Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T13:18:58.310Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Choc de revenu et éducation des enfants en présence d'imperfection du marché du crédit.Le cas du Malawi*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Get access

Résumé

Cet article montre que les ménages utilisent le retrait des enfants du système éducatif comme stratégie ex-post de gestion des chocs de revenu qu'ils subissent. L'analyse souligne également qu'un grand nombre d'enfants dans un ménage affecte négativement la probabilité de scolarisation des enfants, mettant ainsi en exergue l'existence d'un arbitrage dans l'allocation des ressources d'éducation entre les enfants du ménage. Cet arbitrage de ressources laisse place à un effet d'incitation lorsque l'on prend en compte la scolarisation des frères et soeurs: des enfants ayant des frères et sœurs scolarisés ont de plus grande chance d'aller à l'école. Ce résultat remet ainsi en cause l'hypothèse largement acceptée de dilution de ressources intra-ménages pour l'éducation.

Summary

Summary

This paper shows that households take children out of school as risk coping strategy in response to income shocks under binding credit constraints. The analysis also highlights trade-off in resource allocation for education. A higher number of children in household decreases the probability of their schooling. Instead of the resource competition among siblings, the results show an incitation effect when the schooling status of brothers and sisters is taken into account: children with brothers and sisters going to school have better chance to go to school. This result challenges the generally admitted hypothesis of resource competition among siblings in the literature. A new incitation effect, highlighting the positive effect of siblings schooling on the probability of schooling of other children in the household is thus put forward.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2010 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

**

CERDI-CNRS, Université d'Auvergne, Clermont-Ferrand, France; International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, USA.

*

Une version préliminaire de cet article a reçu la mention du Prix Jean-Claude Eicher d'Economie de I'Education. L'auteur remercie Leandre Bassolé, Todd Benson, Anne-Sophie Kaïs, Rachid Laajaj, Luc Désiré Omgba ainsi que deux rapporteurs anonymes pour leurs commentaires et critiques.

References

Bibliographie

Becker, G. et Tomes, N. (1986), “Human Capital and the Rise and Fall of Families”, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 4, n° 3, pp. sl–s39.Google Scholar
Beegle, K., Rajeev, D. et Roberta, G. (2003), “Child Labor, Income Shocks, and Access to Credit”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, n°. 3075.Google Scholar
Chernichovsky, D (1985), “Socioeconomic and Demographic Aspects of School Enrolment and Attendance in Rural Botswana”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 33, n° 2, pp. 319332.Google Scholar
de Janvry, A., Finan, F., Sadoulet, E. et Vakis, R. (2006), “Can Conditional Cash Transfert Serve as Safety Nets in Keeping Children at School and from Working when Exposed to Shocks?”, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 79, n° 2, pp. 349373.Google Scholar
Duryea, S., Lam, D. et Levison, D. (2007), “Effects of Economic Shocks on Children’s Employment and Schooling in Brazil”, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 84, n° 1, pp. 188214.Google Scholar
Fuller, B., Singer, J.D. et Kelly, M. (1995), “Why do Daughters Leave School in Southern Africa? Family Economy and Mothers’ Commitments”, Social forces, vol. 74, n° 2, pp. 657680.Google Scholar
Guarcello, L., Mealli, F. et Rosati, F. (2003), “Household Vulnerability and Child Labor: The Effects of Shocks, Credit Rationing, and Insurance”, Understanding Children’s Work Working Paper, n°3.Google Scholar
Jacoby, H. et Skoufias, E. (1997), “Risk, Financial Markets, and Human Capital in a Developing Country”, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 64, n°3, pp. 311335.Google Scholar
Jensen, R. (2000), “Agricultural Volatility and Investments in Children”, American Economic Review, vol. 90, n°2, pp. 399404.Google Scholar
Kazianga, H. et Udry, C. (2006), “Consumption Smoothing? Livestock, Insurance and Drought in Rural Burkina Faso”, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 79, n° 2, pp. 413446.Google Scholar
Levhari, D. et Weiss, Y. (1974), “The effect of Risk on the Investment in Human Capital”, American Economic Review, vol. 64, n°6, pp. 950963.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D. et Weil, D. (1992), “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 107, n°2, pp. 407437.Google Scholar
Parish, W. et Willis, R. (1993), “Daughters, Education, and Family Budgets Taiwan Experiences”, The Journal of Human Resources, vol. 28, n° 4, pp. 863898.Google Scholar
Parker, S. et Skoufias, E. (2000), “Parental Unemployment, Marital Status Changes and Child Human Capital: Evidence from Urban Mexico”, IFPRI Mimeo.Google Scholar
Paxson, C.H. (1992), “Using Weather Variability to Estimate the Response of Savings to Transitory income in Thailand”, American Economic Review, vol. 82, n°l, pp. 1533.Google Scholar
Sawada, Y. (2003), “Income Risks, Gender, and Human Capital Investment in a Developing Country”, CIRJE Working Paper, F-198.Google Scholar
Sawada, Y. et Lokshin, M. (2001), “Household Schooling Decisions in Rural Pakistan”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, n° 2541.Google Scholar
Townsend, R. (1994), “Risk and Insurance in Village India”, Econometrica, vol. 62, n°3, pp. 539591.Google Scholar
Zeldes, S.P. (1989), “Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 104, n°2, pp.275298.Google Scholar