Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-02T18:44:04.262Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Migration, Skill Composition and Growth

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 March 2020

Young-Bae Kim
Affiliation:
University of Surrey
Paul Levine
Affiliation:
University of Surrey
Emanuela Lotti*
Affiliation:
University of Southampton and University of Surrey

Abstract

The UK, with its relatively liberal immigration policies following recent enlargements, has been one of the main recipients of migrants from new EU member states. This paper poses the questions: what is the effect of immigration on a receiving economy such as the UK? Is the effect beneficial or adverse for growth? Does emigration have brain drain effects on sending economies? How differently would skilled (or unskilled) migration affect both receiving and sending economies? What factors would contribute to immigration/emigration benefits/costs and economic growth driven by migration? Who are the winners and losers in both the sending and host regions? We utilise a two-bloc endogenous growth model with labour mobility of different skill compositions to address these questions. We show that migration, in general, is beneficial to the receiving country and increases the world growth rate. With remittances, the sending country in aggregate can also benefit. The only exception is in the case of unskilled migration, which can actually have a detrimental impact on the world growth rate. This possibility however seems to be unlikely by our examination of migration trends. Winners are migrants, and the skill group in the region that sees its relative size decrease.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2010 National Institute of Economic and Social Research

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

The authors would like to thank Stephen Drinkwater for very helpful comments.

References

Arrow, K.J. (1962), ‘The economic implications of learning by doing’, Review of Economic Studies, 29, 3, pp. 155–73.Google Scholar
Barrell, R., FitzGerald, J. and Riley, R. (2007), ‘EU enlargement and migration: assessing the macroeconomic impact’, NIESR Discussion Paper 292.Google Scholar
Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1992), ‘Regional growth and migration: a Japan-United States comparison’, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 6, pp. 312–46.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995), Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Beine, M., Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2001), ‘Brain drain and economic growth: theory and evidence’, Journal of Development Economics, 64(1), pp. 275–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beine, M., Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2008), ‘Brain drain and human capital formation in developing countries: winners and losers’, Economic Journal, 118(528), pp. 631–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borjas, G. (1995), ‘The economic benefits from immigration’, Journal of Economic Literature, 9(2), pp. 322.Google Scholar
Borjas, G. (1999), ‘The economic analysis of immigration’, in Ashenfelter, O.C. and Card, D. (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics, Amsterdam, North-Holland, pp. 1697–760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borjas, G. (2001), ‘Does immigration grease the wheels of the labor market? ’ Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 69133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buch, C.M. and Toubal, F.(2009), ‘Openness and growth: the long shadow of the Berlin Wall’, Journal of Macroeconomics, 31, pp. 409–22.Google Scholar
Burda, M. and Hunt, J. (2001), ‘From reunification to economic integration: productivity and the labour market in Eastern Germany’, Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp. 192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, D. (2005), ‘Is the new immigration really so bad?’, Economic Journal, 115, 507, pp. 300–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chui, M., Levine, P. and Pearlman, J. (2001), ‘Winners and losers in a North-South model of growth, innovation and product cycles’, Journal of Development Economics, 65, pp. 333–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, A. and Razin, A. (2009), ‘Skill composition of migration and the generosity of the welfare state: free vs. policy-controlled migration’, mimeo 641, Tel-Aviv University.Google Scholar
Cohen, A., Razin, A., and Sadka, E. (2009), ‘The skill composition of migrants and the generosity of the welfare state’, CEPR Discussion Paper Series 7185, February.Google Scholar
Currie, D., Levine, P., Pearlman, J. and Chui, M. (1999), ‘Phases of imitation and innovation in a North-South endogenous growth model’, Oxford Economic Papers, 51(1), pp. 6088.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drinkwater, S. and Clark, K. (2008), ‘The labour-market performance of recent migrants’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24(3), pp. 495516.Google Scholar
Drinkwater, S., Levine, P., Lotti, E. and Pearlman, J. (2003), ‘The economic impact of migration: a survey’, International Journal for Economic Development, 5, 2.Google Scholar
Drinkwater, S., Levine, P., Lotti, E. and Pearlman, J. (2007), ‘The immigration surplus revisited in a general equilibrium model with endogenous growth’, Journal of Regional Science, 47(3), pp. 569601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dustmann, C., Fabbri, F. and Preston, I. (2005), ‘The impact of immigration on the British labour market’, Economic Journal, 115(507), F324F341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hall, R. and Jones, C.I. (1999), ‘Why some countries produce so much more output per worker than others’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, pp. 82116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamermesh, D. (1993), Labor Demand, Princeton,Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hanson, G.H. (2008), ‘The economic consequences of the international migration of labor’, NBER Working Paper 14490, November.Google Scholar
Kahanec, M. and Zimmermann, K.F. (2008), ‘Migration in an enlarged EU: a challenging solution?’, IZA Discussion Paper No. 3913, December.Google Scholar
Kyrdar, M.G. and Saracoulu, D.S. (2008), ‘Migration and regional convergence: an empirical investigation for Turkey’, Papers in Regional Science, 87(4), pp. 545566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levine, P., Lotti, E., Pearlman, J. and Pierse, R. (2010), ‘Growth and welfare effects of world migration’, Scottish Journal Of Political Economy (forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lundborg, P. and Segerstrom, P.S. (2000), ‘International migration and growth in developed countries: a theoretical analysis’, Economica, 67, pp. 579604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lundborg, P. and Segerstrom, P.S. (2002), ‘The growth and welfare effects of international mass migration’, Journal of International Economics, 56, pp. 177204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manacorda, M., Manning, A. and Wadsworth, J. (2007), ‘The impact of immigration on the structure of male wages: theory and evidence from Britain’, CEP Discussion Paper No. 754.Google Scholar
Marchiori, L., Shen, I. and Docquier, F. (2009), ‘Brain drain in globalization: a GE analysis from the sending countries’ perspective’, prepared for a Conference at the World Bank.Google Scholar
Maza, A. (2006), ‘Migrations and regional convergence: the case of Spain’, Jahrbuch fur Regionalwissenschaft, 26, pp. 191202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oecd (2009), International Migration Outlook, Paris, OECD.Google Scholar
Ortega, F. (2005), ‘Immigration quotas and skill upgrading’, Journal of Public Economics, 89, pp. 1841–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortega, J. (2000), ‘Pareto-improving immigration in an economy with equilibrium unemployment’, The Economic Journal, 110(460), pp. 92112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parente, S.L. and Prescott, E.C. (2000), Barriers to Riches, Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perssons, J. (1997), ‘Convergence across the Swedish counties’, European Economic Review, 41, pp. 1835–52.Google Scholar
Rodrick, D. (2004), ‘How to make the trade regime work for development’, mimeo, Harvard University.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J.A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New York, Harper.Google Scholar
Toya, H., Hosono, K. and Makino, T. (2004), ‘Human capital, migration, and regional income convergence in the Philippines’, Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University (Tokyo) Discussion Paper Series, No.18.Google Scholar
Wadsworth, J. (2010), ‘The UK labour market and immigration’, National Institute Economic Review, 213, July.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walmsley, T.L. and Winters, L.A. (2005), ‘Relaxing the restrictions on the temporary movement of natural persons: a simulation analysis’, Journal of Economic Integration, 20(4), pp. 688726.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walmsley, T.L., Winters, L.A. and Ahmed, S.A. (2009), ‘Measuring the impact of the movement of labor using a model of bilateral migration flows’, paper prepared for a Conference at the World Bank.Google Scholar
Winters, L.A. (2001), ‘Assessing the efficiency gain from further liberalization: a comment’, in Sauve, P. and Subramanian, A. (eds), Efficiency, Equity and Legitimacy: The Multilateral Trading System and the Millennium, Chicago, Chicago University Press. pp. 106–13.Google Scholar
World Bank (2006), Global Economic Prospects 2006 : Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration, Washington, DC, The World Bank.Google Scholar
Zaiceva, A. and Zimmermann, K.F. (2008), ‘Scale, diversity, and determinants of labour migration in Europe’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24(3), pp. 427–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar