Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T18:15:36.537Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Normal Mode Copulas for Nonmonotonic Dependence

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 February 2024

Kentaro Fukumoto*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Gakushuin University, Tokyo, Japan.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Copulas are helpful in studying joint distributions of two variables, in particular, whenconfounders are unobserved. However, most conventional copulas cannot model joint distributions where one variable does not increase or decrease in the other in a monotonic manner. For instance, suppose that two variables are linearly positively correlated for one type of unit and negatively for another type of unit. If the type is unobserved, we can observe only a mixture of both types. Seemingly, one variable tends to take either a high or low value (or a middle value) when the other variable is small (large), or vice versa. To address this issue, I consider an overlooked copula with trigonometric functions (Chesneau [2021, Applied Mathematics, 1(1), pp. 3–17]) thatI name the “normal mode copula.” I apply the copula to a dataset about government formation and duration to demonstrate that the normal mode copula has better performance than other conventional copulas.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - SA
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.0), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the same Creative Commons licence is used to distribute the re-used or adapted article and the original article is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained prior to any commercial use.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of The Society for Political Methodology

1 Introduction

When two variables are simultaneously generated, it becomes challenging and promising to study the relationship between them. For instance, if unobserved confounders affect them, regressing one variable on the other leads to endogeneity bias. Scholars may have reasonable substantive knowledge or theory about the marginal distributions of the two variables but no idea about the conditional distribution of one variable given the other. One approach is to directly analyze the joint distribution. When one variable includes some of the same information as the other, analyzing them together will lead to less biased and more efficient estimation, as well as better prediction without assuming selection on observables. Classic methods include the seemingly unrelated regression and Heckman’s sample selection models, although they assume only a bivariate normal distribution for the variables.Footnote 1 Instead, as I elaborate on below, copula functions are flexible and helpful because they model how dependent the two variables are on each other, whatever marginal distribution each variable follows. In political science, Braumoeller et al. (Reference Braumoeller, Marra, Radice and Bradshaw2018), Chiba, Martin, and Stevenson (Reference Chiba, Martin and Stevenson2015), Chiba, Metternich, and Ward (Reference Chiba, Metternich and Ward2015), and Fukumoto (Reference Fukumoto2015) have employed copulas.Footnote 2 In finance, Li (Reference Li2000) improves credit derivative valuation by accounting for the default correlation with the help of copulas.

However, an understudied shortcoming of copulas is that most conventional copulas cannot model joint distributions where one variable does not increase or decrease in the other in a monotonic manner. To date, little attention has been devoted to such situations because those scenarios “do not seem to arise often in applications” (Hofert et al. Reference Hofert, Kojadinovic, Maechler and Yan2018, 173, emphasis added). Nevertheless, they do sometimes arise, even in political science. For instance, suppose that two variables are linearly positively correlated for one type of unit and negatively correlated for another type of unit. If the type is unobserved, we can observe only a mixture of both types. Seemingly, one variable tends to take either a high or low value (or a middle value) when the other variable is small (large), or vice versa.

One example is the relationship between access to social media and press freedom. Kocak and Kıbrıs (Reference Kocak and Kıbrıs2023) develop a game-theoretic model to argue that higher internet access promotes press freedom in a country when an incumbent has a lower rent from office but prohibits it in a country with higher rent. The left panel of Figure 1 replicates Figure 1 of Kocak and Kıbrıs (Reference Kocak and Kıbrıs2023) that shows the relationship between internet penetration and press freedom in 160 countries from 2000 to 2015.Footnote 3 Each dot corresponds to a unit of observation, namely, a country in a year ( $n=2,560$ ). The horizontal axis represents internet penetration. The vertical axis indicates a press freedom score. When internet penetration is low, the press freedom scores vary (near the left vertical axis). When internet penetration is high, some units have high press freedom scores (top-right corner) and others have low press freedom scores (bottom-right corner), although no unit has a moderate press freedom score (near and in the middle of the right vertical axis). Therefore, the relationship between the two variables is nonmonotonic in the sense that internet penetration decreases in press freedom when press freedom is low but increases in press freedom when press freedom is high. Since the rent is unobserved, we cannot condition on it and should have studied the joint distribution.

Figure 1 Empirical examples of nonmonotonic dependence. (a) Each dot corresponds to a country in a year, 2000 to 2015 ( $n=2,560$ ). (b) Each dot corresponds a civil war, 1946 to 2003 ( $n=267$ ).

Another instance is civil war duration and outcome, 1946 to 2003 (Cunningham, Gleditsch, and Salehyan Reference Cunningham, Gleditsch and Salehyan2009). In the right panel of Figure 1, each point represents a civil war ( $n=267$ ), the horizontal axis indicates the duration in days, and the vertical axis corresponds to the outcome, which is equal to one if the government wins, two if neither side wins, and three if the rebellion wins.Footnote 4 If either the government or the rebellion is strong enough to win, the civil war ends in a short time. Otherwise, neither side obtains a decisive victory, but they instead reach a negotiated settlement to spare the continuing war attrition costs. They do this only after the intrastate military conflict persists for a long duration (Mason, Weingarten Jr, and Fett Reference Mason, Weingarten and Fett1999). Here, the relative power of rebels to governments is a confounder, which is observed but only as a three-category indicator with measurement error.

In these cases, the underlying copulas have irregular properties, such as nonmonotonicity and asymmetricity. Few parametric copulas can handle these properties. To address this gap, I pay special attention to an overlooked copula (Chesneau Reference Chesneau2021), which I name the “normal mode copula.” It is imperative to enlarge the pool of copulas so that analysts can flexibly adapt the joint distribution to the data and alleviate reliance on the functional-form assumption of the joint distribution (Braumoeller et al. Reference Braumoeller, Marra, Radice and Bradshaw2018).

This article is organized as follows: The next section elaborates on the definition of copulas, introduces some conventional copulas, and defines the normal mode copula. In the following section, I apply these copulas to a dataset on government formation and duration (Chiba et al. Reference Chiba, Martin and Stevenson2015) to demonstrate that the normal mode copula fits the data better than do other conventional copulas. Finally, I present concluding remarks.

2 Definition

2.1 Generic and Gaussian Copulas

Let $0 \leq u_{d} \leq 1$ for $d \in \{1, 2\}$ . A function $C(u_{1}, u_{2}): [0, 1]^2 \to [0, 1]$ is called a copula if the following two conditions are met (Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006, 10):

  • Boundary conditions:  $C(u_{1}, 0) = C(0, u_{2}) = 0, C(u_{1}, 1) = u_{1}$ , and $C(1, u_{2}) = u_{2}$ .

  • Two-increasing condition: If $u_{1}^{L} \leq u_{1}^{H}$ and $u_{2}^{L} \leq u_{2}^{H}$ , it follows that $C(u_{1}^{H}, u_{2}^{H}) - C(u_{1}^{L}, u_{2}^{H}) - C(u_{1}^{H}, u_{2}^{L}) + C(u_{1}^{L}, u_{2}^{L}) \geq 0$ .

The motivation for copulas is as follows. I suppose that there are two random variables, $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ . I denote the value of the dth variable $X_{d}$ by $x_{d}$ , the marginal cumulative distribution function (CDF) of $X_{d}$ by $F_{d}(x_{d}) \equiv u_{d}$ , and the joint CDF of $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ by $F_{12}(x_{1}, x_{2})$ . Then, according to Sklar’s theorem (Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006, 18 and 24–25), there exists a copula C such that

(1) $$ \begin{align} F_{12}(x_{1}, x_{2}) = C \{ F_{1}(x_{1}), F_{2}(x_{2}) \}. \end{align} $$

When $F_{1}$ and $F_{2}$ are continuous, C is unique. If $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ are continuous variables and we can differentiate both sides of Equation (1) by $x_{1}$ and $x_{2}$ , we obtain

(2) $$ \begin{align} f_{12}(x_{1}, x_{2}) = f_{1}(x_{1}) f_{2}(x_{2}) c (u_{1}, u_{2}), \end{align} $$

where $f_{d}(x_{d})$ is the probability density function (PDF) of $X_{d}$ and

$$ \begin{align*} c (u_{1}, u_{2}) \equiv \frac{\partial^2 }{\partial u_{1} \partial u_{2}} C (u_{1}, u_{2}) \end{align*} $$

represents densities for copula C.Footnote 5 The copula C of $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ abstracts away the marginal distributions of $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ and thus distills all information about the dependence between $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ . Equation (2) clarifies the modularity of the copula: we can substitute the marginal distribution of one variable or the copula without changing the other two terms on the right-hand side to obtain a new bivariate distribution on the left-hand side.

For instance, the Gaussian copula is defined as

$$ \begin{align*} C_{\mathrm{G}}(u_{1}, u_{2}) \equiv \Phi^2 \{ \Phi^{-1}(u_{1}), \Phi^{-1}(u_{2}) \mid \theta \}, \end{align*} $$

where $\Phi $ and $\Phi ^2$ are univariate and bivariate standard normal distributions, respectively, and $-1 \leq \theta \leq 1$ is the correlation parameter. Figure 2 illustrates an example; the top-left panel shows a contour plot of densities for the joint distribution $f_{12}(x_{1}, x_{2}) = \phi ^2(x_{1}, x_{2} \mid \theta = 0.156)$ , where $\phi ^2$ is the PDF of $\Phi ^2$ ;Footnote 6 the bottom-left and top-right panels present densities for the marginal distributions $f_{1}(x_{1}) = \phi (x_{1})$ and $f_{2}(x_{2}) = \phi (x_{2})$ , respectively, where $\phi $ is the PDF of $\Phi $ ; the bottom-right panel represents a contour plot of densities for the copula $c(u_{1}, u_{2})$ , which turns to be Gaussian, $c_{\mathrm {G}}(u_{1}, u_{2})$ .Footnote 7 If we substitute $f_{1}(x_{1}), f_{2}(x_{2})$ , or $c (u_{1}, u_{2})$ , the joint distribution $f_{12}(x_{1}, x_{2})$ is no longer represented by $\phi ^2$ .

Figure 2 Bivariate normal distribution: joint distribution, marginal distributions, and copula.

2.2 Conventional Copulas

Scholars have derived dozens of copulas (Hofert et al. Reference Hofert, Kojadinovic, Maechler and Yan2018; Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006; Trivedi and Zimmer Reference Trivedi and Zimmer2007). For reference, I introduce the product copula and the following four conventional copulas: Farlie–Gumbel–Morgenstein (FGM), Ali–Mikhail–Haq (AMH), Clayton, and Frank.

The product (or independence) copula is defined as (Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006, 25)

$$ \begin{align*} C_{\mathrm{I}} (u_{1}, u_{2}) \equiv u_{1} u_{2}, \end{align*} $$

where $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ are independent of each other.

The FGM copula is defined as (Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006, 77)

$$ \begin{align*} C_{\mathrm{FGM}} (u_{1}, u_{2}) \equiv u_{1} u_{2} + \theta u_{1} (1 - u_{1}) u_{2} (1 - u_{2}), \end{align*} $$

where $-1 \leq \theta \leq 1$ .

The other three belong to a class of Archimedean copulas. Let the generator function $\varphi (u): [0, 1] \to [0, \infty ]$ be a continuous, convex, strictly decreasing function, where $\varphi (1) = 0$ . I define the pseudoinverse function of $\varphi (u)$ as $\varphi ^{[-1]}(z) = \varphi ^{-1}(z)$ for $0 \leq z \leq \varphi (0)$ and $\varphi ^{[-1]}(z) = 0$ for $\varphi (0) \leq z \leq \infty $ . Then, the following function:

$$ \begin{align*} C_{\mathrm{A}} ( u_{1}, u_{2} \mid \varphi) \equiv \varphi^{[-1]}\{ \varphi(u_{1}) + \varphi(u_{2}) \} \end{align*} $$

meets the two conditions of a copula and is called an Archimedean copula (Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006, 110–112). The generator functions for the AMH, Clayton, and Frank copulas are

$$ \begin{align*} \varphi_{\mathrm{AMH}}(u) &\equiv \log \left[ \frac{1}{u} \{ 1 - \theta (1 - u) \} \right]& \textrm{for} & \quad -1 \leq \theta \leq 1,\\ \varphi_{\mathrm{Clayton}}(u) &\equiv \theta^{-1} (u^{- \theta} - 1) & \textrm{for} & \quad \theta> 0,\\ \varphi_{\mathrm{Frank}}(u) &\equiv - \log \left[ \frac{1}{\exp( - \theta ) - 1} \{ \exp( - \theta u) - 1 \}\right] & \textrm{for} & \quad \theta \in \mathbb{R},\\ \end{align*} $$

respectively.

Figure 3 shows contour plots of densities for the conventional copulas, where the horizontal and vertical axes are $u_{1}$ and $u_{2}$ , respectively. Panels correspond to FGM, AMH, Clayton, and Frank.Footnote 8 Clearly, these copulas represent monotonic dependence.

Figure 3 Example plots of conventional copulas.

In general, the three associated copulas of a copula are defined as (Trivedi and Zimmer Reference Trivedi and Zimmer2007, 13–14)

(3) $$ \begin{align} \overline{C}^{(1)} (u_{1}, u_{2}) & \equiv u_{2} - C (1 - u_{1}, u_{2}), \nonumber\\ \overline{C}^{(2)} (u_{1}, u_{2}) & \equiv u_{1} - C (u_{1}, 1 - u_{2}),\\ \overline{C}^{(12)} (u_{1}, u_{2}) & \equiv u_{1} + u_{2} - 1 + C (1 - u_{1}, 1 - u_{2}).\nonumber \end{align} $$

In particular, $\overline {C}^{(12)} (u_{1}, u_{2})$ is called the survival copula (Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006, 32). Figure 4 illustrates contour plots of densities for the associated Clayton copulas. Graphically, by turning the density $c (u_{1}, u_{2})$ (first panel, the same as the bottom-left panel of Figure 3) with respect to the line $u_{d} = \frac {1}{2}$ , we obtain $\overline {c}^{(d)} (u_{1}, u_{2})$ (second ( $d = 1$ ) and third ( $d = 2$ ) panels); by rotating $c (u_{1}, u_{2})$ 180 degrees, we obtain $\overline {c}^{(12)} (u_{1}, u_{2})$ (fourth panel).Footnote 9 Specifically, I study the three associated copulas for AMH and Clayton copulas (cf. Braumoeller et al. Reference Braumoeller, Marra, Radice and Bradshaw2018, 59); for each of the other conventional copulas, the three associated copulas belong to the family of the original copula.

Figure 4 Example plots of associated Clayton copulas.

2.3 Normal Mode Copulas

Chesneau (Reference Chesneau2021) refers to the following copula but only in passing:

(4) $$ \begin{align} C_{\mathrm{Chesneau}} (u_{1}, u_{2}) = u_{1} u_{2} + \frac{ 1 }{ p_{1} p_{2} \kappa_{1} \kappa_{2} \pi^2 } \theta \{ \sin (u_{1} \kappa_{1} \pi ) \}^{p_{1}} \{ \sin (u_{2} \kappa_{2} \pi ) \}^{p_{2}}, \end{align} $$

where for $d \in \{1, 2\}$ , $\kappa _{d}$ ’s are positive integers, $p_{d} \geq 1$ , and $-1 \leq \theta \leq 1$ .Footnote 10 However, Chesneau (Reference Chesneau2021) did not apply the copula to any real data or give it any name.

I simplify this copula by setting $p_{d} = 1$ ,

$$ \begin{align*} C_{\mathrm{NM}} (u_{1}, u_{2}) \equiv u_{1} u_{2} + \frac{1}{\kappa_{1} \kappa_{2} \pi^2}\theta \sin (u_{1} \kappa_{1} \pi) \sin (u_{2} \kappa_{2} \pi), \end{align*} $$

so that the copula is still flexible in a tractable way with fewer parameters. I name $C_{\mathrm {NM}}$ the normal mode copula, $\theta $ the amplitude, and $\kappa _{d}$ ’s mode numbers. (I explain the motivation shortly.)

Figure 5 shows contour plots of densities for normal mode copulas,

$$ \begin{align*} c_{\mathrm{NM}} (u_{1}, u_{2}) = 1 + \theta \cos (u_{1} \kappa_{1} \pi) \cos (u_{2} \kappa_{2} \pi). \end{align*} $$

The top-left panel corresponds to the case where $\theta = 0.304, \kappa _{1}= 1,$ and $\kappa _{2} = 1$ .Footnote 11 This normal mode copula is (radially) symmetric, where $U_{2}$ monotonically increases in $U_{1}$ . In the top-right panel, I present another normal mode copula where I only change $\theta $ from $0.304$ to $-0.304$ . We obtain the current plot by making the dark parts in the previous plot light and vice versa. Here, $U_{2}$ monotonically decreases in $U_{1}$ . The bottom-left panel represents the case where $\theta = 0.304, \kappa _{1}= 2,$ and $\kappa _{2} = 1$ . This normal mode copula is not (radially) symmetric. Moreover, $U_{2}$ monotonically increases in $U_{1}$ for $U_{1} \leq \frac {1}{2}$ but decreases in $U_{1}$ for $U_{1} \geq \frac {1}{2}$ . Thus, the copula represents a case of nonmonotonic dependence that motivates me, as I explained in Section 1. In fact, if we rotate the plot clockwise (counterclockwise) 90 degrees, it resembles the right (left) panel of Figure 1. Finally, the bottom-right panel addresses the case where $\theta = 0.304, \kappa _{1}= 2,$ and $\kappa _{2} = 2$ . This normal mode copula is (radially) symmetric but has nonmonotonic dependence.

Figure 5 Example plots of normal mode copulas.

If we regard $u_{1}$ as the position along an open pipe (such as a flute) with unit length and $u_{2}$ as time, the displacement of a standing sound wave with one frequency at position $u_{1}$ and time $u_{2}$ resembles $c_{\mathrm {NM}} (u_{1}, u_{2})$ .Footnote 12 Importantly, if $\kappa _{1}$ were not an integer, the corresponding sound wave would not form a standing wave and would not resonate, thus dissipating immediately. In general, this kind of standing wave is called the normal mode. This is why I name $C_{\mathrm {NM}}$ the normal mode copula.

3 Application

3.1 Overview

This section intends to showcase the usefulness of normal mode copulas by reanalyzing Chiba et al. (Reference Chiba, Martin and Stevenson2015, hereafter, “CMS”), who also use a copula.Footnote 13 CMS focus on two outcomes of (coalition) government formation and duration. Scholars have studied what factors affect either outcome. One problem is that these two outcomes are interrelated, and failure to consider simultaneity leads to selection bias in estimating the model. For instance, if a government would not remain in power for a long time, say, due to a hidden scandal, it may be less likely to be formed in the first place. If (and probably as) scholars do not observe all confounders (e.g., the hidden scandal) that affect both outcomes or do observe some of them but with measurement error, the resultant estimates will be less efficient and might suffer from omitted variable bias. To address this problem, CMS incorporate a copula into their model and analyze the two outcomes jointly. A remaining concern is that CMS consider only the Gaussian copula. I substitute the normal mode copulas as well as other conventional copulas to show that a normal mode copula is the best.

3.2 Model

To focus on the comparison between the Gaussian copula and other copulas, this subsection introduces a simplified version of the CMS model using my notation.Footnote 14 The units of observation are a (coalition government) formation opportunity $i \in \{1,2,\ldots ,n = 432\}$ and a potential coalition government (combination of parties) $j \in \mathcal {J}_{i} \equiv \{1,2,\ldots ,m_{i}\}$ ( $\sum _{i} m_{i} = 95,576$ ). For each i, we have two outcome variables. The first outcome is a realized government, $Y_{1, i} \in \mathcal {J}_{i}$ . The second outcome is the duration of the government from its inception to its termination, $Y_{2, i} \in (0, \bar {y}_{i}]$ , where $\bar {y}_{i}$ is the constitutional interelection period. Unless a government ends for political reasons (replacement by another government without an election or dissolution of the legislature followed by an early election), I regard the government’s duration as censored.Footnote 15

CMS use a conditional logit model to explain government formation. We denote a covariate vector by $\boldsymbol {z}_{1, ij}$ and the corresponding coefficient vector by $\boldsymbol {\theta }_{1}$ . Specifically, $\boldsymbol {z}_{1, ij}$ is composed of Minority Government, Status Quo Government, and dozens of party dummy variables.Footnote 16 The probability that government $g \in \mathcal {J}_{i}$ is formed is modeled as

$$ \begin{align*} \Pr(Y_{1, i} = g) & = \frac{\exp(\boldsymbol{z}^{\prime}_{1, ig} \boldsymbol{\theta}_{1})}{\sum_{j \in \mathcal{J}_{i}} \exp(\boldsymbol{z}^{\prime}_{1, ij} \boldsymbol{\theta}_{1})} \\ & \equiv G(g \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{1, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{1}), \end{align*} $$

where $\boldsymbol {z}_{1, i} \equiv (\boldsymbol {z}_{1, i1}^{\prime }, \boldsymbol {z}_{1, i2}^{\prime }, \ldots , \boldsymbol {z}_{1, i m_{i}}^{\prime })^{\prime }$ . In my understanding, CMS implicitly assume that when a latent utility variable $X_{1, i}$ is smaller than $\overline {x}_{1, i} \equiv F_{1}^{-1} \{G(g \mid \boldsymbol {z}_{1, i}, \boldsymbol {\theta }_{1})\}$ , we observe $Y_{1, i} = g$ .Footnote 17

CMS’s main model assumes that the government duration follows a Weibull distribution, $F_{2}(t \mid \theta _{2, \mathrm {inv.scale}}, \theta _{2, \mathrm {shape}})$ , where $\theta _{2, \mathrm {inv.scale}}$ is the inverse scale parameter and $\theta _{2, \mathrm {shape}}$ is the shape parameter. We denote the latent time variable by $X_{2, i}$ , another covariate vector by $\boldsymbol {z}_{2, i}$ , and the corresponding coefficient vector by $\boldsymbol {\theta }_{2, \mathrm {coef}}$ . To be concrete, I include Minority and Polarization Index in $\boldsymbol {z}_{2, i}$ .Footnote 18 The probability density that the length of the duration is t is modeled as

$$ \begin{align*} p(X_{2, i} = t) = f_{2}(t \mid \theta_{2, \mathrm{inv.scale}}, \theta_{2, \mathrm{shape}}), \end{align*} $$

where $\theta _{2, \mathrm {inv.scale}} = \exp (- \boldsymbol {z}^{\prime }_{2, i} \boldsymbol {\theta }_{2, \mathrm {coef}})$ .

Let $W_{i}$ be the censoring indicator. If the duration ends for political reasons at $t < \bar {y}_{i}$ , we observe $W_{i} = 0$ , $Y_{1, i} = g$ , and $Y_{2, i} = X_{2, i} = t$ , and the mixed joint density is

(5) $$ \begin{align} p(Y_{1, i} = g, Y_{2, i} = t) & = \Pr ( X_{1, i} \leq \overline{x}_{1, i} \mid X_{2, i} = t ) p(X_{2, i} = t) \nonumber\\ & = F_{1 \mid 2}( \overline{x}_{1, i} \mid X_{2, i} = t) f_{2}(t \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2}) \\ & = C^{\prime}_{1 \mid 2} ( \overline{u}_{1, i} \mid \underline{u}_{2, i}, \theta_{12}) f_{2}(t \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2}),\nonumber \end{align} $$

where $\overline {u}_{1, i} = F_{1}(\overline {x}_{1, i}) = G(g \mid \boldsymbol {z}_{1, i}, \boldsymbol {\theta }_{1})$ , $\underline {u}_{2, i} \equiv F_{2}(t \mid \boldsymbol {z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol {\theta }_{2})$ , $\boldsymbol {\theta }_{2} \equiv (\boldsymbol {\theta }_{2, \mathrm {coef}}^{\prime }, \theta _{2, \mathrm {shape}})^{\prime }$ , $\theta _{12}$ is the parameter of copula C of $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ , and it generally holds that $\Pr (X_{1} \leq x_{1} \mid X_{2} = x_{2}) = \frac {\partial }{\partial u_{2}} C (u_{1}, u_{2}) \equiv C^{\prime }_{1 \mid 2} ( u_{1} \mid u_{2})$ (Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006, 41).

If the duration is censored at t, we observe $W_{i} = 1$ , $Y_{1, i} = g$ , and $Y_{2, i} = t$ but not $X_{2, i}> t$ , and the joint probability is

(6) $$ \begin{align} \Pr(Y_{1, i} = g, Y_{2, i} = t) & = \Pr(X_{1, i} \leq \overline{x}_{1, i}, X_{2, i}> t) \nonumber\\ & = \Pr(X_{1, i} \leq \overline{x}_{1, i}) - \Pr(X_{1, i} \leq \overline{x}_{1, i}, X_{2, i} \leq t) \\ & = F_{1}(\overline{x}_{1, i}) - F_{12}(\overline{x}_{1, i}, t) \nonumber\\ & = \overline{u}_{1, i} - C ( \overline{u}_{1, i}, \underline{u}_{2, i}\mid \theta_{12}).\nonumber \end{align} $$

By multiplying either Equation (5) or (6), we can obtain the total likelihood function,

(7) $$\begin{align} \mathcal{L}_{12} ( \boldsymbol{\theta}_{1}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2}, \theta_{12} \mid \boldsymbol{w}, \boldsymbol{y}_{1}, \boldsymbol{y}_{2}, \boldsymbol{Z}_{1}, \boldsymbol{Z}_{2}) \propto & \prod^{n}_{i = 1} \left\{ C^{\prime}_{1 \mid 2} ( \overline{u}_{1, i} \mid \underline{u}_{2, i}, \theta_{12}) f_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2})\right\}^{I(w_{i} = 0)} \\ & \left\{ \overline{u}_{1, i} - C ( \overline{u}_{1, i}, \underline{u}_{2, i}\mid \theta_{12}) \right\}^{I(w_{i} = 1)},\nonumber \end{align}$$

where $I(\cdot )$ is the dummy indicator function, and maximize it to estimate the parameters, $\boldsymbol {\theta }_{1}, \boldsymbol {\theta }_{2}$ , and $\theta _{12}$ . This is the CMS model.

3.3 Studied Copulas

CMS assume that the copula of $X_{1}$ and $X_{2}$ is a Gaussian copula. My departure from the CMS model starts here. I substitute normal mode copulas. In general, before analysts apply a normal mode copula to any dataset, they have to determine the values of $\kappa _{1}$ and $\kappa _{2}$ , which are model choice indicators rather than parameters to be estimated. In my case, I explore $\kappa _{1}, \kappa _{2} \in \{1,2,3,4\}$ . I also consider the following four conventional copulas: FGM, AMH, Clayton, and Frank. The three associated copulas of AMH and Clayton copulas are also studied.

For the purpose of comparison, I analyze the “separate” model of formation and duration by maximizing each of the following likelihood functions:

(8) $$\begin{align} \mathcal{L}_{1} ( \boldsymbol{\theta}_{1} \mid \boldsymbol{y}_{1}, \boldsymbol{Z}_{1}) & \propto \prod^{n}_{i = 1} G(y_{1, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{1, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{1}),\quad\quad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad \end{align}$$
(9) $$\begin{align} \mathcal{L}_{2} ( \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2} \mid \boldsymbol{w}, \boldsymbol{y}_{2}, \boldsymbol{Z}_{2}) & \propto \prod^{n}_{i = 1} \left\{ f_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2}) \right\}^{I(w_{i} = 0)} \left\{ 1 - F_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2}) \right\}^{I(w_{i} = 1)}. \end{align}$$

I also analyze another duration model where I include the predicted probability of formation ( $\hat {\overline {u}}_{1, i}$ , hereafter, “Formation Probability”), which is estimated by using the formation model (Equation (8)), as a covariate:

(10) $$\begin{align} \mathcal{L}^{*}_{2} ( \boldsymbol{\theta}^{*}_{2} \mid \boldsymbol{w}, \boldsymbol{y}_{2}, \boldsymbol{Z}_{2}, {\hat{\overline{\boldsymbol{u}}}_{1}}) \propto \prod^{n}_{i = 1} \left\{ f_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \hat{\overline{u}}_{1, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}^{*}_{2}) \right\}^{I(w_{i} = 0)} \left\{ 1 - F_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \hat{\overline{u}}_{1, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}^{*}_{2}) \right\}^{I(w_{i} = 1)}. \end{align}$$

If the relationship between formation and duration is monotonic, this “two-step” model should work.Footnote 19 Note that the separate and two-step models are effectively equivalent to the CMS model with the product copula ( $C_{I}$ ), which has no parameter, because $C^{\prime }_{I, 1 \mid 2} (u_{1} \mid u_{2}) = u_{1}$ and Equation (7) becomes

$$ \begin{align*} & \prod^{n}_{i = 1} \left\{ C^{\prime}_{I, 1 \mid 2} ( \overline{u}_{1, i} \mid \underline{u}_{2, i}) f_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2})\right\}^{I(w_{i} = 0)} \left\{ \overline{u}_{1, i} - C_{I} ( \overline{u}_{1, i}, \underline{u}_{2, i}) \right\}^{I(w_{i} = 1)} \\ =& \prod^{n}_{i = 1} \left\{ \overline{u}_{1, i} f_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2})\right\}^{I(w_{i} = 0)} \left\{ \overline{u}_{1, i} - \overline{u}_{1, i} \underline{u}_{2, i} \right\}^{I(w_{i} = 1)} \\ =& \prod^{n}_{i = 1} \underbrace{G(y_{1, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{1, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{1})}_{\textrm{formation}} \underbrace{\left\{ f_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2})\right\}^{I(w_{i} = 0)} \left\{ 1 - F_{2}(y_{2, i} \mid \boldsymbol{z}_{2, i}, \boldsymbol{\theta}_{2})\right\}^{I(w_{i} = 1)}}_{\textrm{duration}}. \end{align*} $$

If copula models improve the model fit, we can alleviate bias due to unobserved confounders and root mean squared error (CMS, Braumoeller et al. Reference Braumoeller, Marra, Radice and Bradshaw2018). I also expect that a copula model that fits the data better leads to smaller standard errors because the copula model takes greater advantage of the information about formation ( $X_{1}$ ) in estimating the parameters about duration ( $X_{2}$ ), and thus the conditional variance of duration given formation is smaller.

3.4 Results

Table 1 reports the Akaike information criterion (AIC) for each copula used in the CMS model.Footnote 20 Each row indicates the model with each copula. In the first and second rows, I report the AICs of the separate and two-step models, respectively, where I sum the AICs of the formation model (Equation (8)) and the duration model (Equation (9) for the separate model and Equation (10) for the two-step model). The AIC of the two-step model is larger than that of the separate model almost by two, which means the predicted probability of formation has little linear relation with duration. Below, all models employ Equation (7). Compared with the separate model, the Gaussian copula model CMS used (third row) worsens the AIC. In the next 16 rows, I display the AICs of normal mode copula models. The normal mode copula model with $\kappa _{1} = 1$ and $\kappa _{2} = 2$ (hereafter, the “NM(1, 2) copula model,” fifth row) has the best (i.e., smallest) AIC. In the last ten rows, I present the AICs of the conventional copula models and their associated copula models. (For the AMH and Clayton copulas, “Original,” “Associate 1,” “Associate 2,” and “Survival” indicate C, $\overline {C}^{(1)}$ , $\overline {C}^{(2)}$ , and $\overline {C}^{(12)}$ (Equation (3)), respectively.) They have almost the same AIC as the two-step model and do not outperform the NM(1, 2) copula model. This is probably because all of these conventional copulas cope with monotonic relationships alone, where in fact, the relation between $\overline {u}_{1, i}$ and $\underline {u}_{2, i}$ is nonmonotonic as shown next.

Table 1 AICs for models using various copulas.

Figure 6 illustrates the scatter plots of estimated $\overline {u}_{1, i}$ ’s (horizontal axis) and $\underline {u}_{2, i}$ ’s (vertical axis). The left and right panels correspond to the Gaussian copula model and the NM(1, 2) copula model, respectively. In each panel, the contour plot of the copula based on the estimate of $\theta _{12}$ is overlaid.Footnote 21 A point indicates a unit that is not censored, where $(U_{1, i}, U_{2, i}) \in \{ (u_{1}, u_{2}) \mid 0 < u_{1} \leq \overline {u}_{1, i}, u_{2} = \underline {u}_{2, i} \}$ . A cross indicates a unit that is censored, where $(U_{1, i}, U_{2, i}) \in \{ (u_{1}, u_{2}) \mid 0 < u_{1} \leq \overline {u}_{1, i}, \underline {u}_{2, i} < u_{2} < 1 \}$ . Clearly, the relationship between $\overline {u}_{1, i}$ and $\underline {u}_{2, i}$ is nonmonotonic. Since I use a simplified CMS model, neither copula model appears to fit the data well. However, units near the right vertical axis are situated in low-density areas of the Gaussian copula model but in high-density areas of the NM(1, 2) copula model. This is likely why the NM(1, 2) copula model achieves the best performance among the studied copulas in Table 1.

Figure 6 Scatter plots of ${\overline{u}}_{1, i}$ ’s and ${\underline{u}}_{2, i}$ ’s with contour plots of the estimated copula. $n = 432$ .

Table 2 presents the estimation results of the parameters.Footnote 22 The first two rows display covariate coefficients of the formation model ( $\boldsymbol {\theta }_{1}$ except for dozens of party fixed effects). The third to sixth rows indicate covariate coefficients of the duration model (including intercept, $\boldsymbol {\theta }_{2, \mathrm {coef}}$ ), while the last row represents the logged shape parameter of the duration model ( $\log (\theta _{\mathrm {shape}})$ ). The first and second columns concern the separate model (Equations (8) and (9), respectively), while the third and fourth columns correspond to the two-step model (Equations (8) and (10), respectively; thus, the first column is the same as the third column). In the fifth and sixth columns, I show the results of the Gaussian copula model and the NM(1, 2) copula model, respectively (Equation (7)). In each cell, the entry is the estimate with the standard error in parentheses.

Table 2 Results of parameter estimation.

Note: Cell entries are estimates (with standard errors in parentheses). $n = 432$ .

As expected, all standard errors are smaller in the NM(1, 2) copula model than in the separate model, the two-step model, and the Gaussian copula model, except for that of the Duration Dependence parameter. In the case of Minority Government as a formation covariate, the standard error of the NM(1, 2) copula model is reduced by 34% compared with that of the separate model. The coefficient of Formation Probability in the two-step model is close to zero and not significant, although the NM(1, 2) copula model performs well. (Recall also that the two-step model does not improve the AIC compared with the separate model in Table 1.) This implies that the probability of formation affects duration not in a monotonic way but in a nonmonotonic way. Point estimates are not particularly different across models in the simplified models. However, if I use the full CMS model, they are so distinct that coefficient estimates are statistically significantly different from zero in one model but not in another (Supplementary Material).

4 Conclusion

This study sheds light on an understudied family of copulas, normal mode copulas. I apply dozens of copulas to a dataset of government formation and duration to show that the normal mode copula achieves higher performance than other conventional copulas.

There are several directions for future research. In a companion paper (Fukumoto Reference Fukumoto2023a), I have characterized the properties of normal mode copulas such as monotonicity and measures of association. It is also promising to explore the properties of Chesneau’s (Reference Chesneau2021) copulas (Equation (4)) and its multivariate version. Scholars can apply normal mode copulas to various data to find interesting dependence structures. I hope normal mode copulas become a helpful tool to analyze mutually dependent variables in political science.

Acknowlegments

Earlier versions of this article were presented on November 5, 2013, June 23, 2015, and September 16, 2022, at the Institute of Statistical Mathematics, Tokyo, Japan, and on January 6–7, 2023, at the 10th Asian Political Methodology Meeting, National University of Singapore. I thank Toshikazu Kitano and Dean Knox for their helpful comments. I am grateful to Korhan Kocak, Özgür Kıbrıs, David E. Cunningham, Kristian Skrede Gleditsch, Idean Salehyan, Daina Chiba, Lanny W. Martin, and Randolph T. Stevenson for enabling me to reanalyze their datasets. I also appreciate American Journal Experts for providing proofreading service. I am entirely responsible for the scientific content of the article, and the article adheres to the journal’s authorship policy.

Funding

This work was supported by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (Grant No. KAKENHI JP19K21683) and the Gakushuin University's Computer Centre (no grant number).

Conflicts of Interest

There are no conflicts of interest to disclose.

Data Availability Statement

The replication materials for this article can be found in Fukumoto (Reference Fukumoto2023b) at https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/X94ITA.

Supplementary Material

For supplementary material accompanying this paper, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/pan.2023.45.

Footnotes

Edited by: Jeff Gill

1 Furthermore, analysts have to integrate a latent variable out of the selection model.

2 Sartori (Reference Sartori2003) modifies Heckman’s sample selection model by using the Fréchet upper bound copula in effect, although she does not mention a copula. Gomes et al. (Reference Gomes, Radice, Brenes and Marra2019) explicitly incorporate copulas in their sample selection model.

3 I obtained the dataset from one of the authors, Korhan Kocak, through personal communication on March 23, 2023. The replication materials for this article can be found at Fukumoto (Reference Fukumoto2023b).

4 I downloaded the replication materials of Cunningham et al. (Reference Cunningham, Gleditsch and Salehyan2009) (the original publication version, not the latest updated version) from http://jcr.sagepub.com/content/53/4/570/suppl/DC1 on July 6, 2012. I preprocessed the dataset in the same way as Fukumoto (Reference Fukumoto2015) did.

5 In this case, the two-increasing condition is equivalent to $c (u_{1}, u_{2}) \geq 0$ .

6 In Figures 2 and 3, the value of $\theta $ is set so that the Kendall rank correlation (Nelsen Reference Nelsen2006, 161 and 164, Trivedi and Zimmer Reference Trivedi and Zimmer2007, 16 and 22), a measure of association, is equal to 0.1, and thus copulas are comparable. I conduct all analyses in the statistical computational environment R (R Core Team 2022). For Gaussian copulas, I employ the mvtnorm library (Genz et al. Reference Genz2021).

7 In Figures 26, the shade in the contour plot is decided according to the maximum densities of each panel and thus is not comparable across panels.

8 The values of $\theta $ are equal to 0.45, 0.381, 0.222, and 0.907 in the order of the mentioned copulas, respectively. For deriving $\theta $ of the Frank copula, I utilize the gsl library (version 2.1-7.1 Hankin Reference Hankin2006).

9 The Kendall rank correlation is equal to $0.1, -0.1, -0.1$ , and $0.1$ for $c, \overline {c}^{(1)}, \overline {c}^{(2)}$ , and $\overline {c}^{(12)}$ , respectively.

10 To be accurate, Chesneau (Reference Chesneau2021) introduces the multivariate version of this copula.

11 The Kendall rank correlation is equal to $0.1, -0.1, 0$ , and $0$ for the first to fourth panels, respectively. Note that the Kendall rank correlation can be equal to 0 when the two variables are not independent of each other and the dependence between these two variables is nonmonotonic.

12 Strictly speaking, the displacement is $\theta \cos (u_{1} \kappa _{1} \pi ) \cos (u_{2} \kappa _{2} \pi )$ , where $|\theta |$ can be larger than one, $X_{2}$ is a circular variable, and $\kappa _{2}$ is an even integer.

13 I downloaded the replication materials (Chiba, Martin, and Stevenson Reference Chiba, Martin and Stevenson2014) on March 14, 2023. The dataset covers 17 European countries, 1945 to 2011. For details, see CMS, f.n. 11 (p.51).

14 I thank a reviewer for suggesting simplifying the CMS model. In the Supplementary Material, I present reanalyses of the full CMS model.

15 According to CMS, “an observation is right-censored if the government was still in office as of December 31, 2011 (the cutoff date for our sample), or if it terminated for any of the following reasons: the occurrence of a regularly scheduled election, a technical resignation required for constitutional reasons, or the death of the prime minister. …Of our 432 governments, 89 are right-censored for these reasons” (p. 52). CMS employ the competing risks approach where they differentiate termination due to replacement from termination due to dissolution.

16 Minority is equal to one if government parties do not collectively control a parliamentary majority, zero otherwise (CMS, 53). Status Quo Government is equal to one if the potential coalition government is the same as the pervious government, zero otherwise (Martin and Stevenson Reference Martin and Stevenson2010, 504). The intercept is not included in $\boldsymbol {z}_{1, ij}$ . CMS include 20 additional variables. I retain Minority because CMS show that it affects both formation and duration in a statistically significant manner. I retain Status Quo Government for the exclusion restriction; CMS (53–54) argue that it affects formation but not duration. See also the Supplementary Material. As for party dummy variables, see Martin and Stevenson (Reference Martin and Stevenson2010, 512–514).

17 For details, see the Supplementary Material. In other words, $X_{1, i}$ is integrated out: $\Pr (Y_{1, i} = g) = \int ^{\overline {x}_{1, i}}_{-\infty } f_{1}(x_{1}) d x_{1}$ .

18 Polarization Index measures the presence of anti-establishment parties in the legislature (for details, see CMS, 53). The intercept is included in $\boldsymbol {z}_{2, i}$ . CMS add four variables. I retain Polarization Index for the purpose of the exclusion restriction; CMS (53–54) argue that it affects duration but not formation.

19 I thank a reviewer for suggesting the two-step model.

20 Braumoeller et al. (Reference Braumoeller, Marra, Radice and Bradshaw2018) and Fukumoto (Reference Fukumoto2015) also select the best among copulas in terms of AIC.

21 $\hat {\theta }_{12} = 0.070$ for the Gaussian copula and $\hat {\theta }_{12} = 1.000$ for the NM(1, 2) copula. The corresponding Kendall rank correlations are 0.045 and 0, respectively, which implies little linear correlation between formation and duration.

References

Braumoeller, B. F., Marra, G., Radice, R., and Bradshaw, A. E.. 2018. “Flexible Causal Inference for Political Science.” Political Analysis 26 (1): 5471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chesneau, C. 2021. “On New Types of Multivariate Trigonometric Copulas.” Applied Mathematics 1 (1): 317.Google Scholar
Chiba, D., Martin, L. W., and Stevenson, R. T.. 2014. Replication Data for: A Copula Approach to the Problem of Selection Bias in Models of Government Survival. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/26966, Harvard Dataverse, V2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiba, D., Martin, L. W., and Stevenson, R. T.. 2015. “A Copula Approach to the Problem of Selection Bias in Models of Government Survival.” Political Analysis 23 (1): 4258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiba, D., Metternich, N. W., and Ward, M. D.. 2015. “Every Story Has a Beginning, Middle, and an End (But Not Always in That Order): Predicting Duration Dynamics in a Unified Framework.” Political Science Research and Methods 3 (3): 515541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cunningham, D. E., Gleditsch, K. S., and Salehyan, I.. 2009. “It Takes Two: A Dyadic Analysis of Civil War Duration and Outcome.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 53 (4): 570597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukumoto, K. 2015. “What Happens Depends on When It Happens: Copula-Based Ordered Event History Analysis of Civil War Duration and Outcome.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 110 (509): 8392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukumoto, K. 2023a. Not Linearly Correlated, But Dependent: A Family of Normal Mode Copulas. arXiv:arXiv:2308.03541 [stat.ME].Google Scholar
Fukumoto, K. 2023b. Replication Data for: Normal Mode Copulas for Nonmonotonic Dependence. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/X94ITA, Harvard Dataverse, V1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Genz, A., et al. 2021. “mvtnorm: Multivariate Normal and t Distributions.” R Package Version 1.1–3. http://CRAN.R-project.org/package=mvtnorm Google Scholar
Gomes, M., Radice, R., Brenes, J. C., and Marra, G.. 2019. “Copula Selection Models for Non-Gaussian Outcomes That Are Missing Not at Random.” Statistics in Medicine 38 (3): 480496.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hankin, R. K. S. 2006. “Special Functions in R: Introducing the gsl Package.” R News 6 (4).Google Scholar
Hofert, M., Kojadinovic, I., Maechler, M., and Yan, J.. 2018. Elements of Copula Modeling with R. Gewerbestrasse: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kocak, K., and Kıbrıs, Ö.. 2023. “Social Media and Press Freedom.” British Journal of Political Science 53 (1): 140162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, D. X. 2000. “On Default Correlation.” Journal of Fixed Income 9 (4): 4354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, L. W., and Stevenson, R. T.. 2010. “The Conditional Impact of Incumbency on Government Formation.” American Political Science Review 104 (3): 503518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mason, T. D., Weingarten, J. P. Jr., and Fett, P. J.. 1999. “Win, Lose, or Draw: Predicting the Outcome of Civil Wars.” Political Research Quarterly 52 (2): 239268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelsen, R. B. 2006. An Introduction to Copulas, 2nd. ed. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
R Core Team. 2022. R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. Version 4.1.3. Vienna: R Foundation for Statistical Computing.Google Scholar
Sartori, A. E. 2003. “An Estimator for Some Binary-Outcome Selection Models without Exclusion Restrictions.” Political Analysis 11 (2): 111138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schafer, J., Opgen-Rhein, R., Zuber, V., Miika Ahdesmaki, A., Silva, P. D., and Strimmer, K.. 2021. “Corpcor: Efficient Estimation of Covariance and (Partial) Correlation.” R Package Version 1.6.10. https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=corpcor Google Scholar
Trivedi, P. K., and Zimmer, D. M.. 2007. Copula Modeling: An Introduction for Practioners. Boston: Publishers Inc.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 Empirical examples of nonmonotonic dependence. (a) Each dot corresponds to a country in a year, 2000 to 2015 ($n=2,560$). (b) Each dot corresponds a civil war, 1946 to 2003 ($n=267$).

Figure 1

Figure 2 Bivariate normal distribution: joint distribution, marginal distributions, and copula.

Figure 2

Figure 3 Example plots of conventional copulas.

Figure 3

Figure 4 Example plots of associated Clayton copulas.

Figure 4

Figure 5 Example plots of normal mode copulas.

Figure 5

Table 1 AICs for models using various copulas.

Figure 6

Figure 6 Scatter plots of ${\overline{u}}_{1, i}$’s and ${\underline{u}}_{2, i}$’s with contour plots of the estimated copula. $n = 432$.

Figure 7

Table 2 Results of parameter estimation.

Supplementary material: File

Fukumoto supplementary material

Fukumoto supplementary material
Download Fukumoto supplementary material(File)
File 382.3 KB