Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T04:53:59.124Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Optimal design for network mutual aid

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 October 2022

Jingchao Li
Affiliation:
College of Mathematics and Statistics, Shenzhen University, Nanhai Ave 3688, Shenzhen, Guangdong 518060, P.R. China Shenzhen Key Laboratory of Advanced Machine Learning and Applications, Shenzhen University, Shenzhen, Guangdong 518060, P.R. China
Zichen Fang
Affiliation:
College of Mathematics and Statistics, Shenzhen University, Nanhai Ave 3688, Shenzhen Guangdong 518060, P.R. China. E-mail: [email protected]
Ciyu Nie
Affiliation:
Division of Banking and Finance, College of Business (Nanyang Business School), 50 Nanyang Avenue, Singapore 639798, Singapore. E-mail: [email protected]
Sizhe Chen
Affiliation:
Department of Actuarial Studies and Business Analytics, Macquarie University, Macquarie Park, Sydney, NSW 2109, Australia
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Network mutual aid platforms is one of the popular risk-sharing models in recent years, and they have almost 200 million members in China. However, current mutual aid platforms does not satisfy the actuarial rules in either the apportionment method or the pricing principle. Hence, a variety of mutual aid models which enable mutual aid members with different risks to exchange their risks in a transparent and actuarial fair way have been proposed in this paper. Besides, the decision-making frameworks for participants choosing between the mutual aid platform and similar insurance products, or choosing no risk sharing are constructed, respectively. Decisions are made based on the principle of maximizing expected utility. Moreover, the optimization problems of maximizing profit and minimizing risk are constructed, respectively. Through the principle of individual fairness and relative fairness, the problem of adverse selection of the platform can also be reduced. Finally, the actual mutual aid plan is compared with similar insurance products to discuss the advantages of the optimized plan.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

The concept of mutual aid funds can be traced back to hundreds of years ago. A typical example is the collegium tenuiorum of the Roman Empire which was mentioned in Ginsburg [Reference Ginsburg17] and Perry [Reference Perry21] and its main function is to assist its members in paying for funeral expenses. Members pay the membership entrance fee and monthly membership fee into the fund, which is managed by the association. When a member dies, collegium tenuiorum uses its mutual fund to assist the family members of the deceased to pay for funeral expenses and may provide bequests on behalf of the deceased. Historically, there have been many similar mutual aid organizations that shared resources and risks through self-funding within a group of people who has common interests, but most of them were limited to a certain size of the population.

With the development of society, individuals begin to transfer risks through insurance. Nowadays, most of the commercial insurance are relatively mature, but due to operating costs, brand premium, corporate profits, and other factors, the insurance premiums are normally higher than the actual average payout cost. The premium could be unaffordable for the population with low income but high risk. Carlin [Reference Carlin7] discussed the price complexity in retail financial markets. The company divides the price into direct fees and indirect involuntary surcharges, and designs a new technical language for price disclosure. This behavior of increasing industry profits by reducing industry pricing clarity is common in markets such as term life insurance, life annuities, and credit cards. Therefore, Donnelly et al. [Reference Donnelly, Guillén and Nielsen15] proposed a decomposed annuity structure, which can disclose costs and improve the transparency of financial and insurance products.

In response to these shortcomings of insurance products, the market produces new products to transfer risks. The advent of the Internet era has brought a new round of economic reforms. The development of technologies such as big data, blockchain, and artificial intelligence have subtly changed people's lifestyles and thinking patterns. With the development of Internet economy, the insurance industry is also seeking breakthroughs and development amidst reforms. The rise of the sharing economy points out a new direction for insurance. New forms of risk-sharing such as P2P insurance and network mutual aid are based on the principle of sharing economy, which cuts down the cost of the intermediaries by eliminating or reducing the role of traditional insurance companies. We specially review the literature of network mutual aid and P2P insurance in the next two subsections.

1.1. Network mutual aid

Since the establishment of the first mutual aid platform named Kang Ai Gong She in 2011 in China, network mutual aid platforms grew rapidly. By 2015, there were 50 mutual aid platforms in China, and network mutual aid once became a hot topic in the Internet field. However, with the return of capital to rationality and regulatory pressure, a large scaled collapse of mutual aid platforms occurred in 2017, and only a few mutual aid platforms survived. Until the second half of 2018, Ant Financial, JD.com, Suning, and other capital giants successively carried out network mutual aid business. The regulatory rectification of Xianghubao has once again aroused widespread attention on the risk and supervision of network mutual aid platforms. As of May 2020, there were more than 150 million people who have joined network mutual aid platforms in China and the amount of mutual aid has exceeded 5 billion yuan. Zhao and Zeng [Reference Zhao and Zeng30] introduced the historical background and development of mutual aid platform.

However, network mutual aid platforms need to be supervised by regulator because they do not follow actuarial principles and lack of risk assessment. Besides, compared with insurance institutions, they also lack rigid guarantee commitment. The mutual aid platform places eligible participants in the same pool, and at the end of the coverage period, participants bear the cost of losses from other members in the same risk pool. Most of the payment allocation methods in existing mutual aid platforms in China are equal payments, which means that members in the same pool with different risks share the same payout amount, which causes the problem of adverse selection.

Initially, consumers thought that network mutual aid was a kind of crowdfunding, because it was similar to the traditional mutual insurance in risk sharing, but the behavior of raising a large number of donations with small amount through Internet was similar to crowdfunding. Some mutual aid platforms also compare themselves with insurance products, which confuse customers with the differences between insurance products and mutual aid plans. But in practice, regulators deny the possibility that the network mutual aid plan belongs to mutual insurance on the ground of business qualification, and guide it to the direction of public welfare.

Su et al. [Reference Su, Xiong and Tang23] introduced various risks and problems faced by the network mutual aid platform, including adverse selection risk and operation risk. Hence, there is need for network mutual aid platforms to seek for reasonable pricing methods and payment allocation rules to reduce the risk faced by platforms and increase platform revenue.

1.2. P2P insurance and risk sharing

Friendsurance is a German company that launched P2P insurance in 2010, and since then it has been extended to many countries in the world. Compared with many network mutual aid platforms in China, P2P insurance mainly shares risks among a small group of people with social relations (such as friends and relatives). Part of the premium paid by the owner forms a mutual fund, and the other part is paid to a third-party insurance company. The loss of the claimant is first paid by the mutual fund, and the excess claim amount is compensated by the insurer. At the end of the coverage period, the surplus of the mutual fund is returned to participants or donated to a nonprofit organization designated by participants. Through technological innovation and unique product positioning, P2P insurance is more transparent. As the cost of acquiring customers is greatly reduced, the premium charged by P2P insurance is much lower than traditional insurance. Moenninghoff and Wieandt [Reference Moenninghoff and Wieandt20], World Bank Group [27] introduced the characteristics and development status of P2P insurance.

P2P is essentially a form of risk sharing, and its research can be traced back to Borch [Reference Borch6]. Denuit and Dhaene [Reference Denuit and Dhaene14] proposed a conditional average risk-sharing mechanism, which is based on the risk reduction characteristics of convex order to achieve Pareto optimality. Denuit [Reference Denuit12] obtained the expression of each participant's contribution to the pool under the known loss function by the size-biased transform under the conditional mean risk allocation rule. Asimit et al. [Reference Asimit, Boonen, Chi and Chong4] studied the optimal reinsurance contract design under different compensation environments. Based on Pareto optimality, it is concluded that the premium can be selected in a given interval and the buyer and seller should equally distribute the income of risk sharing. Abdikerimova and Feng [Reference Abdikerimova and Feng1] proposed a variety of P2P models for peers with different needs, so that they can exchange a variety of risks in a fair and transparent actuarial way. In addition, Abdikerimova et al. [Reference Abdikerimova, Boonen and Feng2] considered the P2P risk sharing in both the dynamic and the static settings. Domestic network mutual aid and foreign P2P insurance have strong reference significance in terms of sharing methods, pricing rules, and relative fairness.

1.3. Our contributions

The first contribution of this article is to analyze the participants’ behavioral decisions from multiple aspects. Based on the risk aversion degree of the participants, then decision-making model of the participants is constructed by applying utility function. By considering whether to join a mutual aid platform or to buy same type of insurance or not, it has been found that the choice not only affects the decision-making of the participants, but also has important impact on platform's pricing rules.

The other contribution is that the mutual aid platforms with different business concepts have been studies. The optimization problem is constructed from two aspects which are maximizing platform revenue and minimizing business risks. Under the condition of individual fairness and relative fairness between heterogeneous risks, a different loss sharing method is designed. Different from the conditional mean risk-sharing rule of Denuit [Reference Denuit13] and the risk exchange between different participants in Abdikerimova and Feng [Reference Abdikerimova and Feng1], these payment allocation methods are relatively complex, which may reduce the transparency of the mutual aid platform. Besides, the existing business model aggregates all losses and then distributes them equally to members. In this paper, we propose an alternative risk-sharing method which comes from the equal division scheme in Abdikerimova and Feng [Reference Abdikerimova and Feng1] but adopts equal allocation of the same type and proportional allocation for different types of members. The proposed method is relatively simple, reasonable, and can reduce adverse selection.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the decision-making methods of the participants in the mutual aid plan, the optimization goals of the platform and the payment allocation mode under fair conditions. Section 3 puts forward the sharing method based on fair conditions and the network mutual aid structure model under different choices. Section 4 gives the optimal solution to various problems and analyzes the sensitivity. Section 5 gives a numerical example and compares the difference between network mutual aid and medical insurance with a million-level coverage. Finally, conclusions are given in Section 6.

2. Mutual aid plans

Xueqiu [28] introduced some mutual aid products and sharing cases of the network mutual aid platform in China. The domestic network mutual aid platforms are mainly engaged in serious illness mutual aid and some of them are equipped with comprehensive accident mutual aid. There are two main business models. One is that a certain amount of funds are required to be paid in advance which are used to maintain the qualification of their membership and then to share mutual aid costs at the end of the coverage period. The other model has no need to pay the amount in advance, but both the mutual aid expenses and the management expenses are shared at the end of the coverage period. In order to ensure the transparency of mutual funds, the funds paid by members are managed by a third party. At the end of the publicity period, mutual aid amount and recipients are announced on the platform page, and mutual funds are distributed to the recipients. Most of the mutual aid coverage period is set to be half a month, at the end of the period, the participants need to pay the sharing fee within a specified time. In order to prevent moral hazard, the platform sets a waiting period ranging from 90 to 180 days. Members within the waiting period cannot apply for mutual aid even an accident occurs, but they still have to perform their sharing obligations. For simplicity, the study objects in this paper are mutual aid platforms and members who have finished waiting period.

2.1. Mutual aid platforms

In the mutual aid plan, the main function of the mutual aid platform is to provide certain management services when participants share risks. Sohu [22] introduced some revenue sources of network mutual aid platform. For the platform, the ways to generate profit are mainly from advertisement fees and by providing some additional services, such as medical value-added services and Internet financial services. Part of the mutual aid platform also set up an insurance mall, which makes profits by providing insurance products for members who are more risk-conscious. The management fee is only to meet the costs incurred in normal operations. There are two main ways for the platform to charge management fees.

  • Setting a fixed fee $\beta$. Mutual aid platform charges fixed management fees to participants every month. For example, E-mutual aid, quarkers.com, and some other platforms charge a fixed management fee of 1 yuan per month. The fee charged in this way is only related to the number of people in the mutual aid plan, but it is different from the insurance premium and is not used for claim reserve.

  • Setting the management rate $\alpha$. Mutual aid platform is free to join, and the management fee is charged according to the percentage of actual loss in each period of cost-sharing, such as Xianghubao and Waterdrop mutual aid.

Different from insurance products, the pricing of network mutual aid is mainly reflected in the setting of the management fee. Zhao and Zeng [Reference Zhao and Zeng30] mainly analyzes the pricing strategy of mutual aid platform under the goal of maximum revenue. But the government has not given a clear definition of network mutual aid at the present. The profitability of each network mutual aid platform is unknown, and the business strategies of each platform vary at different stages of development. Therefore, for different stages and different decision-making groups, the platform should select the different optimization objectives, respectively.

For platforms with a small number of members, the limited number of members makes the platform unable to operate sustainably. In Wen and Siqin [Reference Wen and Siqin26], risk-averse platform decision-makers choose to minimize operational risk as their optimization goal, rather than maximize revenue. This paper uses the mean-variance (MV) theory to simulate the risk aversion behavior of decision-makers. The MV theory was initially built for portfolio optimization, which is a standard method to explore the risk hedging problem. Wen and Siqin [Reference Wen and Siqin26] discussed the pricing of risk-averse airlines under the framework of the MV theory. Chiu et al. [Reference Chiu, Choi, Dai, Shen and Zheng9] analyzed the optimal allocation decision of advertising budget by the MV theory. Zhang et al. [Reference Zhang, Meng and Zeng29] analyzed the optimal investment and reinsurance strategies of insurance companies based on the MV premium principle. In order to ensure the platform's revenue and to reduce the operational risk, this paper develops a plan to achieve high revenue and low risk, so as to maximize the expected revenue and minimize the risk at the same time. Besides, in order to reduce the adverse selection problem and the overall loss risk of the mutual aid plan, we divide mutual aid members into different risk levels, and different types of members share different payout amounts. Let $v$ represents the revenue of the platform, then the optimization goal of minimizing platform risk is

$$\min(r\,{\rm Var}(v)-E(v)).$$

The parameter $r\ge 0$ indicates the degree of risk aversion of the platform, which increases with the increase of $r$. When $r=0$, it means that the platform is risk-seeking and only interested in maximizing the expected return. When choosing a finite $r$, it corresponds to a moderate risk aversion which has a balance between minimum variance and maximum expected return. Compared with $\max (E(v)-r\,{\rm Var}(v))$ which was selected in Wen and Siqin [Reference Wen and Siqin26] as the objective function, the optimization objective of this paper is more appropriate to the characteristics of mutual aid platform with unclear profitability and aimed at minimizing business risk.

For the mutual aid platform with relatively stable participants, due to its sufficient member size and stable sharing amount, the goal of the platform gradually turns to maximize revenue, that is, $\max E(v)$.

By comparing various data of existing mutual aid platforms, we found that as the number of platform members gradually stabilized, the monthly share of cost for members is also gradually increasing. And the same type of insurance products, which are the main competitors of network mutual aid, naturally become the participants’ alternatives. Therefore, for mutual aid platforms with maximize revenue as its goal, this paper considers the impact of insurance products on platform pricing rules additionally.

2.2. Participant

This paper uses the utility function to measure people's satisfaction from a given portfolio, and an individual's behavior depends on his or her attitude to risk. It is assumed that all individuals who consider whether to join the mutual aid plan are risk-averse, that is, the risk aversion coefficient of participants $\xi$ is set to be great than zero $\xi > 0$. Suppose that an individual has a utility function $u(y)$, the initial wealth is $w$, the probability of loss is $p$, and the amount of loss is $B$. The utility function $u(y)$ of risk aversion is an increasing concave function, that is, $u^{\prime }(y)>0$, $u^{\prime \prime }(y)<0$.

Then, we consider the situation where individuals choose to join a mutual aid plan. In order to distinguish, we refer to individuals who may be joining the network mutual aid plan as participants and those who have joined the mutual aid plan as members. Assuming that there are $N$ types of members in a mutual aid plan, the probability of loss for $i^{\rm th}$ type members is $p_i$, and the amount of loss which is also the amount of compensation denotes as $B_i$ (assuming that all losses incurred are compensated), where $i\in \mathcal {N}=\{1,2,\ldots,N\}$. The platform can charge members with additional management fees to maintain operation. Assuming that the management fees for all members within the same type are the same, and the management fees for different types of members are different, then the fixed fee for the $i^{\rm th}$ type members is $\beta _i$, and the management fee rate is $\alpha _i$. We name members who have losses in the coverage period as recipients, and members who have no losses as helpers. Then, at the end of each coverage period, helpers share the mutual aid fund of recipients and pay a certain management fee, recipients collect the mutual aid fund without paying other fees.

Let $I_{ij}$ represents the indicator function of loss for $j^{\rm th}$ participants in $i^{\rm th}$ type member, such that

$${I}_{ij}=\begin{cases} 0, & w.p. \ 1-p_i,\\ 1, & w.p. \ p_i. \end{cases}$$

It is assumed that all members of the same type are independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.). Based on this, we assume that the initial wealth of $j^{\rm th}$ member from $i^{\rm th}$ type is $w^{0}_{i,j}$, the wealth of member $j$ in $i^{\rm th}$ type at the end of the coverage period is $w^{1}_{i,j}$ , hence

$$w^{1}_{i,j}=w^{0}_{i,j}-(1-{I}_{ij})(\beta_i+s_{ij}(1+\alpha_i)),$$

where $s_{ij}$ is the expected payout cost of $j^{\rm th}$ member in $i^{\rm th}$ type, which is the average of actual payout. For $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$, we consider the utility of $i^{\rm th}$ type member in three cases,

  1. 1. The expected utility of choosing not to purchase any guarantee product is

    (2.1)\begin{equation} Eu_{i,1}=E[u(w^{1}_{i,j})] = (1-p_i)u(w^{0}_{i,j})+p_iu(w^{0}_{i,j}-B_i). \end{equation}
  2. 2. The expected utility of choosing to join the mutual aid plan is

    (2.2)\begin{equation} Eu_{i,2}= (1-p_i)u(w^{0}_{i,j}-\beta_i-s_{ij}(1+\alpha_i))+p_iu(w^{0}_{i,j}). \end{equation}
  3. 3. The expected utility of choosing to buy insurance is

    (2.3)\begin{equation} Eu_{i,3}= u(w^{0}_{i,j}-\pi_i), \end{equation}

where $\pi _i$ is the premium of term full insurance, and the insured amount is equal to the mutual aid fund. According to the principle of maximum expected utility, individuals make decisions by maximizing expected utility.

$$\max_{\psi_i\in\{1,2,3\}}{E(u_{i,\psi_i})},\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N},$$

where $\psi _i\in \{1,2,3\}$ denotes above three different decisions for $i^{\rm th}$ type members. In other words, based on the management fee and the expected payout amount, the member's expected utility of joining the mutual aid plan is greater than not joining and buying insurance.

2.3. Fair exchange of heterogeneous risks

The premium of traditional insurance is based on the theory of law of large numbers. For a large enough pool of policyholders with independent and identically distributed losses, based on the equivalence principle, the net premium is set to be equal to the expected claim amount. However, most of the insurance products are set up for homogeneous risk. For example, accident insurance compensates for the loss caused by accidents, term life insurance compensates for the death pension when the insured dies. These kinds of insurance go through risk assessment, rate making, and other processes, so that the benefits and expected losses brought by homogeneous risks offset each other.

Network mutual aid platforms in China lack rigid guarantee commitment. Members have the benefit of mutual aid guarantee but also bear the responsibility similar to traditional insurance insurers (share the amount of mutual aid of other “Insured”). However, most mutual aid platforms put members with different risks in the same risk pool. Although platforms divide members into different types by age, members with different ages only have the difference of mutual aid fund, and the actual amount of payment allocation is usually the same. For example, the standard version of mutual aid for Xianghubao divides members into two age groups: 0–39 years old and 40–59 years old, and the mutual aid amount is 300,000 and 100,000 RMB, respectively. At the end of the coverage period, each person's share is calculated as

$$\frac{\text{total amount of mutual aid fund} \times(1+ 8\%)}{\text{number of members of mutual aid}},$$

where $8\%$ is the existing management fee for Xianghubao platform. This kind of sharing method leads participants with high risk to gain more than the participants with low risk. In other words, it is subsidizing high-risk members through low-risk members. This risk heterogeneity will lead to serious adverse selection problems. High-risk participants are more willing to join the mutual aid plan, the overall risk of the mutual aid pool increases, and the actual allocation payment amount increases. Low-risk members are more likely to quit the mutual aid plan. In the end, only high-risk members remain in the mutual aid plan.

Recently, Shapley value method, $\tau$ value method, conditional mean risk sharing, and so on are the common ways of cost allocation. These cost allocation methods meet the actuarial conditions but are relatively complex. This paper chooses a simple and fair allocation method, which is more likely to be accepted by consumers for mutual aid platforms.

Assa and Boonen [Reference Assa and Boonen5] study different risk management settings and effective insurance plans under macroeconomic risks. In the risk-sharing platform, assuming that insurance treats all policyholders equally, so that their ultimate wealth is equally distributed, and the risks among policyholders are independent and identically distributed, then it is the best way for everyone to equally share all risks in the market excellent. For members of same type, the method of sharing equally among members of same type is adopted because they facing same risk. $s_i$ is used to indicate the expected apportionment amount borne by helper in the $i^{\rm th}$ type members, so that

$$s_{i1}=s_{i2}=\cdots=s_i,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}.$$

Then, income and expenses for each member is considered. Suppose that the number of $i^{\rm th}$ type members is $n_i$. For $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$,$j\in n_i$, we use $R_{ij}^{\ast }$ to denote the net income of member $j$ in the $i^{\rm th}$ type and without taking the management fee into consideration, hence

$$R_{ij}^{{\ast}}=I_{ij}B_i-(1-I_{ij})s_i.$$

In order to meet the condition of individual fairness, that is, the expected value of member's income should be equal to the expected value of cost, and the expected net income should be 0, that is

$$E(R_{ij}^{{\ast}})=p_iB_i-(1-p_i)s_i=0.$$

Then, the expected payout amount $s_i$ of helper in $i^{\rm th}$ type members is

$$s_i=\frac{p_iB_i}{1-p_i},\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}.$$

In this way, the expected total allocation of all mutual aid persons on the platform is $\sum _{i=1}^{N}{n_is_i(1-p_i)}$, the total risk of platform members is $\sum _{i=1}^{N}{n_iI_iB_i}$, which can be seen from the following equation:

$$E\left(\sum_{i=1}^{N}{n_iI_iB_i}\right)=\sum_{i=1}^{N}{n_is_i(1-p_i)},\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}.$$

This way of sharing enables the helpers to share the risks of all members.

For different types of members, because of different risks they facing, their apportioned amounts should also be different. This paper adopts the method that all kinds of helpers sharing the total loss according to a certain weight. Then, the loss to be shared by all $i^{\rm th}$ type helpers is

(2.4)\begin{equation} n_i(1-p_i)s_i=\theta_i\sum_{i=1}^{N}{n_ip_iB_i},\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{equation}

where $\sum _{i=1}^{N}{n_ip_iB_i}$ represents the expected total loss of the mutual aid plan, and $\theta _i$ is the proportion of the total loss shared by $i^{\rm th}$ type helpers. The two sides of Eq. (2.4) represent the amount expected to be allocated by the $i^{\rm th}$ type helpers. From (2.4), we can get

$$\theta_i=\frac{n_ip_iB_i}{\sum_{i=1}^{N}{n_ip_iB_i}},\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}.$$

This kind of apportionment method can allocate all losses, that is, $\sum _{i=1}^{N}\theta _i=1$.

Regarding the fairness between different types of members, this paper adapts the relative fairness conditions as proposed in Chen et al. [Reference Chen, Feng, Wei and Zhao8]. Let $R_{ij}$ represents the net cash flow of member $j$ in the $i^{\rm th}$ type, so that

$$R_{ij}=I_{ij}B_i-(1-I_{ij})(\beta_i+s_i(1+\alpha_i)),\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N},\ j\in n_i.$$

The first term on the right side of the above equation represents the income of member $j$ in the $i^{\rm th}$ type and the second term is its expenditure. It can be seen that $R_{ij}$ is an additional platform management fee based on $R_{ij}^{\ast }$. Chen et al. [Reference Chen, Feng, Wei and Zhao8] mentioned that when $E(R_{ij})=E(R_{kl})$, it is fair to different types of members, that is,

$$(1-p_i)\beta_i+{p_iB_i\alpha}_i=(1-p_k)\beta_k+{p_kB_k\alpha}_k,\quad \forall i,k\in\mathcal{N},$$

where $R_{kl}$ represents the net cash flow of member $l$ in the $k^{\rm th}$ type, $\forall l\in n_k$. From above equation, we can see that the expected income that platform obtains from each member are the same.

3. Modeling framework

3.1. Decisions excluding insurance

Two types of mutual aid platforms with different optimization goals are considered in this paper. Suppose the target number of $i^{\rm th}$ type members is $m_i$, where $i\in \mathcal {N}$. For a member of type $i$, define the cumulative distribution of the risk aversion coefficient $\xi _i$ as $F_i$. Assuming that for $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$, $F_i(\xi _i)$ is continuously differentiable, and $\xi _i\in [0,{\bar {\xi }}_i]$ strictly increases with respect to $F_i(\xi _i)$. ${\bar {\xi }}_i$ is the upper limit of the $i^{\rm th}$ type member's risk aversion coefficient. Under this assumption, the distribution function $F_i$ is reversible. Let $F_i^{-1}$ be the corresponding inverse function, then for $\xi _i\in [0,{\bar {\xi }}_i]$, we have $F_i^{-1}(F_i(\xi _i))=\xi _i$. In Cohen and Einav [Reference Cohen and Einav10] and Halek and Eisenhauer [Reference Halek and Eisenhauer18], they used survey data to estimate people's risk aversion. This paper studies a more general form of $F_i$ and specific distribution functions are used in numerical examples.

For mutual aid platform, the initial number of platform members have not yet stabilized. Due to the effect of waiting period, the actual payment allocation amount paid by members are smaller than that of traditional insurance, and the utility obtained exceeds the utility given by traditional insurance. So here we assume that members only consider whether to join the mutual aid platform and not consider purchasing insurance. Then, the condition for individuals to choose to join the mutual aid plan is

(3.1)\begin{equation} Eu_{i,2}>Eu_{i,1},\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{equation}

We then adapt Taylor series’ expansion on utility function of personal initial wealth to estimate personal risk aversion. This method is also used in Thomas [Reference Thomas24], Hassett et al. [Reference Hassett, Sears and Trennepohl19], Eeckhoudt and Laeven [Reference Eeckhoudt and Laeven16], Corner [Reference Corner11], and Viscusi and Evans [Reference Viscusi and Evans25]. Its advantage is that it does not need to formulate the form of the utility function, but there may be a certain error in approximating the original utility function as a quadratic expression.

This paper intends to compare the expected utility functions for decision-making, rather than approximating the expected utility of various situations based on the Taylor expansion method. We adopt this Taylor series approximation constrains from Thomas [Reference Thomas24] that are both $w^{0}_{i,j}\gg B_i$ and $w^{0}_{i,j}\gg \beta _i+s_{ij}(1+\alpha _i)$ to make sure second-order Taylor expansion is good approximation. The assumptions represent that the initial wealth is much greater than potential loss. Because of these conditions, $(w^{0}_{i,j})-B_i$ and $(w^{0}_{i,j})-\beta _i+s_ij (1+\alpha _i)$ are in a sufficiently small neighborhood of $(w^{0}_{i,j})$. Some numerical examples are given in Appendix to show that the second-order Taylor expansion is a good approximation for decision making under an individual's expected utility function in this study.

Assuming that both $w^{0}_{i,j}\gg B_i$ and $w^{0}_{i,j}\gg \beta _i+s_{ij}(1+\alpha _i)$, the utility terms on the right-hand side of Eqs. (2.1) and (2.2) may be expanded using the first three terms of a Taylor series,

(3.2)\begin{align} & u(w^{0}_{i,j}-B_i)\approx u(w^{0}_{i,j})-B_iu^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})+\frac{1}{2}B_i^{2}u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j}).\\ & u(w^{0}_{i,j}-\beta_i-s_{ij}(1+\alpha_i))=u\left(w^{0}_{i,j}-\frac{x+p_iB_i}{1-p_i}\right)\nonumber\\ \end{align}
(3.3)\begin{align} & \quad \approx u(w^{0}_{i,j})-\frac{x+p_iB_i}{1-p_i}u^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j}) +\frac{1}{2}{\left(\frac{x+p_iB_i}{1-p_i}\right)}^{2}u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j}), \end{align}

where $x=(1-p_i)\beta _i+p_i B_i \alpha _i$ to simplify expressions. Then,

(3.4)\begin{align} Eu_{i,1}& \approx u(w^{0}_{i,j})-p_iB_iu^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})+\frac{1}{2}p_iB_i^{2}u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j}), \end{align}
(3.5)\begin{align} Eu_{i,2}& \approx u(w^{0}_{i,j})-(x+p_iB_i)u^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})+\frac{1}{2}\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j}). \end{align}

From the decision condition (3.1), we get

$$\left[\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}-p_iB_i^{2}\right]u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})>2xu^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j}).$$

According to the definition of absolute risk aversion coefficient,

$$\xi_i={-}\frac{u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})}{u^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})}.$$

Therefore, when the risk aversion coefficient of participants meets the following two conditions, they will choose to join the mutual aid plan:

  1. 1. when $0< x< B_i[\sqrt {p_i(1-p_i)}-p_i]$,

    (3.6)\begin{equation} -\frac{u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})}{u^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})} >\frac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}=\xi_i^{{\ast}}. \end{equation}
  2. 2. when $x>B_i[\sqrt {p_i(1-p_i)}-p_i],$

    $$-\frac{u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})}{u^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})} <\frac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}<0.$$

$\xi _i^{\ast }$ is the minimum value of the risk aversion coefficient of participants who choose to join the platform. Only those participants whose risk aversion coefficient exceeds $\xi _i^{\ast }$ join the mutual aid program, and the target groups in this paper are risk-averse, so the second case is not considered. As a result, the probability of a participant joining the mutual aid platform is $P(\xi _i>\xi _i^{\ast })$. The final number of $i^{\rm th}$ type participants who choose to join the mutual aid plan $n_i$ is

(3.7)\begin{align} n_i& =m_i\times P(\xi_i>\xi_i^{{\ast}})\nonumber\\ & = m_i\left(1-F_i \left(\frac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right)\right),\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{align}

Denote $v_i$ as the platform's income from $i^{\rm th}$ type members, $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$. The platform's revenue comes from management fees paid by helpers. Therefore,

$$v_i=\sum_{j=1}^{n_i}{(1-I_{ij})(s_i\alpha_i+\beta_i)}.$$

Then, the expectation and variance of the platform's income from $i^{\rm th}$ type members are

(3.8)\begin{equation} E(v_i)=n_ix, \end{equation}

and

(3.9)\begin{equation} {\rm Var}(v_i)=n_i{(s_i\alpha_i+\beta_i)}^{2}p_i(1-p_i)=\frac{n_i{p_ix}^{2}}{1-p_i}. \end{equation}

Setting $(\alpha,\beta )$ to be the vector of management fee and fixed cost of the platform, where $\alpha =(\alpha _1,\ldots,\alpha _N)\in \mathbb {R}^{|N|}$, $\beta =(\beta _1,\ldots,\beta _N)\in \mathbb {R}^{|N|}$. Total revenue of the platform $v={\sum _{i=1}^{N}{v_i}}$. When participants do not consider purchasing insurance, the risk minimization model of the platform (Model 1) is

(3.10)\begin{align} \min_{\{\alpha,\beta\}} & [r\,{\rm var}(v)-E(v)], \end{align}
(3.11)\begin{align} {\rm s.t.}\quad & n_i=m_i\left[1-F_i\left(\frac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right)\right], \quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}
(3.12)\begin{align} & x=(1-p_i)\beta_i+{p_iB_i\alpha}_i \ge 0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}
(3.13)\begin{align} & 0\le n_i\le m_i,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}
(3.14)\begin{align} & \alpha_i\geq 0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}
(3.15)\begin{align} & \beta_i\geq 0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{align}

In Model 1, constraint (3.11) comes from the condition of relative fairness. Constraint (3.12) guarantees $n_i$ is a feasible solution, constraint (3.13), (3.14) to ensure that $(\alpha,\beta )$ is a feasible management rate and fixed cost. The platform influences the number of people who join the mutual aid plan by selecting appropriate management fees and fixed fees, so as to minimize operating risks.

In the same way, the platform with maximize its revenue as optimization object (Model 2) can be expressed as

(3.16)\begin{align} \max_{\{\alpha,\beta\}}& E(v). \end{align}
(3.17)\begin{align} {\rm s.t.}\quad & n_i=m_i\left[1-F_i\left(\frac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right)\right],\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}
(3.18)\begin{align} & x=(1-p_i)\beta_i+{p_iB_i\alpha}_i \ge 0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}
(3.19)\begin{align} & 0\le n_i\le m_i,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}
(3.20)\begin{align} & \alpha_i\geq 0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}
(3.21)\begin{align} & \beta_i\geq 0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{align}

3.2. Decisions including insurance

In Section 3.1, participants’ decisions of whether join the mutual aid plan are based on the principle of maximum expected utility. As the actual cost-sharing is relatively small, participants only need to consider whether to join a mutual aid plan. However, this assumption is not comprehensive enough. In recent years, some low-priced, competitive insurance products have also appeared, such as medical insurance with a million-level coverage and city universal commercial health insurance. Based on Section 3.1, this section assumes that participants also consider whether to purchase insurance with the same sum insured amount as mutual aid and without a deductible.

For the $i^{\rm th}$ type participant, $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$, the condition for an individual to choose to join a mutual aid plan instead of buying insurance is

$$Eu_{i,2}>Eu_{i,3},$$

that is, the utility of joining a mutual aid plan exceeds the utility of buying insurance. Under different premiums, the minimum value of the member's risk aversion coefficient ${\widetilde {\xi }}_i^{\ast }$ is

  1. 1. when $0< x<\pi _i\sqrt {1-p_i}-p_iB_i$,

    (3.22)\begin{equation} -\frac{u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})}{u^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})} >\frac{2(x+p_iB_i-\pi_i)}{{\pi_i}^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}={\widetilde{\xi}}_i^{{\ast}}. \end{equation}
  2. 2. when $\pi _i\sqrt {1-p_i}-p_iB_i< x,$

    (3.23)\begin{equation} -\frac{u^{\prime\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})}{u^{\prime}(w^{0}_{i,j})} <\frac{2(x+p_iB_i-\pi_i)}{{\pi_i}^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}={\widetilde{\xi}}_i^{{\ast}}. \end{equation}
  3. 3. when $x=\pi _i\sqrt {1-p_i}-p_iB_i$, $Eu_{i,2}>Eu_{i,3}$ established.

When the platform's expected return $x$ is relatively small, only the participants’ risk aversion level needs to be considered. Excessive fees cause participants to switch to insurance. Figure 1 shows the value range of the risk aversion coefficient of $i^{\rm th}$ type members under different decision-making conditions. When considering whether to join a mutual aid program, the participant's risk aversion coefficient must be above the orange solid line. When considering whether to join a mutual aid plan or purchase insurance, the expected return $x$ affects the threshold of the member's risk aversion coefficient. When $x< x_1$, the member's risk aversion coefficient should be below the blue solid line; when $x>x_1$, the member's risk aversion coefficient should be above the blue realization, where $x_1=\pi _i\sqrt {1-p_i}-p_iB_i$. Combining the two types of decision-making, only participants whose risk aversion coefficient is in the shadow zone choose to join the mutual aid platform.

Figure 1. Risk aversion coefficient $\xi _i$ and platform expected return $x$.

According to Figure 1 and combining equations (3.6), (3.17), and (3.18), it can be seen that in different situations, for $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$,the final numbers of $i^{\rm th}$ type participants who choose to join the mutual aid plan are

  1. 1. when $0< x\le \pi _i\sqrt {1-p_i}-p_iB_i$,

    $$n_i=m_i\left[1-F_i\left(\frac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right)\right].$$
  2. 2. when $\pi _i\sqrt {1-p_i}-p_iB_i< x\le (p_iB_i^{2}(1-2p_i)+z_i^{2})^{\frac{1}{2}}-z_i$,

    $$n_i=m_i\left[F_i\left(\frac{2(x+p_iB_i-\pi_i)}{{\pi_i}^{2}-\frac{{(x+p_iB_i)}^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right) -F_i\left(\frac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right)\right].$$
    where $z_i=p_iB_i+{((p_iB_i^{2}-{\pi _i}^{2})(1-p_i))}/{2(\pi _i-p_iB_i)}$.
  3. 3. when $x>p_iB_i^{2}(1-2p_i)+z_i^{2})^{1/2}-z_i$,

    $$n_i=0.$$

It can be found that the number of participants in the second case is the ones in the former case minus the number of people who buys insurance due to excessive cost-sharing. Then, when participants consider purchasing insurance, the number of participants in the platform's risk minimization model (Model 3) is

(3.24)\begin{equation} n_i=\begin{cases} m_i\left[1-F_i\left(\dfrac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right)\right], \quad 0< x\le \pi_i\sqrt{1-p_i}-p_iB_i,\\ 0, \quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad\quad x>(p_iB_i^{2}(1-2p_i)+z_i^{2})^{1/2}-z_i,\\ m_i\left[F_i\left(\dfrac{2\left(x+p_iB_i-\pi_i\right)}{{\pi_i}^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right) -F_i\left(\dfrac{2x}{p_iB_i^{2}-\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}}\right)\right], \quad \text{otherwise}, \end{cases}\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{equation}

The rest of constraints are the same as Model 1.

Based on relatively fair conditions, the expected revenue $x$ of the platform is the same for different types of members. However, since premiums and loss probabilities for different types of members are different, when a certain type of member's platform expected revenue $x$ is in the range $(\pi _i\sqrt {1-p_i}-p_iB_i,(p_iB_i^{2}(1-2p_i)+z_i^{2})^{1/2}-z_i]$, $x$ of the remaining members are in other ranges. When the expected return $x$ of the platform is within the premium range of high-risk groups $(\pi _i\sqrt {1-p_i}-p_iB_i,+\infty )$, the utility of the mutual aid plan for low-risk groups is lower than the insurance utility. In other words, an excessively high platform expected return leads to withdrawal of low-risk groups.

Similarly, the platform revenue maximization model considering that participants may purchase insurance (Model 4) is to adjust the number of participants to formula (3.19) based on Model 2, and other constraints remain unchange.

4. Finding the optimal solutions

In this section, we first find the optimal solutions of Model 1 and Model 2. Then, the numerical method is applied to find optimal solutions for Model 3 and Model 4. Finally, the network structure of the mutual aid plan is analyzed by studying the relationship between variables.

4.1. The analytic solutions of Model 1 and Model 2

In this section, the optimal solutions of Model 1 and Model 2 are found by implementing the KKT condition, that is, the optimal fixed cost and management rate of the mutual aid platform are obtained. In order to facilitate the calculation, $n_i$ is considered as a decision variable and bring (3.8) and (3.9) into (3.10) to get the optimization objective as

$$\min_x{\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{N}{\left(\frac{rn_ip_ix^{2}}{1-p_i}-n_ix\right),}}$$

with the corresponding Lagrange function $\mathcal {L}$ as

(4.1)\begin{align} \mathcal{L}(x,n,\lambda,\mu)& =\sum_{i=1}^{N}\lambda_i\left[F_i^{{-}1}\left(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i}\right) \left(\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}-p_iB_i^{2}\right)+2x\right] \nonumber\\ & \quad +\sum_{i=1}^{N}{\left(\frac{rn_ix^{2}p_i}{1-p_i}-n_ix\right)+}\sum_{i=1}^{N}{\mu_{1i}(m_i-n_i)}+\sum_{i=1}^{N}{\mu_{2i}n_i}+\mu_3x, \end{align}

where $\mu$ and $\lambda$ are Lagrange multipliers with $\mu =(\mu _{11},\ldots,\mu _{1N},\mu _{21},\ldots,\mu _{2N},\mu _3)$ and $\lambda =(\lambda _1,\ldots,\lambda _N)$. According to the stationary condition, we take the derivatives of $\mathcal {L}$ with respect to $x$ and $n_i$, respectively. Then, we have

(4.2)\begin{equation} \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial x}=\sum_{i=1}^{N}\left[\frac{2rxn_ip_i}{1-p_i}-n_i +2\lambda_i\left(1+F_i^{{-}1}\left(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i}\right)\left(\frac{x+p_iB_i}{1-p_i}\right)\right)\right]+ \mu_3=0, \end{equation}

and

(4.3)\begin{align} \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial n_i}& =\frac{rx^{2}p_i}{1-p_i}-x+\lambda_i\left[F_i^{{-}1}\left(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i}\right)\right]^{\prime} \left(\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}-p_iB_i^{2}\right)\nonumber\\ & \quad - \mu_{1i}+\mu_{2i}=0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{align}

According to equality constraints, taking the derivative of $\mathcal {L}$ with respect to $\lambda _i$ gives

(4.4)\begin{equation} \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial\lambda_i} =F_i^{{-}1}\left(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i}\right)\left(\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}-p_iB_i^{2}\right)+2x=0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{equation}

From the complimentary slackness conditions, it gives

(4.5)\begin{equation} \mu_{1i}(m_i-n_i)=0,\quad \mu_{2i}n_i=0,\quad \mu_3x=0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{equation}

and

(4.6)\begin{equation} \mu_{1i}\geq 0,\quad \mu_{2i}\geq 0,\quad \text{and}\quad \mu_{3i}\geq 0,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{equation}

Suppose $0< n_i< m_i$ and $x\neq 0$, that $\mu _{1i}=\mu _{2i}=\mu _3=0$. From Eq. (4.4), it can be concluded that:

(4.7)\begin{align} x& ={\left[(1-p_i)(p_iB_i^{2}+\frac{2p_iB_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i})} +\frac{1-p_i}{{(F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i}))}^{2}})\right]}^{1/2}\nonumber\\ & \quad -\frac{1-p_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i})}-p_iB_i, \end{align}

By taking Eq. (4.7) into Eqs. (4.2) and (4.3), we obtain

(4.8)\begin{align} & \sum_{i=1}^{N}{\left(\frac{rp_i(g_i-p_iB_i)}{1-p_i} -\frac{rp_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i})}-1\right) \frac{g_i\left[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i})\right]^{2}}{(1-p_i)[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i})]^{\prime}}}\nonumber\\ & \quad +\sum_{i=1}^{N}\left(\frac{2rn_ip_i(g_i-p_iB_i)}{1-p_i} -\frac{2rp_in_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i})}-n_i\right)=0, \end{align}

where

$$g_i=\left[(1-p_i)\left(p_iB_i^{2}+\frac{2p_iB_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i})} +\frac{1-p_i}{[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i})]^{2}}\right)\right]^{1/2}.$$

Note that, $n_i=0$ or $n_i=m_i$ are not solutions to Model 1. Thus, the assumption $0< n_i< m_i$ holds. This can also be seen from practice as it is impossible for everyone to be willing to join the mutual aid plan nor if no one joins the mutual aid plan, the platform cannot operate.

Using the same method, the optimal solution of Model 2 can be obtained, and Theorems 4.1 and 4.2 then can be obtained.

Theorem 4.1. Suppose $(\alpha ^{a},\beta ^{a})$ is the optimal solution of minimizing platform risk Model 1, $n_i^{a}$ is the stable number given $(\alpha ^{a},\beta ^{a})$. In the case of heterogeneous risk fair exchange, $n_i^{a}$ is determined by solving the following equation:

(4.9)\begin{align} & \sum_{i=1}^{N}{\left(\frac{rp_i(g_i^{a}-p_iB_i)}{1-p_i}-\frac{rp_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{a}}{m_i})}-1\right) \frac{g_i^{a}[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{a}}{m_i})]^{2}}{(1-p_i)[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{a}}{m_i})]^{\prime}}}\nonumber\\ & \quad +\sum_{i=1}^{N}\left(\frac{2rn_i^{a}p_i(g_i^{a}-p_iB_i)}{1-p_i} -\frac{2rp_in_i^{a}}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{a}}{m_i})}-n_i^{a}\right)=0. \end{align}

The optimal fixed cost and management rate of Model 1 are not unique, and the relationship is as follows:

(4.10)\begin{equation} (1-p_i)\beta_i^{a}+p_iB_i\alpha_i^{a}=g_i^{a}-\frac{1-p_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{a}}{m_i})}-p_iB_i,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{equation}

with

$$g_i^{a}=\left[(1-p_i)\left(p_iB_i^{2}+\frac{2p_iB_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{a}}{m_i})} +\frac{1-p_i}{(F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{a}}{m_i}))^{2}}\right)\right]^{1/2}.$$

Theorem 4.2. Suppose $(\alpha ^{b},\beta ^{b})$ is the optimal solution of maximizing platform revenue Model 2, $n_i^{b}$ is the stable number given $(\alpha ^{b},\beta ^{b})$. In the case of heterogeneous risk fair exchange, $n_i^{b}$ is determined by solving the following equation:

(4.11)\begin{equation} \sum_{i=1}^{N}\left(n_i^{b}+\frac{g_i^{b}{[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{b}}{m_i})]}^{2}} {(1-p_i){[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{b}}{m_i})]}^{\prime}}\right)=0. \end{equation}

The optimal fixed fee and management fee rate of Model 2 are also not unique, the relationship is as follows:

(4.12)\begin{equation} (1-p_i)\beta_i^{b}+p_iB_i\alpha_i^{b}=g_i^{b}-\frac{1-p_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{b}}{m_i})}-p_iB_i,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{equation}

where

$$g_i^{b}=\left[(1-p_i)\left(p_iB_i^{2}+\frac{2p_iB_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{b}}{m_i})} +\frac{1-p_i}{[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{b}}{m_i})]^{2}}\right)\right]^{1/2}.$$

From Theorems 4.1 and 4.2, we find that the relationship between optimal fixed fee and management rate are the same under different optimization objectives. The reason is that the decision objects of the participants are the same, and they only consider whether to join the platform. But the actual apportionment value can be unequal because that the number of participants is different from time to time. This paper determines the optimal fixed fee and management rate by selecting the best participant group under the optimization goal. There are many kinds of optimal fixed fees and management fee rates on the platform, but in reality, most mutual aid platforms only charge a fixed fee or only set a management rate. Participants may prefer an uncomplicated charging method. Hence, we have the following corollary from Theorems 4.1 and 4.2.

Corollary 4.1. A simpler example of the optimal solution of Models 1 and 2 is as follows, $(\alpha ^{\ast },\beta ^{\ast })$ is the optimal solution under the optimization objective, $n_i^{\ast }$ is given $(\alpha ^{\ast },\beta ^{\ast })$ stable number of people. For $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$,

  • Setting $\alpha _i^{\ast }=0$, then

    $$\beta_i^{{\ast}}=\displaystyle\frac{g_i^{{\ast}}}{1-p_i}-\frac{1}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{{\ast}}}{m_i})} -\frac{p_iB_i}{(1-p_i)},\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}.$$
  • Setting $\beta _i^{\ast }=0$, then

    $$\alpha_i^{{\ast}}=\frac{1}{p_iB_i}\left(g_i^{{\ast}}-\frac{1-p_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{{\ast}}}{m_i})}\right)-1, \quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}.$$

Among them,

$$g_i^{{\ast}}=\left[(1-p_i)\left(p_iB_i^{2}+\displaystyle\frac{2p_iB_i}{F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{{\ast}}}{m_i})} +\frac{1-p_i}{[F_i^{{-}1}(1-\frac{n_i^{{\ast}}}{m_i})]^{2}}\right)\right]^{1/2}.$$

In Cohen and Einav et al. [Reference Cohen and Einav10], the risk aversion coefficient is estimated to be a logarithmic normal distribution. The simulation experiment of Andersen et al. [Reference Andersen, Harrison, Lau and Rutström3] obtained a skewed distribution with a thick right tail. Based on this, this paper selects the lognormal distribution function and the Pareto distribution function as the distribution function of the risk aversion coefficient. Then, in the case of determining the number of $i^{\rm th}$ type participants $n_i^{\ast }$, the optimal solution expressions under different distribution functions are given.

When $\xi _i$ follows the lognormal distribution with parameters $(u_i,\sigma _i)$, the relationship between the optimal fixed cost and the management rate is

(4.13)\begin{align} (1-p_i)\beta_i^{{\ast}}+p_iB_i\alpha_i^{{\ast}} & =\left[(1-p_i)\left(p_i{B_i}^{2}+\frac{2p_iB_i}{y_i^{{\ast}}}+\frac{1-p_i}{{y_i^{{\ast}}}^{2}}\right)\right]^{1/2}\nonumber\\ & \quad - \frac{1-p_i}{y_i^{{\ast}}}-p_iB_i,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{align}

where $y_i^{\ast }=\exp [\sigma _i\Phi _i^{-1}(1-{n_i^{\ast }}/{m_i})+u_i]$ and $\Phi _i^{-1}(\cdot )$ is the inverse function of the standard normal distribution function.

When $F_i=1-{({\vartheta _i}/{(x+\vartheta _i)})}^{a_i}$, $\xi _i$ obeys the Pareto distribution with parameters $(a_i,\vartheta _i)$, then the relationship between the optimal fixed cost and management rate is

(4.14)\begin{align} (1-p_i)\beta_i^{{\ast}}+p_iB_i\alpha_i^{{\ast}}& =\left[(1-p_i)\left(p_i{B_i}^{2}+\frac{2p_iB_i}{h_i^{{\ast}}} +\frac{1-p_i}{{h_i^{{\ast}}}^{2}}\right)\right]^{1/2}\nonumber\\ & \quad - \frac{1-p_i}{h_i^{{\ast}}}-p_iB_i,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}. \end{align}

where $h_i^{\ast }=\vartheta _i({m_i^{1/a_i}}/{n_i^{\ast }}^{{1}/{a_i}}-1)$.

To compare the influence of the distribution function of different risk aversion coefficients on the final result, we consider a simple mutual aid example, in which the mutual aid platform divides the participants into three types. Suppose $m=(2,5,3)$, $p=(0.0004,0.0015,0.009)$, $r=20$, $B=(50{,}000,30{,}000,10{,}000)$. For $\forall i\in \{1,2,3\}$, we use $\varphi _i=n_i^{\ast }/m_i$ to represent the proportion of the number of people joining the $i$-type member. It is assumed that different types of participants obey the same distribution function with the same parameters, and for the convenience of comparison, the mean and variance of the two distribution functions are the same, with the mean value of 0.002 and the standard deviation of 0.02. Tables 1 and 2 respectively show the optimal solutions for minimizing platform risk under different distribution functions.

Table 1. The optimal solution of Model 1 under the lognormal distribution function.

Table 2. The optimal solution of Model 1 under the Pareto distribution function.

It can be seen from Tables 1 and 2 that the optimal number of participants $n_i^{\ast }$, the optimal management rate $\alpha _i^{\ast }$, and the optimal fixed cost ${\beta _i}^{\ast }$ of Model 1 under the Pareto function are greater than the optimal solution under the lognormal distribution function, but the overall difference is not significant. This shows that the selection of different distribution functions has a certain impact on the final results of the model, which is related to the nature of the function itself.

4.2. Numerical solution of Model 3 and Model 4

In this section, we give numerical optimization results with minimize the platform risk and maximize the platform revenue when taking insurance product into consideration, respectively. The parameter values used in the numerical calculation are shown in Table 3. The premium is set in the form of pure premium plus additional premium,

(4.15)\begin{equation} \pi_i=(1+\rho)p_iB_i,\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}, \end{equation}

where $\rho$ is the surcharge rate, here we assume that the surcharge rate of all types of insurance is the same.

Table 3. Parameter value.

We calculate the number of participants of various agents and the expected revenue of the platform in an iterative manner. Table 4 shows the optimal mutual aid plan under the maximization of the mutual aid platform. We select three types of members based on the probability of loss. The mean value of the risk aversion coefficient is 0.002, the standard deviation is 0.02, and the surcharge rate is 0.15. Among them, the participation rate of the first type member is the lowest, mainly because the difference between the expected contribution amount of participants and insurance is very small. Some members with high degree of risk aversion choose insurance with more security.

Table 4. Maximize platform revenue.

Table 5 gives the optimal plan design of the mutual aid platform under minimizing risks. We select the same parameters as Table 4, and the risk aversion degree of the platform is $r=1$. It can be found that, compared to Table 4, the fixed fees and management rates under minimized platform risk are much smaller, and the corresponding number of participants is higher than Table 4. In other words, the platform increases the number of users by reducing unit revenue to maintain stable operation of the platform.

Table 5. Minimize platform risk.

4.3. Analysis of relations between variables

In this section, we mainly analyze how various variables affect each other when participants do not consider insurance. First, we study the relationship between the expected revenue of the platform unit and the number of participants of various members. There are following propositions.

Proposition 1. The number of $i^{\rm th}$ type members participants $n_i$ is a decreasing function of the expected revenue of the platform unit $x$ for $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$. That is,

$$\frac{dn_i}{dx}<0.$$

Proof. We consider the following function, for $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$,

$$G_i(x,n_i)=F_i^{{-}1}\left(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i}\right)\left(\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}-p_iB_i^{2}\right)+2x.$$

Taking the derivative of $G_i$ with respect to $x$ yields

$$\frac{\partial G_i}{\partial x}=F_i^{{-}1}\left(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i}\right)\frac{2(x+p_iB_i)}{1-p_i}+2>0.$$

Taking the derivative of $G_i$ with respect to $n_i$ yields

$$\frac{\partial G_i}{\partial n_i}=\left[ F_i^{{-}1}\left(1-\frac{n_i}{m_i}\right) \right]^{\prime}\left(\frac{(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}{1-p_i}-p_iB_i^{2}\right).$$

Note that $F_i^{-1}$ is an increasing function and thus $F_i^{-1}(1-{n_i}/{m_i})$ is a decreasing function of $n_i$, so $[F_i^{-1}(1-{n_i}/{m_i})]^{\prime }<0$. Because of the risk aversion coefficient $\xi _i>0$, we have ${(x+p_iB_i)^{2}}/{(1-p_i)}-p_iB_i^{2}<0$, so

$$\frac{\partial G_i}{\partial n_i}>0 \quad \text{and} \quad \frac{dn_i}{dx}={-}\frac{\partial G_i/\partial x}{\partial G_i/\partial n_i}<0.$$

 □

It can be seen from Proposition 1 that the platform can control the number of participants of various members by changing the expected return of the unit. More specifically, the platform can adjust the expected return of the unit by increasing or reducing the management fee of a certain type of member, thereby affecting the final number of participants. Hence, it is necessary to study the relationship between the expected return of the platform unit and various parameters.

Proposition 2. The relationship between the expected revenue $x$ of the platform unit and the fixed management fee $\beta _i$, the management rate $\alpha _i$, the probability of loss $p_i$, and the mutual aid amount $B_i$ are as follows:

  1. 1. For $\forall i\in \mathcal {N}$, $x$ is the increasing function of $\beta _i$ and $\alpha _i$.Thus,

    $$\frac{\partial x}{\partial\beta_i}>0,\quad \frac{\partial x}{\partial\alpha_i}>0.$$
  2. 2. Set $\beta _i=0$, that is, when the platform only sets the management rate, $\alpha _i$ is the decreasing function of $p_i$ and $B_i$. That is,

    $$\frac{\partial\alpha_i}{\partial p_i}<0,\quad \frac{\partial\alpha_i}{\partial B_i}<0.$$
  3. 3. Set $\alpha _i=0$, that is, when the platform only sets the fixed fee, $\beta _i$ is the increasing function of $p_i$.Therefore, $\beta _i$ is independent of $B_i$.

    $$\frac{\partial\beta_i}{\partial p_i}>0,\quad \frac{\partial\beta_i}{\partial B_i}=0.$$

The first part of Proposition 2 indicates that the increment in fixed fees and management rates inevitably increases the expected revenue per unit of the platform. Combining Proposition 1 we know that the increment in the cost of mutual aid for any type of member leads to a decrease in the number of members.

The second and third parts of Proposition 2 describe the relationship between the member's risk of loss, mutual fund, and payment when only one method is used to collect management fees. When there is no fixed management fee, the higher the member's loss probability and mutual fund, the lower the management rate. Of course, the low management rate does not mean that the cost of mutual aid is low. A higher apportionment ratio makes the cost of mutual aid of high-risk members the same as those of low-risk members, thereby satisfying the condition of relative fairness.

5. Numerical illustration

5.1. Numerical analysis

In this section, the analysis is based on the largest network mutual aid platform in China, named “Xianghubao.” Some actual values are used and the model proposed in this paper is applied to calculate the payment made by mutual aid platform members, to design the management fee and the number of people who join the mutual aid plan. We regard all Internet users as the target group of Xianghubao. The scale of Internet users and their attribute structure are selected from the “45th Statistical Report on the Development of Internet in China.” The data in the “China Life Insurance Industry Critical Illness Experience Occurrence Table (2020)” is selected as the probability of illness for different members.

Since Xianghubao only allows members aged 60 and below to join, we divide people into five different age groups according to their ages. Table 6 gives the probability of critical illness among different age groups and the proportion of total population.

Table 6. Critical illness probability and total internet user population portion.

It can be seen from Table 6 that the probability of critical illness varies greatly between different age groups, and the largest difference in the probability of critical illness among age groups with the same mutual fund is nearly five times. In order to make the apportionment mechanism fair and not overly cumbersome, we divide members into five types according to age, and the total population is standardized to 1. Table 7 summarizes the parameter values used by different types of members in the model.

Table 7. Various parameter values in the model.

We assume that different types of members have the same risk aversion coefficient distribution. This paper selects a lognormal distribution with a mean value of 0.002 and a standard deviation of 0.018. Taking $r=30$, the mutual aid scheme to minimize platform risk is shown in Table 8. In this case, whether insurance is considered or not does not affect the final pricing. Regarding the selection of premiums, we choose the 20% surcharge rate of group insurance to be included in the calculation. Table 9 shows the mutual aid schemes to maximize platform revenue. ${\beta _i}^{\ast }$ or $\alpha _i^{\ast }$ indicates the optimal solution when only a fixed management fee or management rate is charged. $n_i^{\ast }$ is the optimal number of people to join the mutual aid platform. ${\bar {s}}_i$ represents the expected annual apportionment amount of participants. $\theta _i^{\ast }$ is the optimal allocation weight coefficient.

Table 8. The optimal solution of Model 1.

Table 9. The optimal solution of Model 4.

At present, the annual apportionment amount of Xianghubao's “serious illness mutual aid” plan is about $120. Compared with the apportioned expenses ${\bar {s}}_i$ in Tables 8 and 9, we find that except for the apportioned amount of 1-type member is less than the actual apportioned amount, the others are larger than the actual apportioned amount. The analysis found that there are three main reasons for this situation

  1. 1. People who join Xianghubao actually have a lower probability of getting the disease. Only Alipay users with sesame credit scores of more than 650 points and meeting mutual health requirements of Xianghubao can join, which makes the loss probability of Xianghubao members much lower than that of the experience table.

  2. 2. Xianghubao has a problem of difficulty in paying compensation. After the patient applies for the protection fund, there will be a third-party audit. The audit is stricter and lasts a long time, which lasts about 1–3 months. The approval will be publicized on the platform, and the security deposit can be obtained only after the publicity period expires and there is no objection. Because the entry threshold is low and there is no substantive underwriting medical examination, the patient may fail to apply because of not meeting the health conditions.

  3. 3. Some people are still in the waiting period, they only participate in the apportionment and cannot get mutual funds. Joining and exiting Xianghubao are relatively simple, and platform members are highly mobile. Some members are still in the 90-day waiting period. Even if they are sick, they cannot apply for mutual funds, but they still have to perform their sharing obligations, which indirectly reduces the overall risk of the mutual aid group. Moreover, Xianghubao's review process is long, and some claims have not been made public yet.

These three main reasons cause the loss probability under actual conditions to be lower than the probability in the “Experience Table.” Next, estimate the actual loss probability based on the number of patients in the 24th period of 2020 in the “serious illness mutual aid” of Xianghubao. The average total number of mutual aid groups is 100.2474 million, and the total number of losses is 52,682. The proportion of each age group is based on the statistical report. We use $\widehat {p_i}$ to represent the actual probabilities of $i^{\rm th}$ type members.

It can be seen from Table 10 that the empirical probability is two to five times the actual illness probability, and a lower loss probability naturally leads to a smaller apportioned amount. Next, we adapt the empirical data where the probability of illness among participants in the mutual aid program is the loss probability, $r=300$, and the optimal mutual aid plan is shown in Tables 11 and 12.

Table 10. Actual parameters.

Table 11. Optimal solution of Model 1 with actual parameters.

Table 12. Optimal solution of Model 4 with actual parameters.

It shows that the model sharing amount calculated by using the empirical loss probability is more suitable. The average per capita sharing is about $90, which is lower than the actual sharing amount, and different members have different apportionment shares, which reduces the risk of adverse selection.

5.2. Compared with insurance

Developed at the same time, medical insurance with a million-level coverage, which has the same advantages as the network mutual aid, is also controversial as the network mutual aid. For consumers, these two products have great similarities, so we analyze the advantages and disadvantages of medical insurance with a million-level coverage and network mutual aid through price and protection.

We select “Good health insurance long-term care” (GIC) as the representative of medical insurance with a million-level coverage, and in terms of network mutual aid, we select “Xianghubao” with the largest number of users. Table 13 shows a comparison of the costs of the GIC and the Xianghubao platform. In order to be fair, we convert the premiums of GIC to the costs under the same amount as Xianghubao.

Table 13. Medical insurance with a million-level coverage and network mutual aid.

Through comparison, we found that the two products have their own advantages and disadvantages:

  1. 1. The annual cost of each age group of Xianghubao is lower than that of GIC, but the premium here is calculated based on the insured person without Social Security, otherwise the premium is lower than the share of Xianghubao.

  2. 2. GIC is reimbursement insurance with a deductible of 10,000 ¥; Xianghubao is similar to payment insurance with no deductible.

  3. 3. Both types of protection are short-term. GIC has a coverage period of 1 year, but the insurance is guaranteed to be renewed within 6 years; while Xianghubao is apportioned every half month and can be withdrawn at any time.

  4. 4. GIC, as medical insurance, has rigid protection, while Xianghubao is not insurance, and there is a risk of platform failure.

Through analysis, we can clearly distinguish the advantages and disadvantages of each, and also attract different types of people to buy. Those with higher risk aversion and better economic levels can buy medical insurance with a million-level coverage. People with low risk awareness and low economic level can choose to network mutual aid. However, there is no conflict between the two and can be purchased at the same time.

6. Conclusion

In this paper, the framework of the platform under different optimization objectives is constructed for members with different options. Members are divided into different types according to their risks, and each member decides whether to join a mutual aid plan based on expected utility. The platform sets the optimal management cost under the goals of maximizing revenue and minimizing risks. In addition, we analyzed the relationship between the variables in the mutual aid plan, and compared the advantages and disadvantages between the mutual aid plan and similar competing products based on actual data.

  • First, we established a member's decision-making model. In general, participants who are willing to transfer risks would have three choices: buying insurance, joining a mutual aid platform, or buying nothing. Since everyone has different degrees of risk aversion, hence risk aversion people of different degrees make decisions based on the principle of maximizing expected utility is analyzed.

  • Secondly, we considered the optimization goals of mutual aid platforms under different business concepts. In the case of satisfying individual fairness conditions and relative fairness conditions, different optimization problems are proposed. The results showed that setting different categories, adopting the same type equally, and different types proportionally can effectively reduce the problem of adverse selection.

  • Finally, model results are compared with empirical evidence. We found that our optimized model has more advantages in price compared with the actual mutual aid platform and medical insurance with a million-level coverage. The cost difference under different optimization goals is more obvious. The platform management fee under the maximization of revenue is higher, and correspondingly, the number of participants on the platform under the minimization of risk is larger.

Acknowledgments

The authors are very grateful to reviewers for their very thorough reading of the paper and valuable suggestions. The research of Jingchao Li was supported by the National Key R&D Program of China (Grant No. 2020YFB2103503 ), Shenzhen Peacock Program (project No. 000417), and the Science and Technology Planning Project of Shenzhen Municipality, P.R. China (20200813151828003). The authors wish to express their gratitude for these financial supports.

Competing interests

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

We give some numerical examples in below, which shows that the approximation by using second-order Taylor expansion is accurate for different cases. We present the error for three kinds of utility functions such as exponential utility, logarithm utility, and power utility. In addition, under different parameter values for $p$, $\alpha$, and $\beta$, the errors for Eqs. (3.2) and (3.3) are always small.

The error is defined as

$$\text{Error }=\frac{|\text{Approximation}-\text{Exact}|}{\text{Exact}}.$$

In the following numerical examples, we assume that there are five types of members, so that $i=5$. Let $w_{i,j}^{0}=(200{,}000,300{,}000,400{,}000,500{,}000,600{,}000)$ (simplified as $w$) and $B$ is a divisor of $w$.

Example A.1. Considering an exponential utility function where $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001w}$. The probabilities of illness for different members are chosen to be the same as Table 6 in the paper, where $p=(0.000269,0.000528,0.001444,0.003909,0.008553)$. Besides, the values of management rates and fixed fees are also the same as the optimal solution of Model 1 in the paper, so that $\alpha =(0.094,0.0479,0.0175,0.0194,0.0089)$ and $\beta =(7.59,7.59,7.59,7.61,7.65)$.

From Table A.1, it shows that for the exponential utility function with different combinations of amount of loss $B$ and initial wealth $w$, the errors are very small for all cases. In addition, with the difference between $w$ and $B$ increases, the errors become smaller, which means that if the condition $w_{i,j}^{0} \gg B_i$ and $w_{i,j}^{0} \gg \beta _i+s_{ij} (1+\alpha _i)$ are satisfied, the errors for second-order Taylor approximation will be very small. In addition, we can see that the approximation works well for both Eqs. (3.2) and (3.3).

Example A.2. Letting a logarithm utility function where $u(w)=\ln (w)$. The probability of illness are the same as in Example A.1, where $p=(0.000269,0.000528,0.001444,0.003909,0.008553)$. Besides, the values of management rates and fixed fees are also the same as the optimal solution of Model 1 in the paper, so that $\alpha =(0.094,0.0479,0.0175,0.0194,0.0089)$ and $\beta =(7.59,7.59,7.59,7.61,7.65)$.

Table A.1. Exponential utility function with $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$.

From Table A.2, it shows that for a logarithm utility function $u(w)=\ln (w)$ for different combinations of amount of loss $B$ and initial wealth $w$, the errors are very small for Eq. (3.3) and also small for Eq. (3.1). In addition, we can also see that for Eq. (3.2), when the difference between B and w is not large enough, the error is about between 0.1 and 0.17%, as the difference between $B$ and $w$ gets larger, the error become significantly smaller, which implies the assumptions $w_{i,j}^{0} \gg B_i$ and $w_{i,j}^{0} \gg \beta _i+s_{ij} (1+\alpha _i)$ are necessary for both Eqs. (3.1) and (3.2) to apply Taylor expansion.

Example A.3. Considering a fractional power utility function which $u(w)=w^{0.5}$. The probabilities of illness are the same as in Example A.1. Besides, the values of management rates and fixed fees are also the same as Examples A.1 and A.2.

Table A.2. Logarithm utility function with $u(w)=\ln (w)$.

From Table A.3, it shows that for a fractional power utility function $u(w)=w^{0.5}$ for different combinations of amount of loss $B$ and initial wealth $w$, the errors again are very small for Eq. (3.3) and small for Eq. (3.1). The error has similar trend as in Table 2, which also indicates the importance to have the assumptions $w_{i,j}^{0} \gg B_i$ and $w_{i,j}^{0} \gg \beta _i+s_{ij} (1+\alpha _i)$ for Eqs. (3.1) and (3.2) to apply Taylor expansion. Besides, the errors for Eq. (3.2) are the same when the multiplier for $B$ and $w$ are the same, that is due to the structure of the fractional power utility function.

Example A.4. Considering an exponential utility function with a different parameter value where $u(w)=-e^{-0.000003 w}$. The probabilities of illness, the values of management rates and fixed fees are all the same as in Example A.1.

Table A.3. Fractional power utility function with $u(w)=w^{0.5}$.

Example A.5. Considering a power utility function with a different parameter value which $u(w)=w^{0.4}$. The probabilities of illness, the values of management rates and fixed fees are all the same as in Example A.1.

From Tables A.4 and A.5, we can see that by changing the parameters of exponential utility function and fractional power utility function, the errors are still small. Especially for Eq. (3.2), the error becomes smaller as the multiplier of $w$ and $B$ gets larger, so it shows that when $w$ is much greater than $B$, the approximation works well.

Example A.6. Considering an exponential utility function where $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$. The probabilities of illness for different members are the same in Example A.1. The values of management rates and fixed fees are the same as the optimal solution of Model 1 but with actual parameters in the paper, where $\alpha =(0.1753,0.791,0.196,0.453,0.151)$ and $\beta =(3.16,3.16,3.16,3.16,3.16)$.

Table A.4. Exponential utility function $u(w)=-e^{-0.000003 w}$.

Table A.5. Fractional power utility function $u(w)=w^{0.4}$.

Example A.7. Considering an exponential utility function which $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$. The probabilities of illness for different members are the same in Example A.1. The values of management rates and fixed fees change to a significantly large setting where $\alpha =(0.3,0.3,0.3,0.3,0.3)$ and $\beta =(20,20,20,20,20)$.

Example A.8. Considering a logarithm utility function which $u(w)=\ln (w)$. The probabilities of illness for different members are the same in Example A.1. The values of management rates and fixed fees change to a significantly large setting where $\alpha =(0.3,0.3,0.3,0.3,0.3)$ and $\beta =(20,20,20,20,20)$.

Example A.9. Considering a fractional power utility function which $u(w)=w^{0.5}$. The probabilities of illness for different members are the same in Example A.1. The values of management rates and fixed fees change to a significantly large setting where $\alpha =(0.3,0.3,0.3,0.3,0.3)$ and $\beta =(20,20,20,20,20)$.

Tables A.6A.9 gives the errors for Eqs. (3.2) and (3.3) by changing values of management rates and fixed fees. We can see that the errors for Eq. (3.2) do not depend on $\alpha$, $\beta$. Moreover, the errors for Eq. (3.3) remain at a very small level no matter management rates and fixed fees increase or decrease.

Example A.10. Considering an exponential function with a different parameter value which $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$. The values of management rates and fixed fees are both the same as in Example A.1. The probabilities of illness are changed to the probabilities with actual parameters as in Table 10 in the paper, where $p=(0.00006,0.000133,0.000536,0.000696,0.002096)$.

Table A.6. Exponential utility function $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$ with $\alpha$, $\beta$ from actual parameters.

Table A.7. Exponential utility function $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$ with relatively large $\alpha$, $\beta$.

Table A.8. Logarithm utility function $u(w)=\ln (w)$ with relatively large $\alpha$, $\beta$.

Table A.9. Fractional Power utility function $u(w)=w^{0.5}$ with relatively large $\alpha$, $\beta$.

We can see from Table A.10 that as the probability decreases, the errors for Eq. (3.3) also decreases. However, errors for Eq. (3.2) remains the same as it does not depend on the probability.

Table A.10. Exponential utility function $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$ with different probabilities.

From above examples we can see that by applying constrains $w_{i,j}^{0} \gg B_i$ and $w_{i,j}^{0} \gg \beta _i+s_{ij} (1+\alpha _i)$, the second-order Taylor expansion is a good approximation for decision making under an individual's expected utility function.

References

Abdikerimova, S. & Feng, R. (2022). Peer-to-peer multi-risk insurance and mutual aid. European Journal of Operational Research 299(2): 735749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abdikerimova, S., Boonen, T.J., & Feng, R. (2021). Multi-period peer-to-peer risk sharing. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4065099.Google Scholar
Andersen, S., Harrison, G.W., Lau, M.I., & Rutström, E.E. (2010). Preference heterogeneity in experiments: Comparing the field and laboratory. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 73(2): 209224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asimit, A.S., Boonen, T.J., Chi, Y., & Chong, W.F. (2021). Risk sharing with multiple indemnity environments. European Journal of Operational Research 295(2): 587603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Assa, A. & Boonen, T.J. (2022). Risk-sharing and contingent premia in the presence of systematic risk: The case study of the UK COVID-19 economic losses. In Pandemics: Insurance and social protection, (Springer Actuarial). Springer. 95126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borch, K. (1962). Equilibrium in a reinsurance market. Econometrica 30(2): 424444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlin, B.I. (2009). Strategic price complexity in retail financial markets. Journal of Financial Economics 91(3): 278287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Z., Feng, R., Wei, L., Zhao, J. (2021). From ex ante to ex post risk sharing: Cost-effectiveness, unfairness and adverse selection in mutual aid. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3925904.Google Scholar
Chiu, C.H., Choi, T.M., Dai, X., Shen, B., & Zheng, J.H. (2018). Optimal advertising budget allocation in luxury fashion markets with social influences: A mean-variance analysis. Production and Operations Management 27(8): 16111629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, A. & Einav, L. (2007). Estimating risk preferences from deductible choice. American Economic Review 97(3): 745788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corner, J.L. (1994). Operationalizing approximate multiattribute utility functions for use in practice. European Journal of Operational Research 79(1): 7384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denuit, M. (2019). Size-biased transform and conditional mean risk sharing, with application to P2P insurance and tontines. ASTIN Bulletin: The Journal of the IAA 49(3): 591617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denuit, M. (2020). Investing in your own and peers’ risks: The simple analytics of P2P insurance. European Actuarial Journal 10(2): 335359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denuit, M. & Dhaene, J. (2012). Convex order and comonotonic conditional mean risk sharing. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 51: 265270.Google Scholar
Donnelly, C., Guillén, M., & Nielsen, J.P. (2014). Bringing cost transparency to the life annuity market. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 56: 1427.Google Scholar
Eeckhoudt, L.R. & Laeven, R.J. (2015). Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large under Rank-Dependent Utility. Preprint arXiv:1512.08037.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, M. (1940). Roman military clubs and their social functions. Transactions and Proceedings of the American Philological Association 71: 149156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halek, M. & Eisenhauer, J.G. (2001). Demography of risk aversion. The Journal of Risk and Insurance 68(1): 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hassett, M., Sears, R.S., & Trennepohl, G.L. (1985). Asset preference, skewness, and the measurement of expected utility. Journal of Economics and Business 37(1): 3547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moenninghoff, S.C. & Wieandt, A. (2013). The future of peer-to-peer finance. Schmalenbachs Zeitschrift für betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung 65(5): 466487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perry, J.S. (2006). The Roman Collegia: the modern evolution of an ancient concept. Leiden, The Netherlands: Koninklijke Brill NV.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sohu (2016). What is the profit model of the comparative analysis of the 11 major online mutual aid platforms? Viewed 22 March 2020. Available: https://www.sohu.com/a/113619060_115411.Google Scholar
Su, F., Xiong, J., & Tang, W. (2020). A discussion on theoretical attribute of network mutual assistance. Insurance Studies 387(7): 4962.Google Scholar
Thomas, P.J. (2016). Measuring risk-aversion: The challenge. Measurement 79: 285301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W.K. & Evans, W.N. (1990). Utility functions that depend on health status: Estimates and economic implications. The American Economic Review 80(3): 353374.Google Scholar
Wen, X. & Siqin, T. (2020). How do product quality uncertainties affect the sharing economy platforms with risk considerations? A mean-variance analysis. International Journal of Production Economics 224: 107544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank Group. (2018). How technology can make insurance more inclusive. Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Xueqiu (2019). AI media report - 2019 special research report on China's network mutual aid development. Viewed 25 March 2020. Available: https://xueqiu.com/9582690951/138125021.Google Scholar
Zhang, X., Meng, H., & Zeng, Y. (2016). Optimal investment and reinsurance strategies for insurers with generalized mean–variance premium principle and no-short selling. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 67: 125132.Google Scholar
Zhao, Y. & Zeng, Y. (2021). Optimal commissions and subscriptions in mutual aid platforms. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3781344.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Risk aversion coefficient $\xi _i$ and platform expected return $x$.

Figure 1

Table 1. The optimal solution of Model 1 under the lognormal distribution function.

Figure 2

Table 2. The optimal solution of Model 1 under the Pareto distribution function.

Figure 3

Table 3. Parameter value.

Figure 4

Table 4. Maximize platform revenue.

Figure 5

Table 5. Minimize platform risk.

Figure 6

Table 6. Critical illness probability and total internet user population portion.

Figure 7

Table 7. Various parameter values in the model.

Figure 8

Table 8. The optimal solution of Model 1.

Figure 9

Table 9. The optimal solution of Model 4.

Figure 10

Table 10. Actual parameters.

Figure 11

Table 11. Optimal solution of Model 1 with actual parameters.

Figure 12

Table 12. Optimal solution of Model 4 with actual parameters.

Figure 13

Table 13. Medical insurance with a million-level coverage and network mutual aid.

Figure 14

Table A.1. Exponential utility function with $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$.

Figure 15

Table A.2. Logarithm utility function with $u(w)=\ln (w)$.

Figure 16

Table A.3. Fractional power utility function with $u(w)=w^{0.5}$.

Figure 17

Table A.4. Exponential utility function $u(w)=-e^{-0.000003 w}$.

Figure 18

Table A.5. Fractional power utility function $u(w)=w^{0.4}$.

Figure 19

Table A.6. Exponential utility function $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$ with $\alpha$, $\beta$ from actual parameters.

Figure 20

Table A.7. Exponential utility function $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$ with relatively large $\alpha$, $\beta$.

Figure 21

Table A.8. Logarithm utility function $u(w)=\ln (w)$ with relatively large $\alpha$, $\beta$.

Figure 22

Table A.9. Fractional Power utility function $u(w)=w^{0.5}$ with relatively large $\alpha$, $\beta$.

Figure 23

Table A.10. Exponential utility function $u(w)=-e^{-0.000001 w}$ with different probabilities.