Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-19T15:51:07.109Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Biodiversity conservation in a post-COVID-19 economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 December 2020

Chris Sandbrook*
Affiliation:
Department of Geography, University of Cambridge, Downing Place, Cambridge, CB2 3EN, UK
Erik Gómez-Baggethun
Affiliation:
Norwegian Institute for Nature Research, Oslo, Norway
William M. Adams
Affiliation:
Department of Geography, University of Cambridge, Downing Place, Cambridge, CB2 3EN, UK
*
(Corresponding author) E-mail [email protected]

Abstract

The impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic extend to global biodiversity and its conservation. Although short-term beneficial or adverse impacts on biodiversity have been widely discussed, there is less attention to the likely political and economic responses to the crisis and their implications for conservation. Here we describe four possible alternative future policy responses: (1) restoration of the previous economy, (2) removal of obstacles to economic growth, (3) green recovery and (4) transformative economic reconstruction. Each alternative offers opportunities and risks for conservation. They differ in the agents they emphasize to mobilize change (e.g. markets or states) and in the extent to which they prioritize or downplay the protection of nature. We analyse the advantages and disadvantages of these four options from a conservation perspective. We argue that the choice of post-COVID-19 recovery strategy has huge significance for the future of biodiversity, and that conservationists of all persuasions must not shrink from engagement in the debates to come.

Type
Forum Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Fauna & Flora International

Introduction

The COVID-19 pandemic has caused huge global social and economic disruption. A rapidly growing literature on the coronavirus explores the many dimensions of its social, economic and environmental impacts (e.g. Monbiot, Reference Monbiot2020; Zizek, Reference Zizek2020). There is increasing debate about the implications of the pandemic for global biodiversity and efforts to conserve it. Some commentators identify short-term benefits for biodiversity, such as less pollution as a result of reduced human activity, wildlife reclaiming human-dominated habitats, and enforced shutdowns making people more aware of the species and ecosystems around them, perhaps awakening public concern for the state of nature (e.g. Corlett et al., Reference Corlett, Primack, Devictor, Maas, Goswami and Bates2020; Helm, Reference Helm2020).

The COVID-19 pandemic also has short-term downsides for biodiversity and conservation, linked to the severe global economic recession it has triggered. Firstly, subsistence crises in developing countries have increased the consumptive use of wild species, as people seek food or saleable commodities (Paxton, Reference Paxton2020). Although nature can play an important role as a safety net for well-being during difficult times, even established community-managed sustainable use systems risk failure under such pressures. Secondly, economic disruption has reduced the financial and human capital of conservation organizations. Problems include loss of income for conservation that is derived directly or indirectly from wildlife-based enterprises such as tourism, government tax revenues being reallocated to social benefits (e.g. for the many new unemployed), changing donor priorities to address the pandemic, and reduced funding from corporate or philanthropic donors (Sandbrook, Reference Sandbrook2020). Taken together these negative impacts may outweigh the immediate benefits for biodiversity from COVID-19 (Gardner, Reference Gardner2020).

Beyond the short-term impacts of the pandemic, there is growing debate on the shape of international and national policies for the world after (or with) COVID-19. Roy (Reference Roy2020) describes the pandemic as ‘a portal, a gateway between one world and the next’. Governments and international institutions are now seeking to develop a route out of the portal of the COVID-induced global recession (Helm, Reference Helm2020; International Monetary Fund, 2020). There are various potential pathways, each of which entails a very different relationship between human society and non-human life on Earth. Even as much of the conservation sector is embroiled in a battle for survival in the midst of the crisis, it is essential to look to the future and weigh the consequences of different post-COVID-19 economic scenarios for conservation.

Here we consider the conservation implications of four alternative future political and economic responses to the crisis. We identified the scenarios on the basis of options that have received wide attention before and during the COVID-19 crisis in policy, the media and/or academic debates, and named them according to their central objectives. These are: (1) restoration of the previous economy, (2) removal of obstacles to economic growth, (3) green recovery and (4) transformative economic reconstruction (Table 1). Each of these possible futures carries a different range of opportunities and risks. We explore these possibilities from a conservation perspective, drawing on a range of blogs and commentaries published during the crisis as well as on the peer reviewed literature.

Table 1 Four possible future policy responses to the COVID-19 crisis and their implications for conservation.

Restoration of the previous economy

The first scenario is an attempt to restore previous forms and levels of economic activity. This return to something resembling business as usual is likely to be the most appealing for politicians, businesses and publics because it requires the least reform or disruption to existing institutions, legal systems or ways of life.

This scenario has some immediate advantages for conservation, because it would facilitate the restoration of previous sources of funding. Before COVID-19, international conservation organizations relied on tax revenues, corporate funding (using some spare profit to gift to NGOs), and donations from Trusts and high net worth individuals. Much on-the-ground conservation was dependent on wildlife tourism, whether through business–community partnerships (including direct wages, indirect economic contributions, dividend or lease fee payments), or in business–state partnerships (taxation, jobs, fees). The grounding of international flights and the lockdown of booked and potential tourists have brought crisis to many wildlife tourism businesses and those dependent on their revenue (Paxton, Reference Paxton2020). A return to business as usual would allow these activities to resume, enabling conservation organizations to survive, continue to employ their staff and to implement their existing programmes of work.

On the downside, the pre-COVID-19 economic model was deeply unsustainable at a global scale (Adams, Reference Adams2020). Shutdown has brought declines in CO2 emissions (the Global Footprint Network placed Earth Overshoot Day 2020 on 22 August, three weeks later than in 2019, as a result of lockdown; Global Footprint Network Earth Overshoot Day, 2020). Present patterns of economic growth are key drivers of biodiversity loss (Otero et al., Reference Otero, Farrell, Pueyo, Kallis, Kehoe and Haberl2020), present and future climate change (Jackson & Victor, Reference Jackson and Victor2019), and resource depletion (Haberl et al., Reference Haberl, Wiedenhofer, Virág, Kalt, Plank and Brockway2020). There are therefore strong reasons for conservationists to be concerned about a return to old ways, and some conservation writers have identified this moment as an opportunity to take a different path (e.g. Stafford et al., Reference Stafford, Croker and Jones2020).

Removal of obstacles to economic growth

As lockdowns end, governments will be desperate to reboot their economies to get money into pockets and into their treasuries. As a result, they may push beyond the restoration of the previous economy (described above) by removing all obstacles to short term economic growth. After the 2008 economic crash, many governments selectively removed environmental regulations to boost return on private investment and promote growth and employment, and downgraded protected area designations (Apostolopoulou & Adams, Reference Apostolopoulou and Adams2015). In the face of an even greater global recession caused by the pandemic, governments are likely to feel a similar temptation to take any steps necessary to maximize economic growth. This could include bailing out polluting industries such as aviation, relaxing environmental standards, and opening up natural resources to exploitation—in effect spending down natural capital reserves to pay for COVID-19 debt. Several countries have already allowed new mining concessions in protected areas since the crisis began (e.g. Ecuador and India; Sandbrook, Reference Sandbrook2020), and the media are reporting ongoing or planned dismantlement of environmental regulations in high biodiversity countries such as Brazil and the USA (Holden, Reference Holden2020; Spring, Reference Spring2020).

Maximizing economic growth would have some benefits for certain conservation actors. It would enable governments, philanthropists and citizens to start donating to, investing in and purchasing from the conservation sector more quickly than under our alternative scenarios. It could also offer a short-term livelihoods social safety net for the poor, if reduced environmental regulation allowed increased natural resource use, although such benefits would be short-term and unsustainable.

Unfortunately, any such economic benefits would be at the expense of biodiversity. Maximizing growth would in effect entail accelerated biodiversity loss (Otero et al., Reference Otero, Farrell, Pueyo, Kallis, Kehoe and Haberl2020) and further commodification of nature to generate profit (Gómez-Baggethun & Ruiz-Pérez, Reference Gómez-Baggethun and Ruiz-Pérez2011). At its worst for conservation, this scenario could even include the deliberate extermination of species deemed to harbour potential future zoonotic diseases, such as pangolins or bats (Zhao, Reference Zhao2020), or even ecosystems.

Green recovery

A hope of many conservationists is that recovery should aspire to deliver the same level of economic activity (with all its potential in terms of wealth creation and poverty alleviation), but based on technologies with radically reduced environmental impacts. This idea of green recovery has some political traction (e.g. Harvey, Reference Harvey2020).

This is a classic ecomodernist vision, a familiar part of the debate about sustainable development since the 1970s (Adams, Reference Adams2020). It lay at the heart of the Rio + 20 Conference, under the name of a Green Economy. The report Towards a Green Economy envisaged growth in global income and employment driven by both public and private investment (UNEP, 2011). It argued that the Green Economy could ‘deliver improved human well-being and social equity, while significantly reducing environmental risks and ecological scarcities’ (UNEP, 2011, p. 16). This shift implies an economy that is still capitalist, but cleverer and greener, where growth, markets and corporations are turned into conservation allies and where biodiversity conservation becomes an agent of green economic development (Gasparatos & Willis, Reference Gasparatos and Willis2015).

Within this perspective, the idea of so-called green growth is the dominant policy response advocated to address the environmental crises by the European Union, United Nations, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, and the World Bank, among others. The core premise is that continued growth is compatible with conservation because increased efficiency from technological progress and market signals will facilitate the substitution of natural resources, leading us to a dematerialized and decarbonized economy in which growth is decoupled from resource use and pollution. The related notion of a Green New Deal gained traction in the aftermath of the 2008 recession (Barbier, Reference Barbier2010) and now again in discussions around economic recovery after COVID-19 (e.g. Mace, Reference Mace2020). The Green New Deal involves a wide wide-ranging set of goals, often emphasizing green job creation and public investment in the energy transition to decarbonize the economy. The USA version includes proposals for 100% clean and renewable electricity by 2035 and zero net emissions by 2050, while creating 10 million jobs to build and install energy infrastructure (Whyte, Reference Whyte2018). Goals of the European Green Deal include boosting the efficient use of resources by moving to a circular economy, restoring biodiversity and cutting pollution (European Commission, 2019).

The idea of green growth is popular among so-called new conservationists, who make the case for biodiversity conservation as a key driver of economic development (Kareiva et al., Reference Kareiva, Lalasz and Marvier2011). The expectation is that intensive use of technology will allow land to be spared for rewilding and the recovery of biodiversity (Asafu-Adjaye et al., Reference Asafu-Adjaye, Blomquist, Brand, Brook, Defries and Ellis2015). Conservationists would partner with corporate power to integrate the value of nature's benefits into the economy. Instead of pursuing the protection of biodiversity for biodiversity's sake, a new conservation based on enhancing natural systems that benefit people would reduce conservation conflicts (Kareiva et al., Reference Kareiva, Lalasz and Marvier2011).

Much recent conservation practice is consistent with new conservation thinking, but conservation's growing dependence on private sector actors and market-based initiatives (rather than relying on state action) looks vulnerable in the light of the limited capacity of businesses to sustain public action during the current crisis without direct state subsidy. There are also risks in commoditization and little evidence that market-based instruments can bring effective conservation outcomes (Gómez-Baggethun & Muradian, Reference Gómez-Baggethun and Muradian2015). Another drawback of green growth is that there are few or no signs of decoupling of growth and environmental impact at the pace needed to reach sustainability targets (Jackson & Victor, Reference Muradian2019; Haberl et al., Reference Haberl, Wiedenhofer, Virág, Kalt, Plank and Brockway2020).

Economic arguments for large-scale public investment in green technologies will face competition from other pressing claims for direct social investment, and subsidy and investment in other sectors such as primary extraction of raw materials or transportation (Helm, Reference Helm2020). There is a risk that the slogan of green recovery will be co-opted to camouflage traditional strategies of large-scale infrastructure development (Harvey, Reference Harvey2020).

Transformative economic reconstruction

The last of our four visions of the future economy reflects the numerous calls (e.g. Stafford et al., Reference Stafford, Croker and Jones2020) for a substantial change in conventional growth-based models, that ‘reward more instead of better consumption, private vs public investment in [hu]man-made vs natural capital’ (Martinez-Alier et al., Reference Martínez-Alier, Pascual, Vivien and Zaccai2010, p. 1741, emphases in the original). There have been many alternative visions of post-growth economies over the last half century (Adams, Reference Adams2020). The term post-growth encompasses a spectrum of perspectives, ranging from those that adopt an agnostic stance towards growth (van den Bergh, Reference van den Bergh2011; Raworth, Reference Raworth2017), to those that explicitly aim at stabilizing or reducing the scale of the economy (D'Alisa et al., Reference D'Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2014; Jackson, Reference Jackson2016). Socio-ecological transitions to reduce economic metabolism (flows of energy and materials) down to a level compatible with planetary boundaries have been long advocated by ecological economists, often in the form of a steady state economy (Daly, Reference Daly2014). For wealthy industrial economies this idea is increasingly thought about under the label of degrowth. Degrowth advocates a sustainable and equitable downscaling of production and consumption. In contrast to what is often assumed, degrowth is different from recession (negative GDP). The focus of downscaling is on the physical (not monetary) size of the economy (Kallis, Reference Kallis2018).

Once a marginal proposal, the idea of post-growth has gained leverage as mounting research has revealed a lack of empirical support to the thesis of decoupling sustained by green growth advocates (Jackson & Victor, Reference Jackson and Victor2019). Although cases of decoupling between growth and environmental impact at national or regional level bring some hope (Le Quéré et al., Reference Le Quéré, Korsbakken, Wilson, Tosun, Andrew and Andres2019; Marques et al., Reference Marques, Martins, Kastner, Plutzar, Theurl and Eisenmenger2019), globally growth remains highly coupled to carbon emissions and resource use (Haberl et al., Reference Haberl, Wiedenhofer, Virág, Kalt, Plank and Brockway2020), as well as to biodiversity loss (Otero et al., Reference Otero, Farrell, Pueyo, Kallis, Kehoe and Haberl2020). The idea of post-growth has also gained renewed attention as COVID-19 has shown that large-scale economic changes can happen fast if there is political will for it (Everingham & Chassagne, Reference Everingham and Chassagne2020).

Proponents of transformative ecological–economic reconstruction advocate radical reorganization of the economy, including reforms in national accounts (to account for the environmental costs of growth), green tax reforms (shifting taxes from labour to resources and pollution), subsidy reforms (from nuclear and fossils to renewables), reforms in finance (divestment from fossil fuels) and trade (green tariffs), reduced working time (to stabilize consumption and combat unemployment), and resource and pollution caps (at levels compatible with the Earth's regenerative and assimilative capacities); for an overview see Daly (Reference Daly2013). In a manifesto on the future after the COVID-19 crisis, degrowth advocates demand divestment from fossil fuels, military and advertising to liberate resources for healthcare, education, renewable energy, ecological agriculture, and a basic income (Barlow et al., Reference Barlow, Chertkovskaya, Grebenjak, Liegey, Schneider and Smith2020).

The critique of growth has been linked to the debates around biodiversity conservation (Büscher & Fletcher, Reference Büscher and Fletcher2020). Conservationists critical of growth argue that to stop biodiversity loss, the metabolism of the world economy needs to change. Because growth and biodiversity loss are linked via a set of mechanisms triggered by increased resource use (Czech et al., Reference Czech, Mills Busa and Brown2012; Marques et al., Reference Marques, Martins, Kastner, Plutzar, Theurl and Eisenmenger2019), proponents suggest that a post-growth economy would bring large benefits for conservation (Otero et al., Reference Otero, Farrell, Pueyo, Kallis, Kehoe and Haberl2020). COVID-19 has revealed the brittleness of extended just-in-time delivery chains, the health risks of globalized hyper-mobility and the implications of a model of conservation (especially in the developing world) that is built around a global tourist industry, corporate investment and wealthy donors. A post-growth world offers an alternative path for conservation as well as the economy.

On the downside, the case has been made that whereas degrowth can be appealing among an educated middle class for which frugality is a choice, it is less likely to appeal to those in lower-income social groups, for whom frugality is a social condition (Muradian, Reference Muradian2019), and who account for larger parts of the population in biodiversity-rich developing countries. The question also remains of how much wild nature will survive in a degrowth scenario of decentralized, less intensive production. It would bring a greener and more just world, but most likely one of intensively used landscapes. Moreover, increased food production in the global North to replace imports from the global South would be likely to re-intensify rural land use, and reduce current opportunities for ecological restoration. Many northern conservationists would see this as an unacceptable outcome. On a more practical level, it is challenging to imagine a new financial model for conservation in a post-growth, and potentially post-carbon world.

Discussion

The four scenarios we have outlined offer both advantages and disadvantages for conservation. Each suffers from its own limitations and represents different hopes that may include a dose of wishful thinking. For example, post-growth advocates criticize green growth advocates for excessive technological optimism, and these in turn criticize post-growth for its political idealism (Gómez-Baggethun, Reference Gómez-Baggethun2020). Some of the policy responses discussed here are shared by different scenarios. For example, although usually connected to notions of green growth (e.g. UNEP, 2009; European Commission, 2019), the Green New Deal offers some flexibility and room for engagement with both green growth and degrowth perspectives, both of which overlap in some proposed policies such as carbon taxation and investment in energy efficiency and renewables (O'Neill, Reference O'Neill2020).

Our personal view is that only the transformative economic reconstruction scenario offers a truly sustainable future. However, conservationists have dissimilar beliefs on a wide range of topics (Sandbrook et al., Reference Sandbrook, Fisher, Holmes, Luque-Lora and Keane2019) and many will disagree with our perspective, and legitimately so. Whichever scenario one may favour, we believe that we are living through a unique moment at which fundamental change in the relationship between nature and society is possible. Conservationists of every hue agree that the prognosis for biodiversity was poor before the advent of COVID-19, and it is important to think clearly about which pathway they would prefer to see taken, and what they could be doing to make this more likely to happen. We believe this should entail serious engagement with the deep-rooted political and economic structures that are the ultimate drivers of biodiversity loss.

A key constraint on new thinking is that current conservation depends on funds from sources originating in rich industrialized countries whose economies are inextricably dependent on unsustainable resource and energy use. This creates a set of perverse incentives for conservation organizations. Although they may wish to see transformative changes to the pre-COVID-19 economic system, in many cases their short-term survival depends on a return to that same system. Success in re-establishing existing economic arrangements (and the reforging of powerful partnerships within the corporate sector) would restore systems of resource consumption that are unsustainable and are driving accelerated biodiversity loss (Otero et al., Reference Otero, Farrell, Pueyo, Kallis, Kehoe and Haberl2020). This paradox can be dealt with locally using various spatial or temporal fixes, such as ignoring the broader contradictions of long-haul nature-based tourism so long as it produces short-term benefits for particular species or ecosystems. This has been the dominant approach taken in the past (Pascual et al., Reference Pascual, Palomo, Adams, Chan, Daws and Garemendia2017), but COVID-19 has revealed its limitations.

The Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services states that ‘goals for conserving and sustainably using nature […] cannot be met by current trajectories […], and may only be achieved through transformative changes across economic, social, political and technological factors’ (IPBES, 2019, p. 5). The COVID-19 crisis opens a unique window of opportunity to push for deeper change, towards transforming the metabolism of the economy such that it does not continue to erode biodiversity and ecological life-support systems. This involves adopting a long term vision and assuming short term costs. It might mean the loss of some conservation funds, projects, and even organizations that are dependent on unsustainable aspects of the pre-COVID-19 economic model.

Whatever form of conservation they believe in, the choice of post-COVID-19 recovery by national governments and international organizations has huge significance for the future of biodiversity. These choices are highly political, but conservationists of all persuasions must not shrink from engagement in the debates to come. They have already started, and will shape the diversity of the biosphere into the 22nd century and beyond.

Acknowledgements

EG-B received partial funding from the strategic resources of the Norwegian Institute of Nature Research (project number: 81151842). CS & WMA received no specific grant from any funding agency, or commercial or not-for-profit sectors.

Author contributions

Analysis and writing: all authors.

Conflicts of interest

None.

Ethical standards

The research conducted for this article abided by the Oryx guidelines on ethical standards. It did not include any primary research and therefore an ethical review process was not required.

Footnotes

*

Also at: Department of International Environment and Development Studies, Norwegian University of Life Sciences, Ås, Norway

References

Adams, W.M. (2020) Green Development: Environment and Sustainability in a Developing World. 4th edition. Routledge, London, UK.Google Scholar
Apostolopoulou, E. & Adams, W.M. (2015) Neoliberal capitalism and conservation in the post-crisis era: the dialectics of ‘Green’ and ‘Un-green’ grabbing in Greece and the UK. Antipode, 47, 1535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asafu-Adjaye, J., Blomquist, L., Brand, S., Brook, B.W., Defries, R., Ellis, E. et al. (2015) An Ecomodernist Manifesto. Breakthrough Institute, Oakland, USA.Google Scholar
Barbier, E.B. (2010) A Global Green New Deal: Rethinking the Economic Recovery. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barlow, N., Chertkovskaya, E., Grebenjak, M., Liegey, V., Schneider, F., Smith, T. et al. (2020) Degrowth: new roots for the economy: re-imagining the future after the corona crisis. framaforms.org/degrowth-open-letter-1587824775 [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Büscher, B. & Fletcher, R. (2020) The Conservation Revolution: Radical Ideas for Saving Nature Beyond the Anthropocene. Verso, London, UK.Google Scholar
Corlett, R.T., Primack, R.B., Devictor, V., Maas, B., Goswami, V.R., Bates, A.E. et al. (2020) Impacts of the coronavirus pandemic on biodiversity conservation. Biological Conservation, 246, 108571.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Czech, B., Mills Busa, J.H. & Brown, R.M. (2012) Effects of economic growth on biodiversity in the United States. Natural Resources Forum, 36, 160166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D'Alisa, G., Demaria, F. & Kallis, G. (eds) (2014) Degrowth: A Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, London, UK.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daly, H. (2013) Top 10 policies for a steady-state economy. Daily News, 28 October 2013. steadystate.org/top-10-policies-for-a-steady-state-economy [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Daly, H.E. (2014) From Uneconomic Growth to a Steady-State Economy. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
European Commission (2019) What is the European Green Deal? ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/api/files/attachment/859152/What_is_the_European_Green_Deal_en.pdf.pdf [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Everingham, P. & Chassagne, N. (2020) Post COVID-19 ecological and social reset: moving away from capitalist growth models towards tourism as Buen Vivir. Tourism Geographies, 22, 555566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardner, C. (2020) Nature's comeback? No, the coronavirus pandemic threatens the world's wildlife. The Conversation, 14 April 2020. theconversation.com/natures-comeback-no-the-coronavirus-pandemic-threatens-the-worlds-wildlife-136209 [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Gasparatos, A. & Willis, K.J. (eds) (2015) Biodiversity in the Green Economy. Routledge, London, UK.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Global Footprint Network Earth Overshoot Day (2020) overshootday.org [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Gómez-Baggethun, E. (2020) More is more: scaling political ecology within limits to growth. Political Geography, 76, 102095.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gómez-Baggethun, E. & Muradian, R. (2015) In markets we trust? Setting the boundaries of Market-Based Instruments in ecosystem services governance. Ecological Economics, 117, 217224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gómez-Baggethun, E. & Ruiz-Pérez, M. (2011) Economic valuation and the commodification of ecosystem services. Progress in Physical Geography, 35, 613628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haberl, H., Wiedenhofer, D., Virág, D., Kalt, G., Plank, B., Brockway, P. et al. (2020) A systematic review of the evidence on decoupling of GDP, resource use and GHG emissions, part II: synthesizing the insights. Environmental Research Letters, 15, 065003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harvey, F. (2020) Boris Johnson under pressure to ensure green recovery in UK. The Guardian, 4 June 2020. theguardian.com/environment/2020/jun/04/boris-johnson-under-pressure-to-ensure-green-recovery-uk-coronavirus [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Helm, D. (2020) The environmental impacts of the coronavirus. Environmental and Resource Economics, 76, 2138.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Holden, E. (2020) Trump dismantles environmental protections under cover of coronavirus. The Guardian, 10 May 2020. theguardian.com/us-news/2020/may/10/trump-environmental-blitzkrieg-coronavirus [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (2020) Global Stability Report, April 2020. imf.org/en/Publications/GFSR/Issues/2020/04/14/global-financial-stability-report-april-2020 [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
IPBES (2019) Summary for Policymakers of the Global Assessment Report on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services of the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. IPBES Secretariat, Bonn, Germany.Google Scholar
Jackson, T. (2016) Prosperity Without Growth: Foundations for the Economy of Tomorrow. Routledge, London, UK.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackson, T. & Victor, P.A. (2019) Unraveling the claims for (and against) green growth. Science, 366, 950951.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kallis, G. (2018) Degrowth. Columbia University Press, New York, USA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kareiva, P., Lalasz, R. & Marvier, M. (2011) Conservation in the Anthropocene: beyond solitude and fragility. Breakthrough Journal, 2, 2937.Google Scholar
Le Quéré, C., Korsbakken, J.I., Wilson, C., Tosun, J., Andrew, R., Andres, R.J. et al. (2019) Drivers of declining CO2 emissions in 18 developed economies. Nature Climate Change, 9, 213e217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mace, M. (2020) ‘Normal was a crisis’: Why the Green New Deal is the perfect response for the post-COVID-19 economy. Edie, 1 April 2020. edie.net/library/-Normal-was-a-crisis---Why-the-Green-New-Deal-offers-hope-to-the-post-Covid-19-economy/6971 [accessed 20 June 2020].Google Scholar
Marques, A., Martins, I.S., Kastner, T., Plutzar, C., Theurl, M.C., Eisenmenger, N. et al. (2019) Increasing impacts of land use on biodiversity and carbon sequestration driven by population and economic growth. Nature Ecology & Evolution, 3, 628637.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Martínez-Alier, J., Pascual, U., Vivien, F.-D. & Zaccai, E. (2010) Sustainable de-growth: mapping the context, criticisms and future prospects of an emergent paradigm. Ecological Economics, 69, 17411747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Monbiot, G. (2020) Airlines and oil giants are on the brink. No government should offer them a lifeline. The Guardian, 29 April 2020. theguardian.com/commentisfree/2020/apr/29/airlines-oil-giants-government-economy [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Muradian, R. (2019) Frugality as a choice vs frugality as a social condition. Is de-growth doomed to be a Eurocentric project? Ecological Economics, 161, 257260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Neill, D.W. (2020) Beyond green growth. Nature Sustainability, 3, 260261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otero, I., Farrell, K.N., Pueyo, S., Kallis, G., Kehoe, L., Haberl, H. et al. (2020) Biodiversity policy beyond economic growth. Conservation Letters, 13, e12713.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pascual, U., Palomo, I., Adams, W.M., Chan, K., Daws, T.M., Garemendia, E. et al. (2017) Off-stage ecosystem service burdens: a blind spot for global sustainability. Environmental Research Letters, 12, 075001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paxton, M. (2020) The coronavirus threat to wildlife tourism and conservation. UNDP Blog, 21 April 2020. undp.org/content/undp/en/home/blog/2020/the-coronavirus-threat-to-wildlife-tourism-and-conservation.html [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Raworth, K. (2017) Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways to Think Like a 21st-Century Economist. Chelsea Green Publishing, Hartford, USA.Google Scholar
Roy, A. (2020) The pandemic is a portal. Financial Times, 3 April 2020. ft.com/content/10d8f5e8-74eb-11ea-95fe-fcd274e920ca [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Sandbrook, C. (2020) Covid and conservation on the ground. Thinking Like a Human Blog, 17 May 2020. thinkinglikeahuman.com/2020/05/17/coronavirus-and-conservation-a-global-situation-report [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Sandbrook, C., Fisher, J.A., Holmes, G., Luque-Lora, R. & Keane, A. (2019) The global conservation movement is diverse but not divided. Nature Sustainability, 2, 316323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spring, J. (2020) Brazil minister calls for environmental deregulation while public distracted by COVID. Reuters, 22 May 2020. reuters.com/article/us-brazil-politics-environment/brazil-minister-calls-for-environmental-deregulation-while-public-distracted-by-covid-idUSKBN22Y30Y [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Stafford, R., Croker, A. & Jones, P.J.S. (2020) After coronavirus. Ecologist, 23 April 2020. theecologist.org/2020/apr/22/after-coronavirus [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
UNEP (2011) Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and Poverty Eradication. United Nations Environment Programme, Nairobi, Kenya.Google Scholar
van den Bergh, J.C. (2011) Environment vs growth—A criticism of “degrowth” and a plea for ‘a-growth’. Ecological Economics, 70, 881890.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whyte, C. (2018) Can a Green New Deal boost the US economy and save the planet? New Scientist. newscientist.com/article/2188186-can-a-green-new-deal-boost-the-us-economy-and-save-the-planet [accessed 22 June 2020].Google Scholar
Zhao, H. (2020) COVID-19 drives new threat to bats in China. Science, 367, 1436.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zizek, S. (2020) Pandemic! Covid-19 Shakes the World. OR Books, New York, USA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Four possible future policy responses to the COVID-19 crisis and their implications for conservation.