Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T12:24:12.777Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The International Wanderings of a Liberal Idea, or Why Liberals Can Learn to Stop Worrying and Love the Balance of Power

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 November 2007

Deborah Boucoyannis
Affiliation:
Harvard University, E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

Scholars in international relations have failed to note a paradox about the balance of power: the concept of checks and balances and equilibria underlie classical Liberal constitutional and economic theory. Interest balancing interest lies at the core of the Liberal solution to the problem of anarchy, power, and human nature, whether in politics, economics, or the international sphere. Liberal scholars have adopted instead a rationalist utilitarian or a normative democratic approach. At the same time, Realists in international relations predict a balance, which realist scholars in domestic politics, like Schattschneider, have effectively questioned. This intellectual confusion denies Liberal theory a robust view of international politics, not least because the balancing principle is erroneously rejected as conservative. The confusion also undermines the coherence of Realist theory, which has hitherto tried to accommodate opposing predictions (balance of power and power concentrations) under one paradigm. I offer an explanation of how this conflation of theories arose. Conflating Liberalism with idealism leaves Realism as the only prudent alternative in international politics. The relation between the two theories is not zero-sum: both capture important aspects of international dynamics, and each can ignore the other only at serious cost.Deborah Boucoyannis is Lecturer in Social Studies at Harvard University ([email protected]). For comments and suggestions over the time the article has been in gestation, the author thanks Bear Braumoeller, Tim Crawford, Daniel Drezner, Nisha Fazal, David Grewal, Arman Grigorian, Mark Haas, Russ Hamilton, Michael Heaney, Jacques Hymans, Seth Jones, Andreas Kalyvas, Jacob Levy, Jack Levy, John Mearsheimer, Jennifer Mitzen, Kevin Narizny, Jacob Schiff, Jack Snyder, Kenneth Waltz, Alex Wendt, Bill Wohlforth, and the participants at the Political Theory and PISP workshops at the University of Chicago. Special thanks are due to Monica Toft, John Ikenberry, and Jennifer Hochschild for their support of the article; it was mostly written with the generous support of the Olin Institute for Strategic Studies at Harvard University.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© 2007 American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and James Robinson. 2005. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Alchian, Armen. 1950. Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy 58 (3): 21121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values. New York: Wiley.
Arrow, Kenneth, and Gerard Debreu. 1954. Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica 22 (3): 26590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashcraft, Richard. 1986. Revolutionary Politics and Locke's Two Treatises of Government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Ashcraft, Richard. 1993. Liberal political theory and working-class radicalism in nineteenth-century england. Political Theory 21 (2): 24972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashley, Richard. 1983. Three modes of economism. International Studies Quarterly 27 (4): 46396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, David, and Jeffrey Wright. 1994. Counteractive lobbying. American Journal of Political Science 38 (1): 2544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhouse, Roger, and John Creedy. 1999. From Classical Economics to the Theory of the Firm. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Bailyn, Bernard. 1992. The Ideological Origins of the American Revolution. Enl. ed. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Baldwin, David. 1993. Neoliberalism, neorealism, and world politics. In Neorealism and Neoliberalism: the Contemporary Debate. New York: Columbia University Press.
Barry, Brian. 1995. Justice as Impartiality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Barry, Brian, and Russell Hardin. 1982. Rational Man and Irrational Society? An Introduction and Sourcebook. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.
Bentham, Jeremy. 1988. A Fragment on Government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bentley, Arthur. 1908. The Process of Government. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Berki, R.N. 1981. On Political Realism. London: Dent.
Berlin, Isaiah. 2002. Liberty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Blaug, Mark. 1997. Economic Theory in Retrospect. 5th ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Blaug, Mark. 2001. No history of ideas, please, we're economists. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 (1): 14564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohman, James, and Matthias Lutz-Bachmann, eds. 1997. Perpetual Peace: Essays on Kant's Cosmopolitan Ideal. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Boucoyannis, Deborah. 2005. “Land, Courts, and Parliaments: The Hidden Sinews of Power in the Emergence of Constitutionalism.” Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago.
Bull, Hedley. 1995. The Anarchical Society: A Study of Order in World Politics. 2d ed. New York: Columbia University Press.
Butterfield, Herbert. 1966. The Balance of Power. In Diplomatic Investigations, ed. H. Butterfield and M. Wight. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Carr, Edward. 1946. The Twenty Years' Crisis, 1919–1939: An Introduction to the Study of International Relations. London: Macmillan.
Cavallar, Georg. 1999. Kant and the Theory and Practice of International Right. Cardiff: University of Wales Press.
Cederman, Lars-Erik. 1997. Emergent Actors in World Politics: How States and Nations Develop and Dissolve. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Cederman, Lars-Erik. 2001. Back to Kant: Reinterpreting the democratic peace as a macrohistorical learning process. American Political Science Review 95 (1): 1531.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica 4 (16): 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald. 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3 (1): 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald. 1976. Adam Smith's view of man. Journal of Law and Economics 19 (3, 1776: The Revolution in Social Thought): 52946.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald. 1992. The institutional structure of production. American Economic Review 82 (4): 71319.Google Scholar
Condorcet, Jean. 1795. Outlines of an Historical View of the Progress of the Human Mind. London: Printed for J. Johnson.
Copeland, Dale. 2000. The Origins of Major War. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Dahl, Robert. 1982. Dilemmas of Pluralist Democracy: Autonomy vs. Control. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Dessler, David. 1989. What's at stake in the agent-structure debate? International Organization 43 (3): 44173.Google Scholar
Dodd, Charles. 1739. A display of French politicks evincing, from antient history and modern facts, that the Bourbon race has ever had in view, the acquist of universal monarchy.by a true Briton. London: Printed for T. Cooper. Microfilm.
Doyle, Michael. 1986. Liberalism and world politics. American Political Science Review 80 (4): 115169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doyle, Michael. 1997. Ways of War and Peace: Realism, Liberalism, and Socialism. New York: Norton.
Edgeworth, Francis. 1897. The pure theory of taxation. Economic Journal 7 (25): 4670.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1998. A Plea for Mechanisms. In Social Mechanisms: An Analytical Approach to Social Theory, ed. P. Hedström and R. Swedberg. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Elster, Jon, and Rune Slagstad, eds. 1988. Constitutionalism and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Fearon, James. 1994. Signaling versus the balance of power and interests: An empirical test of a crisis bargaining model. Journal of Conflict Resolution 38 (2): 23669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James. 1995. Rationalist explanations for war. International Organization 49 (3): 379414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James. 1998a. Bargaining, enforcement, and international cooperation. International Organization 52 (2): 269305.Google Scholar
Fearon, James. 1998b. Domestic politics, foreign policy, and theories of international relations. Annual Review of Political Science 1: 289313.Google Scholar
Fleischacker, Samuel. 1999. A Third Concept of Liberty: Judgment and Freedom in Kant and Adam Smith. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Fleischacker, Samuel. 2004. On Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations: A Philosophical Companion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Frieden, Jeffry, and Ronald Rogowski. 1996. The impact of the international economy on national policies: An analytical overview. In Internationalization and Domestic Politics, ed. R.O. Keohane and H.V. Milner. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1982. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1956. American Capitalism: The Concept of Countervailing Power. Rev. ed. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Galston, William. 1988. Liberal virtues. American Political Science Review 82 (4): 127790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galston, William. 1995. Two concepts of liberalism. Ethics 105 (3): 51634.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gentz, Friedrich. 1806. Fragments upon the Balance of Power in Europe. London: M. Peltier.
Giddens, Anthony. 1984. The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Gilpin, Robert. 1981. War and Change in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Gintis, Herbert. 2006. The dynamics of general equilibrium. Economic Journal 116 (514).Google Scholar
Grampp, William. 1960. The Manchester School of Economics. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Green, T.H. 1895. Lectures on the Principles of Political Obligation. London: Longmans Green.
Greenwald, Bruce, and Jospeh Stiglitz. 1986. Externalities in economies with imperfect information and incomplete markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 101: 22964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guicciardini, Francesco. 1964. History of Italy and History of Florence. New York: Washington Square Press.
Haakonssen, Knut. 1981. The Science of a Legislator: The Natural Jurisprudence of David Hume and Adam Smith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Haas, Ernst. 1953. The balance of power: Prescription, concept, or propaganda. World Politics 5 (4): 44277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Habermas, Jürgen. 1989. The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere: An Inquiry into a Category of Bourgeois Society. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Halévy, Ély. 1928. The Growth of Philosophic Radicalism. New York: Macmillan.
Hansen, John Mark. 1991. Gaining Access: Congress and the Farm Lobby, 1919–1981. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Harrison, Ewan. 2002. Waltz, Kant and systemic approaches to international relations. International Studies Quarterly 28 (1): 14362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartz, Louis. 1955. The Liberal Tradition in America. 1st ed. New York: Harcourt Brace.
Haslam, Jonathan. 2002. No Virtue Like Necessity: Realist Thought in International Relations since Machiavelli. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Herz, John. 1951. Political Realism and Political Idealism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hirschman, Albert. 1977. The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before its Triumph. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Hobhouse, L.T. 1906. Morals in Evolution; A Study in Comparative Ethics. London: Chapman and Hall ltd.
Hobhouse, L.T. 1911. Liberalism. New York: H. Holt.
Hoffmann, Stanley. 1987. Liberalism and international affairs. In Janus and Minerva: Essays in the Theory and Practice of International Politics. Boulder: Westview Press.
Holmes, Stephen. 1995. Passions and Constraint: On the Theory of Liberal Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Holmes, Stephen, and Cass Sunstein. 1999. The Cost of Rights: Why Liberty Depends on Taxes. 1st ed. New York: W.W. Norton.
Hont, Istvan, and Michael Ignatieff. 1983. Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hume, David. 1994. Of the first principles of government. In Political Essays, ed. K. Haakonssen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Huntington, Samuel. 1981. American Politics: The Promise of Disharmony. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, Belknap Press.
Iggers, Georg, and Konrad von Moltke. 1973. Introduction. In The Theory and Practice of History, ed. G.G. Iggers and K.v. Moltke. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.
Ingrao, Bruno, and Giorgio Israel. 1991. The Invisible Hand: Economic Equilibrium in the History of Science. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Jervis, Robert. 1998. Realism in the study of world politics. International Organization 52 (4): 97191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. 2003. Realism, neoliberalism, and cooperation: Understanding the debate. In Progress in International Relations Theory: Appraising the Field, ed. C. Elman and M.F. Elman. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Kalyvas, Andreas, and Ira Katznelson. 2001. The rhetoric of the market: Adam Smith on recognition, speech and exchange. Review of Politics 63 (3): 54979.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kant, Immanuel. 1983a. On the proverb: That may be true in theory, but is of no practical use (1795). In Perpetual Peace. Indianapolis: Hackett.
Kant, Immanuel. 1983b. Perpetual Peace, and Other Essays on Politics, History, and Morals. Ed. T. Humphrey. Indianapolis: Hackett.
Kant, Immanuel. 1983c. To perpetual peace: A philosophical sketch (1795). In Perpetual Peace. Indianapolis: Hackett.
Katzenstein, Peter, Robert Keohane, and Stephen Krasner. 1998. International Organization and the study of world politics. International Organization 52 (4): 64585.Google Scholar
Katznelson, Ira. 2005. When Affirmative Action Was White: An Untold History of Racial Inequality in Twentieth-Century America. 1st ed. New York: W.W. Norton.
Keohane, Robert. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Keohane, Robert. 1986. Theory of world politics: Structural realism and beyond. In Neorealism and Its Critics. New York: Columbia University Press.
Keohane, Robert. 1990. International liberalism reconsidered. In The Economic Limits to Modern Politics, ed. J. Dunn. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Keohane, Robert. 2001. Governance in a partially globalized world. American Political Science Review 95 (1): 113.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert, and Lisa Martin. 1995. The promise of institutionalist theory. International Security 20 (1): 3951.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Meynard. 1926. The End of Laissez-Faire. London: L. & V. Woolf.
Kloppenberg, James. 1987. The virtues of liberalism: Christianity, republicanism, and ethics in early American political discourse. Journal of American History 74 (1): 933.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kramnick, Isaac, ed. 1987. Editor's Introduction. In The Federalist Papers. Hammondsworth: Penguin.
Krasner, Stephen. 1976. State power and the structure of international trade. World Politics XXVIII (3): 31747.Google Scholar
Laitin, David. 2002. Comparative politics: The state of the subdiscipline. In Political Science: The State of the Discipline, ed. I. Katznelson and H.V. Milner. New York: W.W. Norton.
Lake, David, and Robert Powell. 1999. International relations: A strategic-choice approach. In Strategic Choice and International Relations, Edited by D.A. Lake, and R. Powell. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Legro, Jeffrey, and Andrew Moravcsik. 1999. Is anybody still a realist? International Security 24 (2): 555.Google Scholar
Levy, Jack. 2001. Do great powers balance against hegemonic threats? In Realism and the Balance of Power, ed. J.A. Vasquez and C. Elman. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Lindblom, Charles. 1977. Politics and Markets: the World's Political-Economic Systems. New York: Basic Books.
Locke, John. 1988. Two Treatises of Government. Ed. P. Laslett. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lowi, Theodore 1979. The End of Liberalism. 2d ed. New York: Norton.
Machiavelli, Niccolò. 1970. The Discourses. Ed. B.R. Crick. Hammondsworth: Penguin Books.
Machiavelli, Niccolò. 1988. Machiavelli: The Prince. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mackinder, Halford. 1919. Democratic Ideals and Reality. New York: Henry Holt.
Madison, James, Alexander Hamilton, and John Jay. 1987 [1788]. The Federalist Papers. Ed. I. Kramnick. Hammondsworth: Penguin.
Mandeville, Bernard. 1924a [1714]. Fable of the Bees: Or, Private Vices, Publick Benefits. Ed. F.B. Kaye. 2 vols. Vol. 1. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Mandeville, Bernard. 1924b [1714]. Fable of the Bees: Or, Private Vices, Publick Benefits. Ed. F.B. Kaye. 2 vols. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Mansbridge, Jane. 1990. Beyond Self-Interest. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Martin, Lisa, and Beth Simmons. 1998. Theories and empirical studies of international institutions. International Organization 52 (4): 72986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFarland, Andrew. S. 2004. Neopluralism: The Evolution of Political Process Theory. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.
Mearsheimer, John. 1994/5. The false promise of international institutions. International Security 19 (3): 549.Google Scholar
Mearsheimer, John. 2001. The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: W.W. Norton.
Meinecke, Friedrich. 1957. Machiavellism: The Doctrine of Raison d'État and its Place in Modern History. London: Routledge and K. Paul.
Milner, Helen. 1998. Rationalist approaches—rationalizing politics: The emerging synthesis of international, American, and comparative politics. International Organization 52 (4): 75986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. 1989. More Heat than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Moe, Terry. 2005. Power and political institutions. Perspectives on Politics 3 (2): 21533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montesquieu, Charles. 1989 [1748]. The Spirit of the Laws. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Moore, Barrington. 1967. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Boston: Beacon Press.
Moravcsik, Andrew. 1997a. Taking preferences seriously: A liberal theory of international politics. International Organization 51 (4): 51353.Google Scholar
Moravcsik, Andrew. 1997b. Taking preferences seriously: A liberal theory of international politics. In Theory and Structure in International Political Economy, ed. C. Lipson and B.J. Cohen. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Morgan, Glyn. 2005. The Idea of a European Superstate: Public Justification and European Integration. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Morgenthau, Hans. 1946. Scientific Man vs. Power Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Morgenthau, Hans. 1948. Politics among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace. New York: A.A. Knopf.
Morrow, James. 1988. Social choice and system structure in world politics. World Politics 41 (1): 7599.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mueller, John. 2001. Capitalism, Democracy, and Ralph's Pretty Good Grocery. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Nelson, Richard, and Sidney Winter. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action; Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Onuf, Nicholas. 1998. The Republican Legacy in International Thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Organski, A.F.K. 1968. World Politics. 2d ed. New York: Knopf.
Organski, A.F.K., and Jacek Kugler. 1980. The War Ledger. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Osiander, Andreas. 1998. Rereading early twentieth-century IR theory: Idealism revisited. International Studies Quarterly 42: 40932.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palan, Ronen, and Brook Blair. 1993. On the idealist origins of the realist theory of international relations. Review of International Studies 19: 38599.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paul, T.V., James Wirtz, and Michael Fortmann, eds. 2004. Balance of Power: Theory and Practice in the 21st Century. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Pigou, Arthur Cecil. 1952. The Economics of Welfare. 4th ed. London: Macmillan.
Pincus, Steven. 1998. Neither Machiavellian moment nor possessive individualism: Commercial society and the defenders of the English commonwealth. American Historical Review 103 (3): 70536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polanyi, Karl. 1962 [1944]. The Great Transformation. Boston: Beacon Press.
Posner, Richard. 2003. Law, Pragmatism, and Democracy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Powell, Robert. 1994. Anarchy in international relations theory: The neorealist-neoliberal debate. International Organization 48 (2): 31344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ranke, Leopold von. 1973. The Theory and Practice of History. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.
Rawls, John. 1996. Political Liberalism. Rev. ed. New York: Columbia University Press.
Riker, William. 1980. Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions. American Political Science Review 74 (2): 43246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rochau, August von. 1859. Grundsatze der Realpolitik angewendet auf die staatlichen Zustande Deutschlands. Stuttgart.
Rose, Gideon. 1998. Neoclassical realism and theories of foreign policy. World Politics 51 (1): 14472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosecrance, Richard. 1963. Action and Reaction in World Politics. Boston: Little Brown.
Rosecrance, Richard. 1986. The Rise of the Trading State: Commerce and Conquest in the Modern World. New York: Basic Books.
Rosecrance, Richard. 2003. Is there a balance of power? In Realism and the Balancing of Power: A New Debate, ed. J.A. Vasquez and C. Elman. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Rosenberg, Justin. 1990. What's the matter with realism? Review of International Studies 16: 285303.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan. 1963. Mandeville and laissez-faire. Journal of the History of Ideas 24 (2): 18396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, Emma. 2001. Economic Sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet, and the Enlightenment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1982. International regimes, transactions, and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization 36 (2, International Regimes): 379415.Google Scholar
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1998. What makes the world hang together? Neo-utilitarianism and the social constructivist challenge. International Organization 52 (4): 85585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russett, Cynthia. 1966. The Concept of Equilibrium in American Social Thought. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Ryan, Alan. 1974. J.S. Mill. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Ryan, Alan. 1993. Liberalism. In A Companion to Contemporary Political Philosophy, ed. R.E. Goodin and P. Pettit. Oxford: Blackwell.
Satz, Deborah, and John Ferejohn. 1994. Rational choice and social theory. Journal of Philosophy 91 (2): 7187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schattschneider, E.E. 1960. The Semisovereign People: A Realist's View of Democracy in America. 1st ed. New York: Holt Rinehart and Winston.
Schlozman, Kay. 1984. What accent the heavenly chorus? Political equality and the American pressure system. Journal of Politics 46 (4): 100632.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, Brian. 1998. Lessons from the past: Reassessing the interwar disciplinary history of international relations. International Studies Quarterly 42: 43359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitt, Carl. 1985. Political Theology: Four Chapters on the Concept of Sovereignty. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Schochet, Gordon. 1979. Constitutionalism, liberalism, and the study of politics. In Constitutionalism, ed. J.R. Pennock and J.W. Chapman. New York: New York University Press.
Schroeder, Paul. 1994a. Historical reality vs. neo-realist theory. International Security 19 (1): 10848.Google Scholar
Schroeder, Paul. 1994b. The Transformation of European Politics 1763–1848. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Schweller, Randall. 1994. Bandwagoning for profit: Bringing the revisionist state back in. International Security 19 (1): 72107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schweller, Randall. 1996. Neo-realism's status quo bias: What security dilemma? Security Studies 5 (3): 90121.Google Scholar
Schweller, Randall, and William Wohlforth. 2000. Power test: Evaluating realism in response to the end of the Cold War. Security Studies 9 (3).Google Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor. 1951. The state of welfare economics. American Economic Review 41 (3): 30315.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor. 1990. The benefits of asymmetric markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4 (1): 13548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1970. The impossibility of a Paretian liberal. Journal of Political Economy 78: 15257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Ian. 1999. Enough of deliberation: Politics is about interests and power. In Deliberative Politics: Essays on Democracy and Disagreement, ed. S. Macedo. New York: Oxford University Press.
Shimko, Keith. 1992. Realism, neorealism, and American liberalism. Review of Politics 54: 281301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shklar, Judith. 1984. Ordinary Vices. Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Shklar, Judith. 1989. The Liberalism of Fear. In Liberalism and the Moral Life, Edited by N.L. Rosenblum. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Smith, Adam. 1976a [1759]. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Ed. A.L. Macfie and D.D. Raphael. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Smith, Adam. 1976b [1776]. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Ed. R.H. Campbell, A.S. Skinner, and W.B. Todd. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Snyder, Jack. 1991. Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Relations. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Spencer, Herbert. 1884. The Man versus the State. London: Williams & Norgate.
Spykman, Nicholas. 1942. America's Strategy in World Politics: The United States and the Balance of Power. New York: Harcourt Brace.
Sterling-Folker, Jennifer. 1997. Realist environment, liberal process, and domestic-level variables. International Studies Quarterly 41 (1): 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George. 1950. The development of utility theory. I. Journal of Political Economy 58 (4): 30727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George. 1959. The politics of political economists. Quarterly Journal of Economics 73 (4): 52232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George. 1965. The economist and the state. American Economic Review 55 (1/2): 118.Google Scholar
Stigler, George. 1987. The Theory of Price. New York: Macmillan.
Stiglitz, Joseph. 2000. The contributions of the economics of information to twentieth century economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (4): 144178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass. 1990. Political Self-Interest in Constitutional Law. In Beyond Self-Interest, ed. J.J. Mansbridge. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Tarcov, Nathan. 1984. Locke's Education for Liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Thucydides. 1991. History of the Peloponnesian War. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Toulmin, Stephen. 1990. Cosmopolis: The Hidden Agenda of Modernity. New York: Free Press.
Truman, David. 1951. The Governmental Process. 1st ed. New York: Knopf.
Tuck, Richard. 1993. Philosophy and Government, 1572–1651. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Tuck, Richard. 1999. The Rights of War and Peace: Political Thought and the International Order from Grotius to Kant. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ullmann-Margalit, Edna. 1997. The invisible hand and the cunning of reason. Social Research 64 (2): 18198.Google Scholar
Vagts, Alfred. 1948. The balance of power: Growth of an idea. World Politics 1 (1): 82101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vagts, Alfred, and Detlev Vagts. 1979. The balance of power in international law: A history of an idea. American Journal of International Law 73 (4): 55580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vasquez, John. 1997. The realist paradigm and degenerative versus progressive research programs: An appraisal of neotraditional research on Waltz's balancing proposition. American Political Science Review 91 (4): 899912.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vasquez, John, and Colin Elman, eds. 2003. Realism and the Balancing of Power: A New Debate. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Vile, M.J.C. 1967. Constitutionalism and the Separation of Powers. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Von Neumann, John, and Oscar Morgenstern. 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Wagner, R. Harrison. 1986. The theory of games and the balance of power. World Politics 38 (4): 54676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldron, Jeremy. 1987a. Theoretical foundations of liberalism. Philosophical Quarterly 37 (147): 12750.Google Scholar
Waldron, Jeremy, ed. 1987b. ‘Nonsense upon Stilts’: Bentham, Burke and Marx on the Rights of Man. London: Methuen.
Walker, R.B.J. 1987. Realism, change, and international political theory. International Studies Quarterly 31 (1): 6586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1987a. Impôt. Vol. 10. Paris: Economica.
Walras, Léon. 1987b. Théorie mathématique du prix des terres et de leur rachat par l'état. Vol. 9. Paris: Economica.
Walt, Stephen. 1987. The Origins of Alliances. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Waltz, Kenneth. 1962. Kant, liberalism, and war. American Political Science Review 56 (2): 33140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth. 1967. Foreign Policy and Democratic Politics; the American and British Experience. Boston: Little Brown.
Waltz, Kenneth. 1979. Theory of International Politics. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.
Waltz, Kenneth. 1990. Realist thought and neorealist theory. Journal of International Affairs 44 (1): 2137.Google Scholar
Wendt, Alexander. 1987. The agent-structure problem in international relations theory. International Organization 41 (3): 33570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wight, Martin. 1973. The balance of power and international order. In The Bases of International Order, ed. C.A.W. Manning. London: Oxford University Press.
Williams, Michael C. 1996. Hobbes and international relations: A reconsideration. International Organization 50 (2): 21336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, David. 1978. Adam Smith's Politics: An Essay in Historiographic Revision. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Winch, David. 1996. Riches and Poverty: An Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1750–1834. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wohlforth, William. 1999. The stability of a unipolar world. International Security 24 (1): 541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolin, Sheldon. 2004. Politics and Vision; Continuity and Innovation in Western Political Thought. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Wood, Gordon. 1969. The Creation of the American Republic, 1776–1787. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
Woodward, Ernest. 1929. Three Studies in European Conservatism: Metternich, Guizot and the Catholic Church in the Nineteenth Century. London: Constable.
Zakaria, Fareed. 1998. From Wealth to Power: The Unusual Origins of America's World Role. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.