 referencing Olson, The Logic of Collective Action and Tullock, Gordon G., The Social Dilemma: The Economics of War and Revolutions (Blacksburg, VA: Center for the Study of Public Choice, 1974)Google Scholar .

39 Finkel, Steven E., Muller, Edward N. and Opp, Karl-Dieter, ‘Personal Influence, Collective Rationality, and Mass Political Action’, American Political Science Review, 83:3 (1989), pp. 885903CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

40 Regan and Norton, ‘Greed, Grievance, and Mobilization’. Also see Regan, Sixteen Million One.

41 See, for example, Lichbach, The Rebel's Dilemma; Lichbach, ‘Contending Theories of Contentious Politics’; Moore, ‘Rational Rebels’; Olson, The Logic of Collective Action. For an excellent review of mechanisms to overcome collective action problems associated with rebellion, see Lichbach, The Rebel's Dilemma.

42 Weinstein, Jeremy, Inside Rebellion: The Politics of Insurgent Violence (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007)Google Scholar .

43 Note that the relative ease of measuring opportunity – as compared to motivations and grievances – also has contributed to empirical testing of this theory.

44 Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler, ‘On The Economic Causes of Civil Wars’; Collier and Hoeffler, ‘Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars’; Fearon and Laitin, ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War’; Buhaug, Halvard, ‘Relative Capability and Rebel Objective in Civil War’, Journal of Peace Research, 43:6 (2006), pp. 691708CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

45 Walter, Barbara F., ‘Building Reputation: Why Governments Fight Some Separatists but Not Others’, American Journal of Political Science, 50:2 (2006), pp. 313330CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

46 Gurr and Moore, ‘Ethnopolitical Rebellion’.

47 Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler, ‘Greed and Grievance in Civil War’, Policy Research Working Paper No. 2355 (Washington, DC: World Bank, 2001); Collier, Hoeffler and Sambanis, ‘The Collier-Hoeffler Model of Civil War Onset’.

48 Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarCrossRefGoogle Scholar .

49 Ngaruko, Floribert and Nkurunziza, Janvier D., ‘Civil War and Its Duration in Burundi’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar ; Humphreys, Macartan and Mohamed, Habaye Ag, ‘Senegal and Mali’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar ; Zinn, Annalisa, ‘Theory Versus Reality: Civil War Onset and Avoidance in Nigeria since 1960’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar ; Makdisi, Samir and Sadaka, Richard, ‘The Lebanese Civil War, 1975–90’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar .

50 Lund, Michael S., ‘Greed and Grievance Diverted: How Macedonia Avoided Civil War, 1990–2001’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar ; Zinn, ‘Theory Versus Reality’.

51 Snyder, Richard, ‘Does Lootable Wealth Breed Disorder? A Political Economy of Extraction Framework’, Comparative Political Studies, 39:8 (2006), pp. 943968CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

52 Lowi, Miriam R., ‘Algeria, 1992–2002: Anatomy of a Civil War’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar .

53 Kalyvas, Stathis N. and Sambanis, Nicholas, ‘Bosnia's Civil War: Origins and Violence Dynamics’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil War, pp. 222223Google Scholar .

54 Ndikumana, Leonce and Emizet, Kisangani F., ‘The Economics of Civil War: The Case of the Democratic Republic of Congo’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar .

55 Ross, Michael L., ‘Resources and Rebellion in Aceh, Indonesia’, in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar .

56 Taydas, Zeynep, Peksen, Dursun and James, Patrick, ‘Why Do Civil Wars Occur? Understanding the Importance of Institutional Quality’, Civil Wars, 12:3 (2010), pp. 195217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

57 Buhaug, ‘Relative Capability and Rebel Objectives’.

58 Davenport, ‘State Repression and Political Order’.

59 Gurr, , Why Men Rebel, p. 238Google Scholar .

60 Gurr, Ted Robert, Peoples Versus States: Minorities at Risk in the New Century (Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press, 2000)Google Scholar .

61 Lichbach, Mark I., ‘Deterrence or Escalation? The Puzzle of Aggregate Studies of Repression and Dissent’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 31:2 (1987), p. 269CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

62 Thyne, ‘ABCs, 123s’; Zeynep Taydas and Dursun Peksen, ‘Can States Buy Peace? Social Welfare Spending and Civil War Onset’, unpublished manuscript (2011).

63 Collier, Paul, Elliott, L., Hegre, Harvard, Hoeffler, Anke, Reynal-Querol, M. and Sambanis, Nicholas, Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy (Washington, DC: Oxford University Press, 2003)Google Scholar .

64 Kalyvas, Stathis N., The Logic of Violence in Civil War (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006)CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Metelits, Claire, ‘The Logic of Change: Pushing the Boundaries of Insurgent Behavior Theory’, Defense and Security Analysis, 25:2 (2009), pp. 105118CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Weinstein, Inside Rebellion.

65 Keen, David, ‘Liberalization and Conflict’, International Political Science Review, 26:1 (2005), pp. 7389CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

66 David Keen, ‘“Since I am a Dog, Beware my Fangs”: Beyond a “Rational Violence” Framework in the Sierra Leonean War’, Crisis States Working Papers No. 14 (London: Development Research Centre, London School of Economics, 2002); Keen, ‘Liberalization and Conflict’.

67 Keen, ‘Liberalization and Conflict’; Mark Bradbury, ‘Rebels without a Cause? An Exploratory Report on the Conflict in Sierra Leone’ (CARE International, April 1995).

68 Ibid.

69 Ibid.

70 David M. Malone and Heiko Nitzschke, ‘Economic Agendas in Civil Wars: What We Know, What We Need to Know’, UNU-WIDER Discussion Paper No. 7, 2005), p. 6.

71 Olsson, Ola and Fors, Heather Congdon, ‘Congo: The Prize for Predation’, Journal of Peace Research, 41:3 (2004), pp. 321336CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

72 Prominent treatments of patrimonial politics in Africa include Reno, William, Warlord Politics and African States (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 1999)Google Scholar and Flint, Julie and Waal, Alex de, Darfur: A New History of a Long War (African Arguments) (New York: Zed Books, 2008)Google Scholar . Reno draws attention to the uniqueness of these political systems in Africa. The practice of warlordism combines with penetration by international organisations and great powers to create situations that challenge efforts at generalisation. Similarly, Flint and de Waal paint a picture of Sudan that includes a wide range of actors. The works of these authors and others who focus on patrimonialism remind us that complexity is the norm in African conflicts.

73 Jackson, ‘The March of the Lord's Resistance Army’; Vinci, ‘Greed and Grievance Reconsidered’; Vinci, Anthony, ‘Existential Motivations in the Lord's Resistance Army's Continuing Conflict’, Studies in Conflict and Terrorism, 30:4 (2007), pp. 337352CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

74 Ibid., p. 40.

75 Ibid., p. 47.

76 See Vinci, ‘Existential Motivations’. In fact, much of the qualitative literature on civil war points to a number of important causal factors that the quantitative literature does not. This is precisely because of the latter's focus on grievance and opportunity. This may be due in part to the fact that the qualitative approach to civil war starts by treating ideologically driven conflicts and ethnic conflicts as two distinctly different analytical concepts, while the quantitative literature begins with an amalgam concept that is easier to quantify. The result is that the qualitative approach has been able uncover a variety of important causal factors such as leadership and loyalty. As an example, see Branch, Daniel, Defeating Mau Mau, Creating Kenya: Counterinsurgency, Civil War, and Decolonization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009)Google Scholar .

77 DeRouen, Karl R. and Sobek, David, ‘The Dynamics of Civil War Duration and Outcome’, Journal of Peace Research, 41:3 (2004), pp. 303320CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

78 Fearon and Laitin point out that organisationally, financially and/or politically weak central governments make insurgencies relatively more attractive through poor local policing and inept or corrupt counterinsurgency practices. See Fearon and Laitin, ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War’, pp. 75–6.

79 Tilly, Charles, The Politics of Collective Violence (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), p. 41CrossRefGoogle Scholar . For examples see, Buhaug, ‘Relative Capability and Rebel Objectives’; Fearon and Laitin, ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War’.

80 It is a common practice in the literature to assess state capacity (especially the coercive capacity of the state) as described above using a catchall proxy, namely, income per capita. See Fearon and Laitin, ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War’; and Lacina, Bethany, ‘Explaining the Severity of Civil Wars’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50:2 (2006), pp. 276289CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

81 Levi, Margaret, ‘Why Do We Need A New Theory of Government?’, Perspectives on Politics, 4:1 (2006), p. 5CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

82 Levi defines this concept as ‘compliance motivated by a willingness to cooperate but backed by motivation’. See Levi, ‘Why Do We Need a New Theory of Government?’, p. 7.

83 Azam, Jean-Paul, ‘Redistributive State and Conflicts in Africa’, Journal of Peace Research, 38:4 (2001), p. 435CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

84 Mason, David T., Weingarten, Joseph P. Jr., and Fett, Patrick J., ‘Win, Lose, or Draw: Predicting the Outcome of Civil Wars’, Political Research Quarterly, 52:2 (1999), pp. 239268CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; DeRouen and Sobek, ‘The Dynamics of Civil War Duration and Outcome’, p. 304.

85 Walter, ‘Building Reputation’, p. 324; Walter, ‘Information, Uncertainty, and the Decision to Secede’, p. 106.

86 Fearon, James D., ‘Why Do Some Civil Wars Last So Much Longer Than Others?’, Journal of Peace Research, 41:3 (2004), pp. 275301CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Walter, ‘Building Reputation’; Walter, ‘Information, Uncertainty, and the Decision to Secede’; and Walter, Barbara F., Reputation and Civil War: Why Separatist Conflicts Are So Violent (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

87 Fearon, James D., ‘Signaling Versus the Balance of Power and Interests: An Empirical Test of a Crisis Bargaining Model’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 38:2 (1994), pp. 236269CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Fearon, James D., ‘Signaling Foreign Policy Interests: Tying Hands Versus Sinking Costs’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41:1 (1997), pp. 6890CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Fearon, James D., ‘Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation’, International Organization, 52:2 (1998), pp. 269305CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

88 Gurr, Peoples Versus States; Marshall, Monty G. and Gurr, Ted R., Peace and Conflict, 2003: A Global Survey of Armed Conflicts, Self-Determination Movements, and Democracy (Baltimore: Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland, 2003)Google Scholar .

89 Ibid.

90 Bartkus, Viva Ona, The Dynamics of Secession, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

91 Diehl, Paul F. (ed.), A Road Map to War: Territorial Dimensions of International Conflict (Nashville, TN: Vanderbilt University Press, 1999)Google Scholar ; Toft, Monica D., The Geography of Ethnic Conflict: Identity, Interests, and the Indivisibility of Territory (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003)Google Scholar .

92 Berdal, Mats, ‘Beyond Greed and Grievance-and Not Too Soon…A Review Essay’, Review of International Studies, 31 (2005), p. 689Google Scholar .

93 Ballentine, and Sherman, , The Political Economy of Armed Conflict, p. 6Google Scholar .

94 Gurr, , Peoples Versus States, p. 66Google Scholar .

95 See, for example, Cioffi-Revilla, Claudio and Starr, Harvey, ‘Opportunity, Willingness and Political Uncertainty: Theoretical Foundations of Politics’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 7:5 (1995), pp. 447476CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

96 Murshed, S. Mansoob, ‘Inequality, Indivisibility and Insecurity’, unpublished manuscript (2005), p. 1.

97 Gurr, Minorities at Risk; Gurr, Peoples Versus States; Saxton, ‘Repression, Grievances, Mobilization, and Rebellion; Saxton and Benson, ‘Means, Motives, and Opportunities’.

98 Gurr, , Minorities at Risk, p. 124Google Scholar .

99 Gurr, , Minorities at Risk, p. 63Google Scholar .

100 See, for example, Brancati, Dawn, ‘Political Aftershocks: The Impact of Earthquakes on Intrastate Conflict’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 51:5 (2007), pp. 715743CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Jason S. Enia, ‘Shaking The Foundations of Violent Civil Conflict: Institutions, Disasters, and the Political Economies of State-Rebel Interaction’, (PhD Dissertation: University of Southern California, 2009); and Nel and Righarts, ‘Natural Disasters and the Risk of Violent Civil Conflict’.

101 Ngaruko and Janvier D. Nkurunziza, ‘Civil War and Its Duration in Burundi’.

102 Zinn, ‘Theory Versus Reality’.

103 Humphreys and Mohamed, ‘Senegal and Mali’.

104 Ibid.

105 Makdisi and Richard Sadaka, ‘The Lebanese Civil War’.

106 Lund, ‘Greed and Grievance Diverted’.

107 Zinn, ‘Theory Versus Reality’.

108 Ngaruko and Janvier D. Nkurunziza, ‘Civil War and Its Duration in Burundi’.

109 Lowi, ‘Algeria, 1992–2002’.

110 Kalyvas and Nicholas Sambanis ‘Bosnia's Civil War’.

111 Olsson and Fors, ‘Congo: The Prize for Predation’; Ndikumana and Emizet, ‘The Economics of Civil War’.

112 Weinstein, Jeremy and Francisco, L., ‘The Civil War in Mozambique’ in Collier, and Sambanis, (eds), Understanding Civil WarGoogle Scholar .

113 Ross, ‘Resources and Rebellion in Aceh’; Aspinall, Edward, ‘The Construction of Grievance Natural Resources and Identity in a Separatist Conflict’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 51:6 (2007), pp. 950972CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

114 Zinn, ‘Theory Versus Reality’.

115 Humphreys, Macartan and Weinstein, Jeremy M., ‘Who Fights? The Determinants of Participation in Civil War’, American Journal of Political Science, 52:2 (2008), pp. 436455CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

116 The cases and years coded as false negatives in the table represent years where the Collier-Hoeffler model predicts a low probability for civil war when it actually occurred. For those cases and years coded as false positives, the model predicts a high probability for civil war, but in reality civil war either does not break out or the violence that does occur misses the threshold of 1,000 battle-related deaths that is commonly used to identify civil wars.