Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T10:31:20.165Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Macroeconomics and History

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 March 2020

Abstract

Macroeconomic behaviour varies according to the character of the policy regime. There is therefore no truly ‘general’ theory which will apply at all times and in all places. Over the past hundred years, one model may be appropriate to the period of the gold standard, another to the interwar years, another to the so-called ‘Golden Age’ after the Second World War, and so on. Expectations, which depend on confidence in the regime, determine the stability of both prices and output. Institutions also adapt in ways that may support, or ultimately undermine, the foundations of the policy regime.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2002 National Institute of Economic and Social Research

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Artis, M. (2000), ‘Should the UK join EMU?’, National Institute Economic Review, January.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, A.J. (1985), World Inflation Since 1950, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Britton, A. (1991), Macroeconomic Policy in Britain, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Britton, A. (2001), Monetary regimes of the Twentieth Century, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dow, J.C.R. (1964), The Management of the British Economy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dow, J.C.R. (1998), Major Recessions, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. (1995), Golden Fetters, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. and Schwarz, A. (1963), A Monetary History of the United States, Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hansen, A. (1932), Economic Stabilisation in an Unbalanced World, New York, Harcourt Brace.Google Scholar
Hayek, F.A. (1944), The Road to Serfdom, reprinted 1986, London, Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. (1935), ‘A suggestion for simplifying the theory of money’, Economica.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hood, C. (1994), Explaining Economic Policy Reversals, Milton, Keynes, Open University Press.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T.W. (1953), A Review of Economic Doctrine, 1870-1929, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1923), Tract on Monetary Reform, London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.N. (1891), The Scope and Method of Political Economy, London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. (1987), Models of Business Cycles, Oxford, Blackwell.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. (1976), ‘Econometric policy evaluation - a critique’, in Brunner, K. and Melzer, A. (eds), The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, North Holland.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matthews, R.C.O. (1958), ‘Why have we had full employment since the war?’, Economic Journal.Google Scholar
OECD (1977), Towards Full Employment and Price Stability, Paris, OECD.Google Scholar
OECD (1994), The Jobs Study Report, Paris, OECD.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. (1915), Study of Industrial Fluctuations, London, King and Son.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. (1948), Economics, 1st edition, New York, McGraw Hill.Google Scholar