Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T15:10:58.931Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

History and the Debate Over Intellectual Property

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 March 2017

Mike W. Peng
Affiliation:
University of Texas at Dallas, USA
David Ahlstrom
Affiliation:
The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong
Shawn M. Carraher
Affiliation:
University of Texas at Dallas, USA
Weilei (Stone) Shi
Affiliation:
City University of New York, USA
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This article responds to recent calls for organizational research to address larger, more globally relevant questions and to pay attention to history, by analyzing the crucial debate over intellectual property rights (IPR) between the United States and China. Despite the recent US position, the United States has not always been a leading IPR advocate. Rather, it was a leading IPR violator during the nineteenth century. An institution-based view of IPR history suggests that both the US refusal to protect foreign IPR in the nineteenth century and the current Chinese lack of enthusiasm to meet US IPR demands represent rational choices. However, as cost-benefit considerations change institutional transitions are possible. We predict that to the same extent the United States voluntarily agreed to strengthen IPR protection when its economy became sufficiently innovation-driven, China will similarly improve its IPR protection.

摘要:

摘要:

本文通过分析美国和中国之间关于知识产权 (IPR) 至关重要的辩论, 回应最近对组织研究以解决更大的在全球范围更相关的问题的和注重历史的呼吁。尽管近期的美国立场, 美国并不一直是领先的知识产权倡导者。相反, 在十九世纪它是一个领先的知识产权违规者。知识产权历史的制度基础观认为, 美国在十九世纪对保护外国IPR的拒绝和当前中国缺乏满足美国对IPR要求的热情体现了理性选择。然而, 由于成本效益分析的演化, 制度交易是可能的。我们预测, 与美国在其经济充分成为创新驱动时自愿同意加强IPR保护的程度一样, 中国将类似地改进其IPR保护。

यह शोध पत्र अंतर्राष्ट्रीय स्तर पर प्रासंगिक प्रश्नों के संगठनीय शोध में ध्यान देने व ऐतिहासिक परिप्रेक्ष्य लेने के अभिनव आह्वान के तहत चीन व अमरीका (यू. एस. ए.) के बीच महत्वपूर्ण बौद्धिक सम्पदा संरक्षण सम्बन्धी विवादों का विश्लेषण करता है. अपने वर्तमान दृष्टिकोण के बावजूद अमरीका सदैव बौद्धिक सम्पदा संरक्षण पर अग्रणी व्याख्याता नहीं था. इसके विपरीत 19 वीं शताब्दी में अमरीका बौद्धिक सम्पदा अधिकारों का उल्लंघन करने में अग्रणी था. संस्थागत परिप्रेक्ष्य में 19 वीं शताब्दी में बौद्धिक सम्पदा अधिकार बचने से इनकार और सम्प्रति चीन की अमरीकी बौद्धिक सम्पदा अधिकार बचानी में उत्साह की कमी-दोनों हे अपने सन्दर्भ में तर्कसंगत हैं. फिर भी जैसे-जैसे लागत-लाभ विश्लेषण विकसित होता है, संस्थागत परिवर्तन संभव है. हमारा अनुमान है की जिस स्तर तक अर्थव्यवस्था के नवरचनापरक होने पर जिस प्रकार अमरीका स्वेच्छा से बौद्धिक सम्पदा अधिकार लागू करने को राज़ी हुआ, उसी तरह चीन भी अपना बौद्धिक सम्पदा संरक्षण अधिकार मजबूत करेगा.

Sumário:

Sumário:

Este artigo responde aos recentes apelos à investigação organizacional para abordar questões mais amplas e globalmente relevantes e prestar atenção à história, analisando o debate crucial sobre os direitos de propriedade intelectual (IPR) entre os Estados Unidos e a China. Apesar da posição recente dos Estados Unidos, os Estados Unidos nem sempre foram um dos principais defensores dos IPR. Em vez disso, foram um dos principais violadores de IPR durante o século XIX. Uma visão baseada em instituições da história dos IPR sugere que tanto a recusa dos EUA em proteger os direitos de propriedade intelectual estrangeiros no século XIX como a atual falta de entusiasmo dos chineses para atender às demandas de IPR dos EUA representam escolhas racionais. No entanto, à medida que a análise custo-benefício evolui, transições institucionais são possíveis. Predizemos que, na mesma medida em que os Estados Unidos voluntariamente concordaram em reforçar a proteção dos IPR quando sua economia se tornou suficientemente inovadora, a China também melhorará sua proteção aos IPR.

Аннотация:

АННОТАЦИЯ:

Данная статья отвечает на недавние отклики в научной литературе, которые призывают к решению более крупных и глобально значимых вопросов, а именно обратиться к истории и проанализировать важные дебаты по поводу прав интеллектуальной собственности (ПИС) между Соединенными Штатами и Китаем. Несмотря на современную позицию США, Соединенные Штаты не всегда были главным поборником прав интеллектуальной собственности. Напротив, они были главным нарушителем прав интеллектуальной собственности в девятнадцатом веке. С точки зрения институциональной теории, история прав интеллектуальной собственности предполагает, что отказ США от защиты иностранных прав интеллектуальной собственности в девятнадцатом веке и отсутствие энтузиазма у современного Китая удовлетворить требования США в отношении ПИС представляют теорию рационального выбора. Однако, согласно анализу эффективности затрат, институциональные переходы возможны. Мы прогнозируем, что в той же степени, как и Соединенные Штаты добровольно согласились укрепить защиту прав интеллектуальной собственности, когда их экономика стала достаточно инновационной, также и Китай будет стремиться к защите прав интеллектуальной собственности.

Resumen:

RESUMEN:

Este artículo responde a los recientes llamados por investigación organizacional para abordar cuestiones más amplias y relevantes a nivel mundial y prestar atención a la historia, analizando el debate fundamental sobre los derechos de propiedad intelectual (DPI) entre los Estados Unidos y China. Pese a la reciente posición estadounidense, Estados Unidos no siempre ha sido un defensor líder de los DPI. En cambio, ha sido un líder violando los DPI durante el siglo XIX. Una perspectiva basada en instituciones de la historia de los DPI sugiere que tanto la negativa de los Estados Unidos para proteger las demandas de los DPI extranjeros en el siglo XIX como la falta actual de entusiasmo de China para acatar las demandas de DPI de los Estados Unidos representa opciones racionales. Sin embargo, a medida que el análisis de costo-beneficio evoluciona, las transiciones institucionales son posible. Predecimos que en la misma medida en que los Estados Unidos acordaron voluntariamente fortalecer la protección de los DPI cuando su economía se volviera suficientemente impulsada por la innovación, China similarmente va a mejorar su protección de los DPI.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The International Association for Chinese Management Research 2017 

INTRODUCTION

A leading debate in contemporary US-China relations centers on intellectual property rights (IPR). Given the scope and scale of potential IPR violations in China,Footnote [1] the United States has frequently sought improved IPR protection in China and has been frustrated by the lack of progress, in spite of recent improvements. What does the future of IPR protection in China hold? Despite the obvious importance of the IPR debate, it has attracted little attention from organizational scholars – and little coverage in the pages of Management and Organization Review (MOR). Do organizational scholars such as those in the MOR/International Association for Chinese Management Research (IACMR) community have anything to contribute to the debate over IPR?

Responding to recent calls for organizational research to address larger, more globally relevant questions (Davis, Reference Davis2015; Lewin, Reference Lewin2015) and to pay attention to history (Ahlstrom, Lamond, & Ding, Reference Ahlstrom, Lamond and Ding2009; Barley, Reference Barley2016), we argue that a key to predicting the future development of IPR lies in a deeper understanding of history, which can help to clear up misconceptions. For example, many take for granted that the United States is a leading IPR champion and China a leading IPR violator. Yet ironically, as recently as in the nineteenth century, the United States was a leading IPR violator (Raustiala & Sprigman, Reference Raustiala and Sprigman2012, Reference Raustiala and Sprigman2013). Between the founding of the United States in 1776 and the enactment of the Chace Act in 1891, pirating British publications (such as books) and entertainment (such as stage plays) was widely practiced by numerous Americans to make a living (and a ‘killing’) (Lohr, Reference Lohr2002). This article endeavors to demonstrate how history can help to identify patterns and further resonates with the recent call for international comparisons to better understand how history matters (Friedman & Jones, Reference Friedman and Jones2011).

Leveraging an institution-based view of IPR protection (Peng, Reference Peng2013; Peng, Ahlstrom, Carraher, & Shi, Reference Peng, Ahlstrom, Carraher and Shi2017), we focus on why US institutions supported IPR violation initially. Next, we investigate why US institutions later changed to ban such piracy. How the United States went from being a leading IPR violator to a leading IPR champion is a fascinating chapter in history that, we argue, can help inform the modern debate over IPR. In doing so, we respond to recent calls for organizational researchers to address larger, more globally relevant questions with societal ramifications (Davis, Reference Davis2015: 186; Lewin, Reference Lewin2015: 2) via ‘significant historical research’ as a way forward (Ahlstrom & Wang, Reference Ahlstrom and Wang2009; Barley, Reference Barley2016: 6).

THE INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW

The institution-based view is part of a broader intellectual movement centered on the new institutionalism throughout the social sciences. Organizational scholars have increasingly realized that institutions are more than background conditions (Meyer & Peng, Reference Meyer and Peng2016; Peng, Reference Peng2003). Instead, ‘institutions directly determine what arrows a firm has in its quiver as it struggles to formulate and implement strategy’ (Ingram & Silverman, Reference Ingram, Silverman, Ingram and Silverman2002: 20). Consequently, an institution-based view has emerged (Ahuja & Yayavaram, Reference Ahuja and Yayavaram2011; Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015; Peng, Wang, & Jiang, Reference Peng, Wang and Jiang2008). Further development can benefit from following well-accepted research designs of history research – ‘probing over long periods of time and finding commonalities among institutions’ (Wren, Reference Wren1987: 341).

The institution-based view in the organizational literature (Ahuja & Yaravaram, Reference Ahuja and Yayavaram2011; Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015; Peng, Sun, Pinkham, & Chen, Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009) has roots in sociological institutionalism (DiMaggio & Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983; Scott, Reference Scott2014) and economic institutionalism (North, Reference North1990; Williamson, Reference Williamson1985) as well as allied fields such as political science (Hall & Taylor, Reference Hall and Taylor1996; Pierson, Reference Pierson2004). Authors in the organizational field often take an integrative approach, drawing from various disciplines (Ahuja & Yayavaram, Reference Ahuja and Yayavaram2011: 1633; Peng, Reference Peng2003: 276; Peng et al., Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009: 64), which is the approach followed here.

The ‘rules of the game’ (North, Reference North1990), an institution's most fundamental role is to reduce uncertainty and provide meaning (Scott, Reference Scott2014). The institution-based view ‘focuses on the dynamic interaction between institutions and organizations and considers strategic choices as the outcome of such an interaction’ (Peng et al., Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009: 66). In other words, institutions are ‘both constraints and facilitators’ on the decisions and behavior of organizations (Ahuja & Yayavaram, Reference Ahuja and Yayavaram2011: 1633).

A leading proposition of the institution-based view is that individuals (such as managers, policymakers, and consumers) and organizations (such as government departments and firms) ‘rationally pursue their interests and make strategic choices within the formal and informal constraints in a given institutional framework’ (Peng et al., Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009: 67). Of course, the rationality discussed here is bounded rationality (Williamson, Reference Williamson1985). Individuals and organizations are assumed to be ‘intendedly rational, but only limitedly so’ (Simon, Reference Simon1961: xxiv). Often associated with institutional economics, this rational choice school is one of the three major schools of thought within the institutionalism literature – the other two are sociological and historical (Hall & Taylor, Reference Hall and Taylor1996; Pierson, Reference Pierson2004).

Sociological institutionalism focuses more on the mimetic pressures from isomorphism and the meaning provided by institutions (DiMaggio & Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983; Scott, Reference Scott2014). Historical institutionalism argues that historical contexts shape institutions, which create path dependencies that are difficult to break (Arthur, Reference Arthur1994; David, Reference David1985; Steinmo, Thelen, & Longstreth, Reference Steinmo, Thelen and Longstreth1992). While there is theoretical tension among these three schools of thought, they may ‘be more complementary and less competitive than we realize’ (Pierson, Reference Pierson2004: 131; see also Peng et al., Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009: 64; Ahuja & Yayavaram, Reference Ahuja and Yayavaram2011: 1633). In an effort to propel organizational research further, the institution-based view aspires to draw from the best insights from these three forms of institutionalism – rational choice, sociological, and historical (Hall & Taylor, Reference Hall and Taylor1996). Before examining the institutions underpinning IPR protection, it may be useful to first discuss two ‘popular’ explanations concerning IPR in China: culture and politics.

THE CULTURE AND POLITICS BEHIND IPR IN CHINA

Today, China's IPR laws are generally well-crafted and have pushed a lot of IPR violation under ground (Chow, Reference Chow2003; IP Commission, 2013; Yu, Reference Yu, Dutfeld and Suthersanen2014b). However, enforcement continues to be weak. Despite some progress, repeated negotiations between the United States and China have not produced satisfactory headway. In the context of the contemporary US-China IPR debate, a fundamental puzzle is why China does not pay sufficient attention to IPR protection and why so many Chinese firms and individuals are willingly engaged in piracy, counterfeiting, and other acts of IPR violation (Yu, Reference Yu and Hansen2008). Various debate points can boil down to two popular explanations: culture and politics.

The cultural argument fingers Chinese culture, dating back 2500 years to Confucianism, for a major weakness: a lack of respect for IPR. For example, the title of Alford's (1995) influential book – To Steal a Book is an Elegant Offense: Intellectual Property Law in Chinese Civilization –sums it well. Suttmeier and Yao (Reference Suttmeier and Yao2011: 19) further add that ‘Chinese culture still seems to have trouble valuing intangible assets.’ As culture generally changes slowly (Hofstede, Reference Hofstede2007), though there is some debate about this (McCloskey, Reference McCloskey2016), if it were the main driver of behavior concerning IPR, then it would be difficult to envision better IPR protection in China in the absence of significant changes to its culture.

However, is China the only country that has shown disrespect for IPR? The answer is no (Robinson, Reference Robinson2016). Enough examples exist to refute the notion that IPR violation is driven by certain deeply held, largely invariant cultural values (Peng, Reference Peng2013). In China's pre-Qin period (before 221 BCE), traditional Chinese scholars despised the act of plagiarism (Feng, Reference Feng2007). Numerous swings in IPR protection also occurred in Europe since the Roman Empire where plagiarism (such as appropriating poems and plays) was common (Bugbee, Reference Bugbee1967; Jaffe & Lerner, Reference Jaffe and Lerner2007). Significant violation and theft of IP were regularly noted in the Middle Ages as well (Jaffe & Lerner, Reference Jaffe and Lerner2007).Footnote [2] For example, in the fifteenth century, the Dutch busied themselves making counterfeit Chinese porcelain (Johns, Reference Johns2009).

In the twentieth century, 1960s Japan was a global leader for counterfeit goods. In the 1970s and 1980s, Taiwan, South Korea, and Hong Kong grabbed this dubious distinction (Kumar, Reference Kumar2003; Peng, Reference Peng2013), and recent music piracy has involved people from practically every country (Hill, Reference Hill2007). For example, Russia is now home to some of the most notorious piracy websites in the world (Galtsova, Reference Galtsova2008: 21). Clearly, IPR violation is not unique to China. The more abstract argument about a Confucian value system driving IPR violation does not stand up well to scrutiny.

A political school of thought in this debate suggests that ‘Chinese political culture does not lend itself to the concept of IP ownership’ (Zimmerman, Reference Zimmerman2013: 142). During the Mao era in China, the emphasis on public (state) ownership was directly at odds with the emphasis on private rights inherent in IPR (Lubman, Reference Lubman1999). During the subsequent reform period, China's decentralized political structure encouraged local protectionism. This made IPR protection more problematic (Chow, Reference Chow2003; Mertha, Reference Mertha2007; Poncet, Reference Poncet2005). Although the IPR laws on the books now look impressive and are (mostly) compatible with WTO (2009) mandates, it is the weak enforcement that is often fingered as contributing to the unsatisfactory IPR protection.

However, in 2008 during the Beijing Olympics, the sale of fake Olympic merchandise completely disappeared (Yu, Reference Yu, Calboli and Lee2014a). Similar successes were achieved during the Asian Games in Guangzhou in 2010 and the Summer Youth Olympics in Nanjing in 2014. Did the counterfeiters become more patriotic? Or did the government demonstrate that effective protection of IPR was possible, once it was given political priority? Regardless of the answer, clearly the Chinese can be politically motivated and organizationally capable of eradicating IPR violation if so inclined. Thus, the political argument – just like the cultural argument – can also be rejected. Instead, when there is a will, there is a way.

THE INSTITUTIONS BEHIND IPR IN CHINA

As ‘rules of the game,’ IPR institutions provide the incentive structures that affect the costs of doing business – in this case the costs of engaging via-a-vis the costs of not engaging in piracy and counterfeiting (Peng, Reference Peng2013; Peng et al., Reference Peng, Ahlstrom, Carraher and Shi2017; Yu, Reference Yu, Calboli and Lee2014a). Given weak IPR protection (and weak enforcement if caught), thousands of firms and tens of thousands of individuals have made rational decisions (from their standpoint at least) to engage in piracy and counterfeiting (Hill, Reference Hill2007; Li, Reference Li2004). Stronger IP protection such as criminalizing all counterfeiting activities – instead of only criminalizing large scale counterfeiting above a certain threshold – is likely to significantly reduce counterfeiters’ incentives. Between 2007 and 2009, the WTO adjudicated the dispute between the United States and China (Yu, Reference Yu and Hansen2008, Reference Yu2011). The United States advocated a ‘zero tolerance’ approach. China insisted on a ‘threshold’ approach, which would only penalize violations above the threshold of ‘large scale’ (or using the WTO vocabulary, ‘commercial scale’). While the WTO (2009) respected China's threshold approach and the United States did not win, China's reluctance to criminalize all IPR violations was evident. A lingering question is: Why?

The institution-based view first highlights the path dependent nature of IPR development (North, Reference North1990). Path dependence maintains that the choices one faces for any given circumstance are limited by related decisions made in the past, even though past circumstances may no longer be relevant (David, Reference David1985). Earlier practices and initial conditions of potentially not paying enough attention to IPR thus cast a long shadow.

Second, when viewed from a relatively long span of three decades, China's IPR system ‘has indeed come a very long way’ (Yu, Reference Yu2013: 88). It essentially started from scratch in 1985 (Lubman, Reference Lubman1999). Handling over one million patent applications annually since 2010 (Suttmeier & Yao, Reference Suttmeier and Yao2011), China already has the world's largest volume of domestic patent applications (The Economist, 2014: 73) and it is now one of the world's leaders in filing international (ICT) patent applications (Yu, Reference Yu2013: 88). While China's IPR regulations are fundamentally compatible with the letter of the expectations of the WTO and its sister organization, World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), critics note that their enforcement, however, does not appear to meet the spirit of such expectations.

Finally, institutional transitions moving toward a more effective IPR protection and enforcement regime have both costs and benefits (Mazzoleni & Nelson, Reference Mazzoleni and Nelson1998; Moser, Reference Moser2013; Peng, Reference Peng2003, Reference Peng2013). Given widespread scholarly diffusion, explicit international pressures, and initial legal reforms, it is unlikely that Chinese policymakers, managers, and scholars are not aware of the innovation-boosting benefits of better IPR protection (Abrami, Kirby, & McFarlan, Reference Abrami, Kirby and McFarlan2014; Lewin, Kenney, & Murmann, Reference Lewin, Kenney and Murmann2016; McKinsey, 2015; Yu, Reference Yu and Hansen2008). However, even for proven violations, current law generally imposes a maximum fine of one million RMB ($160,000) – only in a small number of cases when the loss to the plaintiff and income of the defendant are difficult to assess can the judge award damages greater than one million RMB. However, the average award is only 190,000 RMB ($30,000), which is hardly enough to deter violations and that may not even cover legal costs (McKinsey, 2015: 115). Why does China not significantly increase the maximum fine for IPR violations? The reluctance seems to stem from the concern that at this early stage of China's development, satisfying US IPR demands may result in foreign (and primarily US) IP rights holders benefiting more (Liang & Xue, Reference Liang and Xue2010: 490; Yu, Reference Yu2013: 97). In short, costs may exceed benefits.

How does the future of IPR protection look in China? We argue that the history of IPR development in the United States identifies interesting historical parallels and offers a great deal of insights to help inform today's debate.

THE UNITED STATES AS AN IPR VIOLATORFootnote [3]

Although widely known to scholars (Chaudhry & Zimmerman, Reference Chaudhry and Zimmerman2009: 175; Khan, Reference Khan2013: 67; Lopes & Casson, Reference Lopes and Casson2012: 308; Raustiala & Sprigman, Reference Raustiala and Sprigman2013: 29), the US experience as a leading IPR violator during the nineteenth century is seldom mentioned as a part of the modern IPR discourse. It is important to note that we are not offering a radical revision or reinterpretation of the US IPR history in the nineteenth century. Our characterization of the United States as an IPR violator follows the mainstream views of historians who specialize in this era (Gordon, Reference Gordon2005; Khan, Reference Khan2005).

Similar to our earlier rejection of the cultural and political arguments in the contemporary IPR debate (such as the Chinese culture was not aware of the importance of IPR and the Chinese polity was not capable of offering IPR protection), we can also reject the cultural and political arguments concerning nineteenth-century America. From its founding, the United States had a conceptualization of IPR and a formal system of IPR protection. George Washington, in his first inaugural speech, encouraged a system of protection for inventors. Abraham Lincoln, the only US president to hold a patent, was a strong proponent of IPR. Adopted in 1787, the Constitution of the United States included a provision for protecting IPR in Article I, Section 8:

The Congress shall have Power. . . To promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries.

However, such IPR protection only protected US authors and inventors. Section 5 of the 1790 Copyright Act explicitly stated (Yu, Reference Yu, Dutfeld and Suthersanen2014b: 9):

Nothing in this Act shall be construed to extend to prohibit the importation or vending, reprinting or publishing within the United States, of any map, chart, book or books, written, printed, or published by any person not a citizen of the United States, in foreign parts or place without the jurisdiction of the United States.

In short, foreign intellectual property was up for grabs.Footnote [4] During much of the nineteenth century, American pirates were busy knocking off secret British designs for looms and mills, while producers and publishers extensively pirated foreign publications, art, and drama (Khan & Sokoloff, Reference Khan and Sokoloff2001: 237). The US government ‘stood ready to help them’ (Raustiala & Sprigman, Reference Raustiala and Sprigman2013: 29).

Even American author Edgar Allan Poe got into the piracy game. The only book Poe published that was successful enough to be reprinted during his lifetime was not House of Usher or Rue Morgue, but The Conchologist's First Book (or A System of Testaceous Malacology, Arranged Expressly for the Use of Schools – a Textbook on Molluscs first published in 1839) (Gould, Reference Gould1993; Quinn, Reference Quinn1998). This was because Poe and his coauthor plagiarized works by British authors and such plagiarism was quickly discovered. Poe admitted as much in his own writings, but with no international copyright agreement, the original British publisher had no recourse (Gould, Reference Gould1993).

During Charles Dickens’ visit to the United States in 1842, he was appalled by the ubiquitous pirating of his work. He called for better protection of IPR. However, the US media, which regularly pirated British works, serialized novels, and other content, contended that Dickens should be appreciative for his popularity and that he was greedy to complain about his work being pirated (Tomalin, Reference Tomalin2011: 128–132).

There was no shortage of British critics such as Dickens who lamented that the American culture –historically centered on lawlessness and rebellion (from a British standpoint) – might have been hopeless in improving IPR protection (Tomalin, Reference Tomalin2011). Moreover, painful and fruitless IPR negotiations between Britain and the United States led many British commentators to conclude that Americans were politically unwilling to protect IPR. These cultural and political arguments were similar to those invoked to explain the apparent ‘hopelessness’ of the recent IPR situation in China.

From an institution-based view, we argue that the US refusal to protect foreign IPR (prior to 1891) was rational. Given the lower levels of literary and economic development, benefits from the protection of foreign IPR would simply accrue to foreign inventors, authors, and firms (such as British publishers), while domestic consumers had to shoulder higher costs for books, media products, and innovative goods. In path dependence terms, institutions such as those supporting the violation of foreign IPR, once in place, would be hard to change (Arthur, Reference Arthur1994). However, institutions do change – as illustrated in the next section.

INSTITUTIONAL TRANSITIONS IN THE UNITED STATES

Institutions can change (Campbell, Reference Campbell2004). Institutional isomorphism asserts pressures on individuals, organizations, and even nation-states to conform, thus triggering the long-term processes for institutional transitions (DiMaggio & Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983). In the long run, development of informal institutions such as clear norms on what are legitimate behaviors can be identified (Scott, Reference Scott2014). Sometimes, ‘nation-states, subject to only modest coercion or control, adopt standard identities and structural forms’ (Meyer, Boli, Thomas, & Ramirez, Reference Meyer, Boli, Thomas and Ramirez1997: 174).Footnote [5] In the IPR arena, nineteenth-century America and twentieth-first-century China did eventually switch from violating to respecting IPR – at least in terms of formal law-making. In 1891, to the pleasant surprise of British critics, the United States voluntarily strengthened its IPR laws with the passing of the International Copyright Act (commonly known as the Chace Act after its sponsor, Senator Jonathan Chace from Rhode Island), which extended IPR protection to foreign works. What was the cause for such a major institutional transition in the US IPR regime?

Foreign (primarily British) pressures played a role behind the enactment of the Chace Act. However, given the repeated US refusals to British demands prior to 1891, such coercion was likely not the main driver of change. A more significant driving force behind such a transformation was likely the pressures from numerous indigenous inventors, authors, and organizations within the United States. As the close of the nineteenth century approached, the United States had turned from being a net consumer to a net producer of intellectual products (Fisher, Reference Fisher1999; Khan & Sokoloff, Reference Khan and Sokoloff2001, Reference Khan and Sokoloff2004). As more American authors, publishers, and producers were eager to market their products overseas (a leading market was Britain and the British Empire), they naturally desired better IPR protection from foreign governments (Thompson, Reference Thompson1986). However, in the absence of reciprocity, foreign governments were unwilling to grant US rights holders IPR protection. They would only offer IPR protection for US rights holders if the United States offered equivalent protection to non-US IP rights holders in the United States.

Further, in the late nineteenth century, American IP was being increasingly pirated elsewhere – especially in Canada. Similar to the Americans, the Canadians offered IPR protection to domestic (Canadian and British Empire) inventors, authors, and publishers, but did not offer IPR protection to foreigners (essentially Americans). Thus, pirating US publications was widespread in Canada, causing an uproar among American publishers and writers such as Mark Twain.Footnote [6] Given these changing winds, it was rational to start offering IPR protection in the United States to foreign authors and inventors. Essentially, the costs of offering local protection to foreign IPR were thought to be outweighed by the benefits of having American IPR protected overseas.

In other words, piracy ‘promoted domestic publishing output’ in nineteenth-century America (Khan, Reference Khan2013: 67, emphasis added). For nineteenth-century America and many developing economies today, strong IPR ‘to primarily protect the rights of foreigners hindered their ability to imitate the technologies of the advanced countries and to learn by doing’ (Khan, Reference Khan2013: 68). A cost-benefit analysis suggests that only when the US economy (especially its IP production) was strong enough could the United States afford to offer IPR protection to foreigners (Raustiala & Sprigman, Reference Raustiala and Sprigman2013: 29). Charles Dickens would probably be turning in his grave if he heard that the leading pirating nation of his time, the United States, had become a leading IPR advocate recently.

THE SWEET AND SOUR HISTORY OF US IPR PROTECTIONFootnote [7]

Institutional transitions do not take place over night and do not necessarily unfold in a linear fashion (North, Reference North1990; Scott, Reference Scott2014). Twists, turns, and setbacks are likely. Even after major transitions such as the 1891 Chace Act, two episodes stand out: (1) the complaint that US patent law was ‘over protecting’ German chemical firms and (2) the US refusal to protect fashion design as IPR.

US-German Rivalry in the Chemical Industry

As two rapidly developing economies, the United States and Germany engaged in strong rivalry prior to 1914. Competition in the innovation-driven chemical industry was especially intense (Chandler, Reference Chandler1990). Between 1900 and 1910, the United States granted 4,068 patents to chemical and related inventions. Two-thirds of them went to four leading German firms – Badische Anilin und Soda-Fabrik (BASF), Bayer (Farbenfabriken), Hoechst, and IG Farben (Khan, Reference Khan2013: 64). German firms dominated the market for innovations in dyes and chemicals, and used patent rights to foreclose on US rivals. Many US managers and policymakers complained that when the US chemical industry was still an ‘infant industry’, such (overly) strong IPR protection of globally competitive German rivals – thanks to the 1891 Chace Act – prevented US firms from producing knock-off products. In short, such ‘over protection’ made German rivals stronger and conversely the fledgling US firms weaker.

Only the confiscation (without compensation) of German IPR in 1917 consisting of several thousand patents, trademarks, and copyrights as well as German corporate assets – thanks to the US entry into World War I (WWI) and an amendment of the Trading with Enemy Act – did the competitiveness of the US chemical industry improve significantly (Khan, Reference Khan2013). Specifically, such IPR violation resulted in a 20% increase in US domestic inventions during and in the aftermath of WWI (Moser & Voena, Reference Moser and Voena2012). However, despite such a ‘windfall stock’ of German IPR, the absorptive capacity of US firms was still limited (Khan, Reference Khan2013: 64). After WWI, German firms were able to regain their former competitive advantage in dyes and chemicals.

US-French Competition in the Fashion Industry

From the beginning of the fashion industry, France has developed a number of leading firms and the United States has had numerous imitators, copycats, and pirates (Pouillard, Reference Pouillard2011). While one can debate the creativity differences between fashion industry practitioners in the two countries, from an important but often overlooked institution-based view, we need to realize the crucial institutional differences governing this industry. French copyright law protected fashion design, while US copyright law did not and still does not offer such protection (Pouillard, Reference Pouillard2011). Prior to WWII, making sketches at the Paris fashion openings was forbidden by French law. Nevertheless, numerous Americans attended such fashion shows and sketched the designs from memory right after the shows. They then illegally sold such unauthorized copies to American designers in New York, who would start copying the designs immediately.

The efforts made by French fashion houses and their legal US importers (typically high-end retailers) to stop such copying, which was illegal in France but legal in the United States, were difficult. In 1930, a bill outlawing such copying passed the House of Representatives but failed to pass the Senate. Viewed as counter to the American ideal of social equality, the bill, according to its critics, would ‘take away from the poor working girl the right to wear the same pattern of goods that the wealthy people do’ (Pouillard, Reference Pouillard2011: 331). Further, opponents argued that copying pushed American designers to innovate and that such piracy boosted economic growth (Pouillard, Reference Pouillard2011: 343–344). Today the debate continues to rage. A recent effort was the Design Piracy Prohibition Act sponsored by Representative Robert Goodlatte from Virginia, which was debated by the US Congress in 2011. But it failed to pass.

Analysis of the Two US Episodes

Overall, the sweet and sour history of IPR protection in the United States – both before and after the enactment of the 1891 Chace Act – has been neither linear nor comprehensive. From an institution-based view, the path dependence of not respecting (certain) foreign IPR is evident in the efforts to expropriate German IPR during WWI and in the continued refusal to protect fashion design at the expense of the French fashion industry. The processes are indeed long term – several decades after 1891 for the chemical industry and over a century (and still ongoing) for the fashion industry. But despite such industry-specific exceptions, generally speaking, post-1891 institutional transitions in IPR protection have certainly resulted in significantly improved IPR protection in the United States.

Informed by the institution-based view, our historical examination has revealed that (1) the United States engaged in significant IPR violation when its economy was taking off, and (2) the development of admittedly better US IPR protection in recent times has been neither linear nor comprehensive. Next, we use the same institution-based lens to shed light on two recent IPR developments in China.

TWO RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN CHINA

The Surge of IPR Proclamations, Patenting, and Litigation

Far from being an IPR ‘backwater’, since the beginning of the 2000s, China has become one of the most eager countries in promoting innovation and IPR (Abrami et al., Reference Abrami, Kirby and McFarlan2014; Cao, Li, Li, & Liu, Reference Cao, Li, Li and Liu2013; Cheng & Huang, Reference Cheng, Huang, Lewin, Kenney and Murmann2016; Hu & Mathews, Reference Hu and Mathews2008; Lewin et al., Reference Lewin, Kenney and Murmann2016; Li, Reference Li2012; Liu, Simon, Sun, & Cao, Reference Liu, Simon, Sun and Cao2011; Williamson & Yin, Reference Williamson and Yin2014). According to the National Patent Development Strategy (SIPO, 2010):

By 2020, China will become a country with a comparatively high level in terms of the creation, utilization, protection, and administration of patents. . . The quantity of patents for inventions for every 1 million people, and the quantity of patent applications in foreign countries will quadruple (3). . . By 2015, the annual quantity of applications for patents for inventions, utility models and designs will reach 2 million. China will rank among the top two in the world in terms of the annual number of patents on inventions granted to domestic applicants and the quality of patents filed will further improve (4).

Despite the overwhelmingly negative Western media coverage of IPR violation in China, it is difficult to argue that the Chinese government is not serious about IPR (Cao et al., Reference Cao, Li, Li and Liu2013; Hu & Mathews, Reference Hu and Mathews2008; Lewin et al., Reference Lewin, Kenney and Murmann2016; Yu, Reference Yu and Hansen2008). Total patent applications in China jumped from 476,000 in 2005 to over 1.2 million in 2010 (Suttmeier & Yao, Reference Suttmeier and Yao2011: 13). Today China is the world champion in the number of patent applications (The Economist, 2014: 73). While the quality of Chinese patents (such as numerous alleged ‘junk patents’) may be questioned (Cheng & Huang, Reference Cheng, Huang, Lewin, Kenney and Murmann2016; The Economist, 2014), some scholars suggest that it ‘may not be a serious concern’ (Li, Reference Li2012: 236; see Boeing, Mueller, & Sander, Reference Boeing, Mueller and Sander2016).Footnote [8] At least in terms of volume, China's patent system ‘has arguably accomplished what no other patent system in the world has ever achieved’ (Yu, Reference Yu2013: 88).

Given the domestic and international complaints about the lack of IPR expertise among judges, China has recently set up a system of specialized IP courts led by judges specifically trained in IPR enforcement. As a result, IPR litigation has skyrocketed. Table 1 shows 38,945 IPR civil cases in 2010 (most of which involving Chinese plaintiffs suing other alleged Chinese IPR violators).Footnote [9] In comparison, the United States had 6,658 such cases. In 2013, the number of IPR case adjudicated in China reached over 100,000 (McKinsey, 2015: 115). China has become the world's most litigious country with respect to IPR – measured by the number of IPR litigation cases (Suttmeier & Yao, Reference Suttmeier and Yao2011: 13).

Table 1. IPR civil cases in China and the United States

Source: Extracted from data reported in Suttmeier, R. P., & Yao, X. 2011. China's IP transition: Rethinking intellectual property rights in a rising China (13). NBR Special Report 29. Seattle: National Bureau of Asian Research.

Analysis of China's Surge of IPR Proclamations, Patenting, and Litigation

What can explain China's transformation from long-time reluctance to recent eagerness in promoting IPR? From an institution-based view, this development deviates from path dependence. This is why it is labeled ‘counterintuitive’ by Suttmeier and Yao (Reference Suttmeier and Yao2011: 5). Historical forces generally constrain contemporary laws and practices to be similar to past ones (Klochikhin, Reference Klochikhin2012). But exogenous influences and endogenous changes to institutions are possible and can modify a seemingly entrenched path (Greif & Laitin, Reference Greif and Laitin2004).

As the self-reinforcing aspects of the informal institutional regime are gradually undermined by changes in the environment, both endogenous and exogenous changes are enabled. One endogenous element of this change in the United States was paradoxically a push by the railroads in the 1870s to make patenting more difficult and narrow (Usselman, Reference Usselman, Lamoreaux, Raff and Temin1999). Some inventions were thought to be small incremental changes and should fall under the purview of trade secrets within firms and not IP. This debate eventually did lead to the tightening of IP laws, in spite of the railroads’ protests. China has started to experience similar debates about IP and its optimal scope given its current level of development (Suttmeier & Yao, Reference Suttmeier and Yao2011).

The long-term institutional processes of enhancing legitimacy have asserted their influence – thanks to foreign pressures as well as an increase in invention by firms and citizens and gradual recognition from the public of its value (Sokoloff & Khan, Reference Sokoloff and Khan1990). This increasingly accumulated momentum and court cases have led to a gradual appreciation of the wider benefits of strengthened IPR protection.

Over time, the cost-benefit analysis underpinning institutional transitions becomes evident (Greif & Laitin, Reference Greif and Laitin2004; Peng, Reference Peng2003). Figure 1 illustrates the costs and benefits of IPR protection and enforcement institutions. Setting up such institutions is costly. During time 1, the costs of better IPR protection and enforcement outweigh the benefits – at least viewed from the perspective of domestic Chinese firms (a situation almost identical to nineteenth-century America). Over time, both the Chinese government and firms have realized more sustained economic growth will increasingly need to draw on IPR (Cao et al., Reference Cao, Li, Li and Liu2013; Lewin et al., Reference Lewin, Kenney and Murmann2016; Liu et al., Reference Liu, Simon, Sun and Cao2011). Past time 2 (the proverbial ‘crossover point’ [Yu, Reference Yu2013] or ‘point of inflection’ [Peng, Reference Peng2003]), enhanced IPR protection and enforcement will be more beneficial, thus motivating the emergence of stronger IPR institutions (such as specialized IPR courts), which in turn fuel the more extensive use of these institutions (as evidenced by the rising number of IPR litigation cases). In sum, institutional transitions fostering stronger IPR in a country known for IPR violation is possible –as long as stakeholders such as policymakers, managers, consumers, lawyers, and judges believe they can ‘do better’ in a new environment (North, Reference North1990: 8).

Figure 1. The costs and benefits of IPR protection and enforcement institutions

The Promotion of ‘Indigenous Innovation’

If the first new development of improved and widely accepted IPR institutions is encouraging, a second development – the Chinese government's promotion of ‘indigenous innovation’ – has attracted significant criticism, especially from the international business community (IP Commission, 2013; USTR, 2010). China's first ever National Patent Development Strategy stated:

The level of self-relied intellectual property will be higher by a large margin and the quantity of intellectual property will be greater. China will rank among the advanced countries of the world in terms of the annual number of patents for inventions granted to the domestic applicants, while the number of overseas patent applications filed by Chinese applicants should greatly increase. A number of world-famous brands will emerge. The proportion of the GDP accounted for by the value of core copyright industries will greatly increase (SIPO, 2010: 2).

Such an explicit emphasis on indigenous innovation has been criticized by US and foreign rights holders as well as their governments. These sentiments are summarized by the US Trade Representative in the 2010 National Trade Estimate Report on Foreign Trade Barriers:

A troubling trend that has emerged. . . is China's willingness to encourage domestic or ‘indigenous’ innovation at the cost of foreign innovation and technologies. . . In order to qualify as ‘indigenous’ innovation under the accreditation system, and therefore be entitled to procurement preferences, a product's intellectual property must originally be registered in China (USTR, 2010: 69).

Analysis of China's Promotion of ‘Indigenous Innovation’

The institution-based view can again contribute to a better understanding of this development. First, just like the case of US chemical and fashion industries, the path dependent nature of protecting domestic firms in certain industries is hard to break off from in China – even after significant commitments are made to enhance IPR protection (Howell, Reference Howell2015).

Second, being aware of the long-term processes, we caution against a ‘knee-jerk’ reaction of harsh criticism (as reflected in USTR [2010]). Instead, we advocate a more nuanced reading of history. Specifically, history suggests that US policies regarding foreign IPR during much of the nineteenth century (prior to the 1891 Chace Act) can be regarded as US ‘indigenous innovation policies’. One lesson from history is that such policies ‘may help encourage the development of local stakeholders’ as advocates of stronger IPR protection and enforcement (Yu, Reference Yu2013: 91; see also Jandhyala, Reference Jandhyala2015: 287). Recall that it was the emergence of a critical mass of indigenous stakeholders such as US publishers, authors (such as Mark Twain), and inventors (such as Eli Whitney), who decisively pushed the US government to promote stronger IPR protection. Encouragingly, a new generation of indigenous stakeholders interested in better IPR protection is emerging in China. Jack Ma, founder of Alibaba, has called counterfeit goods a ‘cancer’ and vowed to mobilize both Alibaba and other stakeholders to fight counterfeit goods (The Economist, 2016: 52).

Finally, an interest in fostering institutional transitions offers a counterintuitive suggestion that the US government, US rights holders, as well as the international business community assist China to strengthen its indigenous innovation policies. This is because fostering China's indigenous innovation policies is compatible with initiating cognitive beliefs about the value of IPR and the need to protect it. It is also compatible with the long-run goal of improving IPR protection for all firms in China – both Chinese and foreign. To do this, foreign governments can help the Chinese government to create more uniform IPR laws and encourage their consistent enforcement around the country (Poncet, Reference Poncet2005).

DISCUSSION

Contributions

This article endeavors to respond to calls for organizational researchers to address broader, bigger issues of our times (Davis, Reference Davis2015; Lewin, Reference Lewin2015). Overall, at least two contributions emerge. First, we join Peng et al. (Reference Peng, Ahlstrom, Carraher and Shi2017) in demonstrating how history can be directly relevant in informing a crucial, ongoing debate. History can help to identify patterns and parallels that can inform present day explanations and provide potential propositions for future research, practice, and policy (Ferguson, Reference Ferguson1999). For example, Weber studied the history of the Roman Legions, the Prussian Army, and the Roman Catholic Church to develop his theory about effective organizing (Weber, Baehr, & Wells, Reference Weber, Baehr and Wells2002). Chandler (Reference Chandler1990) advocated research on firm strategy and structure by investigating major industrial firms in Britain, Germany, and the United States. Military history has long influenced the analysis and formulation of strategy (Ahlstrom et al., Reference Ahlstrom, Lamond and Ding2009). Extending such traditions of history research, our article suggests that historical variation is an important complement to contemporary cross-sectional variation in articulating conceptual issues (Jones & Khanna, Reference Jones and Khanna2006). Our approach also resonates with the recent call for an international comparison in better understanding how history matters (Friedman & Jones, Reference Friedman and Jones2011).

How generalizable is the American experience in the nineteenth century to today's China? Although the United States and China differ on a number of dimensions, the international exchange and diffusion of ideas and practices have scaled new heights recently (Paulson, Reference Paulson2015). Neither of these two countries – nor any other country for that matter – can evolve its own IPR institutions in total isolation. Institutional systems, especially formal ones, can have considerable influence on each other.Footnote [10] If we embrace a more global and longer view of history, we see that documented IPR violation started at least during the Roman times (Chaudhry & Zimmerman, Reference Chaudhry and Zimmerman2009), and that new laws and their enforcement contributed to improvements of IPR (Raustiala & Sprigman, Reference Raustiala and Sprigman2012; Yu, Reference Yu, Calboli and Lee2014a).

Second, by addressing and leveraging a specific episode of history, this article also enriches the institution-based view (Ahuja & Yayavaram, Reference Ahuja and Yayavaram2011; Meyer & Peng, Reference Meyer and Peng2016; Peng et al., Reference Peng, Wang and Jiang2008, Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009). Our historical excursion identifies the distinction and similarities in the course of events across time and location (Kieser, Reference Kieser1994). Some have argued that culture, and particularly Confucianism, is linked to weak IPR protection (Alford, Reference Alford1995). Our historical examination has revealed similar culture-based arguments made about a US ‘frontier culture’ of lawlessness in the appropriation of IP in the nineteenth century. Few would make the argument about a lawless frontier culture in US IPR today – except in the area of fashion where some French fashion houses continue to complain (Pouillard, Reference Pouillard2011). In spite of the concerns about IPR, China has clearly made strides in recent years.

Specifically, we argue that economic development in China will facilitate improved IPR protection as economic development in the United States did in the nineteenth century. The poorest countries allocate few resources to innovation and thus have little IPR to protect. As incomes grow to middle income levels, some inventive capacity tends to emerge, but competition remains based on imitation. As a result, the majority of economic and political interests prefer weak IPR protection. As an economy develops further, additional inventive capacity and demands for high-quality products emerge, and commercial lobbies form to demand effective protection – a domestic interest that coincides with the foreign interest in better IPR protection.

In summary, organizational research that addresses historical context is beneficial to theory development. This is because it does not allow complex phenomena such as the development IPR protection to be automatically attributed to culture or some other latent variable with little further explanation (Singh, Reference Singh2007), while avoiding limited, episodic understandings of such phenomena. By studying the history of IPR development in the United States, we can better identify and explain the potential parallels to China's current and future IPR development.

Policy and Practical Implications

Several public and business policy implications emerge (Khoury & Peng, Reference Khoury and Peng2011; Paulson, Reference Paulson2015). In terms of public policy, Raustiala and Sprigman suggest that ‘the United States should consider its own history as a pirate nation – and relax’ (2013: 30). With an historical mindset, it is possible to appreciate that the differences between the United States and China in the IPR debate are not as significant as certain media and trade groups may portray. A practical lesson from a greater appreciation of history is to look for similarities that can help overcome the differences (Yu, Reference Yu2011).

However, it is important to point out that certain groups benefit from an environment where the differences between the United States and China are magnified. ‘The more differences there are, the more valuable their expertise will become, and the more they can influence the policy and business debate’ (Yu, Reference Yu2011: 1128). When these differences are sharpened, important areas of potential cooperation – such as those dealing with China's indigenous innovation policies – become difficult. ‘The two countries will be worse off as a result’ (Yu, Reference Yu2011: 1128; see also Paulson, Reference Paulson2015).

Policymakers in China and other developing countries need to better arm themselves with a good command of the historical knowledge and to be aware of the crossover point – the point of inflection beyond which benefits will outweigh the costs of world-class IPR protection. The WTO requires that developing countries raise their IPR levels to the standard in force in more developed countries at the time of negotiation. However, by examining the welfare implications of protecting IPR and bringing technology transfer and tariffs into the equation, Naghavi (Reference Naghavi2007) argues that prior to the crossover point, following the highest standards in IPR protection is not necessarily ideal.

US managers who complain about IPR violation in China today can learn how British authors, composers, and firms dealt with counterfeiters in the United States and elsewhere over 100 years ago. ‘Litigation was normally a last resort. Private agreements with offenders were cheaper and quicker, both because they could be kept confidential and because they avoided unduly alarming consumers about quality or alerting them to the possibility of purchasing a substitute at a cheaper price’ (Lopes & Casson, Reference Lopes and Casson2012: 303). For example, nineteenth-century British composers Gilbert and Sullivan brought their entire troupe to New York to perform The Pirates of Penzance, and thus upstaged the theatrical pirates who had made so much money (without paying any royalties) from pirating Gilbert and Sullivan's previous smash hit, HMS Pinafore (Gould, Reference Gould1993). In contemporary China, numerous multinationals have been able to adapt to the Chinese IPR system and maximize their performance, leveraging a Gilbert-and-Sullivan-style pre-emptive strategy by bringing the innovation to China very early in its development (Liang & Xue, Reference Liang and Xue2010). Specifically, they file patents and trademarks – including Chinese-language trademarks – as soon as possible, and/or set up strategic alliances with dependable Chinese partners right away (Shi, Sun, Pinkham, & Peng, Reference Shi, Sun, Pinkham and Peng2014). Such aggressive activities in China ‘makes major patent infringement very difficult’ (Liang & Xue, Reference Liang and Xue2010: 491).

Managers in China who are currently involved in IPR violation need to be aware of the rapidly evolving institutional transitions toward better IPR protection. Although a ‘copycat’ strategy centered on IPR violation has been viable (Shenkar, Reference Shenkar2010), institutional transitions may make this strategy obsolete. The best managers expect strategy to shift over time by constantly deciphering changes in the ‘big picture’ (Peng, Reference Peng2003). That is why a good command of the historical knowledge of IPR evolution elsewhere in the world can be helpful. As institutional transitions unfold, the highest-performing firms seem to be those that convert the gains from an earlier strategy centered on IPR violation into value-adding capabilities that thrive on innovation. For example, Huawei, which was sued by Cisco for alleged IPR violation in 2003, has emerged as a leading innovator. It now routinely files one of the largest numbers of international patents among all firms in the world. On the other hand, ‘firms that fail to realize the passing of their time are likely to fall behind or go out of business’ (Peng, Reference Peng2003: 292).

Limitations and Future Research Directions

We have barely scratched the surface of IPR development in the United States, China, and elsewhere around the world. We have neither covered IPR development in other parts of today's developed economies (those in Europe such as Great Britain and Germany and those in Asia such as Japan and Korea), nor that in other parts of developing economies (such as Brazil and India). Following Peng et al. (Reference Peng, Ahlstrom, Carraher and Shi2017), new insights will certainly emerge when future historically oriented IPR research probes these areas.

Similarly, future research should also address abstract arguments about culture and its impact on important institutional variables. For example, the more abstract argument about a Confucian value system driving a unique form of Chinese IPR as some commentators have argued does not stand up well to either historical or analytical scrutiny. In particular, it fails to distinguish between Confucianism and a range of ethical teachings that have also influenced and continue to influence China's legal system and cultural milieu such as Taoism and Buddhism. The teachings in these systems are not in harmony with one another when it comes to IPR and other aspects of organizing (Ahlstrom & Wang, Reference Ahlstrom, Wang, Landström and Lohrke2010). This is not to say that culture does not matter, but scholars must be careful not to rush to cultural explanations before examining historical parallels, institutional developments, and other key processes that may be largely distinct from cultural values (Singh, Reference Singh2007).

CONCLUSION

How can history inform the debate on IPR? How can organizational scholars add to such an important debate? In short, history can be used both to understand the past and the present better and to make difficult decisions concerning the future in a more informed way (Neustadt & May, Reference Neustadt and May1986). Instead of strict path dependence, cultural determinism, or basic episodic assessment history helps to explain the past and the present, and suggests possible future directions given institutional constraints by assessing present-day events historically (Draper, Reference Draper1996; North, Reference North1990). Joining Peng et al. (Reference Peng, Ahlstrom, Carraher and Shi2017), this article has extended the institution-based view by demonstrating how the history of the United States transforming itself from a leading IPR violator to a leading IPR champion can be used to inform the contemporary US-China debate on IPR. Leveraging this period of US history, we predict that to the same extent that the United States voluntarily agreed to strengthen IPR protection when the US economy became sufficiently innovation-driven, China will similarly enhance its IPR protection. We further predict that when Chinese IPR are significantly violated abroad, China will become more serious about IPR protection. Therefore, we suggest that China's indigenous innovation policies need to be strengthened instead of discouraged by foreign IP rights holders, governments, and other stakeholders.

Footnotes

We thank Arie Lewin (Editor-in-Chief) for his encouragement and guidance. Earlier versions were presented at AAOM (Hong Kong, 2015); Copenhagen Business School; Hong Kong Baptist; HKUST; IACMR (Beijing, 2014; and Hangzhou, 2016); Renmin; Seattle; Shanghai Jiao Tong; Simon Fraser; Stockholm; Tsinghua; Universities of Newcastle, San Francisco, Sydney, and Texas at Dallas; Western Washington; and Xi'an Jiaotong. We thank Kevin Au, Michael Bond, Xiaoping Chen, Ping Deng, Tony Fang, Sam Garg, Steve Globerman, Syd Gray, Siggi Gudergan, Michael Jacobsen, Kwok Leung, J. T. Li, Jing Li, John Li, Peter Li, John Lin, Klaus Meyer, Bo Nielson, David Reid, Tom Roehl, Danny Shapiro, Pek-Hooi Soh, Hao Tan, Alain Verbeke, Cristina Vlas, David Whetton, Zhengzheng Xie, Xiaohua Yang, Jingtao Yi, Michael Young, Wu Zhan, and Jing Zhao for helpful discussions. This research has been supported by the Jindal Chair at UT Dallas.

[1] While we focus on China, numerous other countries have also been implicated by the United States Trade Representative (USTR, 2010) as IPR violators, such as Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Egypt, India, Israel, Mexico, Paraguay, Russia, Thailand, Turkey, Ukraine, and Venezuela (Chaudhry & Zimmerman, Reference Chaudhry and Zimmerman2009).

[2] For example, the Roman writer Vitruvius (257–180 BCE) revealed IP theft during a literary contest in Alexandria. While serving as a judge in the contest, Vitruvius determined that some poets in the contest had stolen the words and phrases of other writers. After being found out, the false poets were then tried, convicted, and disgraced (Bugbee, Reference Bugbee1967). Yet in spite of such occasional prosecutions in Rome and later in medieval Europe, there were few laws codifying IP protection in Roman and medieval times, and the prosecution of offenses tended to be ad hoc (Bugbee, Reference Bugbee1967).

[3] While we leverage the US experience, it is important to note that Germany, Japan, and numerous other developed countries were also significant IPR violators when their economies were taking off. However, ‘all the major imitators subsequently became leading economic powers, indicating an apparent connection between learning by imitation and economic growth’ (Lopes & Casson, Reference Lopes and Casson2012: 308).

[4] American inventors sometimes found their inventions violated by their countrymen as well. For example, Eli Whitney invented the Cotton Gin in 1793 and patented it in 1794 under America's new Patent Law. Although this invention revolutionized the US cotton industry, it proved impossible to enforce as competent carpenters were able to rapidly produce and sell knock-off Cotton Gins. Whitney spent years pursuing patent lawsuits, and not until 1807 was the patent properly enforced. Whitney would realize only about $100,000 ($2,000,000 today). Much of the money was donated from southern state governments thankful for his invention (Gordon, Reference Gordon2005).

[5] In addition to IPR, another visible area of long-term institutional isomorphism is the adoption of democracy, which has spread from 69 countries in the 1980s to 120 in the 2000s.

[6] Mark Twain had to establish residency in Canada in order to protect the copyright of his novel The Prince and the Pauper in Canada. Given the costs involved, few authors could possibly afford to do that.

[7] This title is inspired by Yu's (Reference Yu, Dutfeld and Suthersanen2014b) title: ‘The sweet and sour story of Chinese intellectual property rights’.

[8] The quality of many US patents can be similarly questioned. For example, BusinessWeek (2006: 60) reports that the United States is ‘awash in a sea of junk patents’.

[9] In China, about 3% of all recent civil IPR litigation involved a foreign party (Suttmeier & Yao, Reference Suttmeier and Yao2011: 34).

[10] For example, California contract law in terms of investment term sheets and related contractual agreements has impacted the practice and rules regarding venture capital and start-up firms around the world – including those in China (Ahlstrom, Bruton, & Yeh, Reference Ahlstrom, Bruton and Yeh2007; Bruton & Ahlstrom, Reference Bruton and Ahlstrom2003).

Accepted by: Editor-in-Chief Arie Y. Lewin

References

REFERENCES

Abrami, R. M., Kirby, W. C., & McFarlan, F. W. 2014. Why China can't innovate: And what it's doing about it. Harvard Business Review, 92 (3): 107111.Google Scholar
Ahlstrom, D., Bruton, G. D., & Yeh, K. S. 2007. Venture capital in China: Past, present, and future. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24 (3): 247268.Google Scholar
Ahlstrom, D., Lamond, D., & Ding, Z. 2009. Reexamining some management lessons from military history. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 26 (4): 617642.Google Scholar
Ahlstrom, D., & Wang, L. C. 2009. Groupthink and France's defeat in the 1940 campaign. Journal of Management History, 15(2): 159--177.Google Scholar
Ahlstrom, D., & Wang, L. C. 2010. Entrepreneurial capitalism in East Asia: How history matters. In Landström, H. & Lohrke, F. (Eds.), The historical foundations of entrepreneurial research: 406428. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Ahuja, G., & Yayavaram, S. 2011. Explaining influence rents: The case for an institution-based view of strategy. Organization Science, 22 (6): 1631–1652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alford, W. P. 1995. To steal a book is an elegant offense: Intellectual property law in Chinese civilization. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Arthur, W. B. 1994. Increasing returns and path dependence in the economy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barley, S. R. 2016. Ruminations on how we became a mystery house and how we might get out. Administrative Science Quarterly, 61: 18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boeing, P., Mueller, E., & Sander, P. 2016. China's R&D explosion: Analyzing productivity effects across ownership types and over time. Research Policy, 45 (1): 159176.Google Scholar
Bruton, G. D., & Ahlstrom, D. 2003. An institutional view of China's venture capital industry: Explaining the differences between China and the West. Journal of Business Venturing, 18 (2): 233259.Google Scholar
Bugbee, B. 1967. The genesis of American patent and copyright law. New York: Public Affairs Press.Google Scholar
BusinessWeek . 2006. The patent epidemic. January 9: 6062.Google Scholar
Campbell, J. L. 2004. Institutional change and globalization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cao, C., Li, N., Li, X., & Liu, L. 2013. Reforming China's S&T system. Science, 341 (August 2): 460462.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chandler, A. D. 1990. Strategy and structure: Chapters in the history of the industrial enterprise. Boston: MIT press.Google Scholar
Chaudhry, P. E., & Zimmerman, A. 2009. The economics of counterfeit trade. Heidelberg, Germany: Springer.Google Scholar
Cheng, M. L., & Huang, C. 2016. Transforming China's IP system to stimulate innovation. In Lewin, A. Y., Kenney, M. & Murmann, J. P. (Eds.), China's innovation challenge: Overcoming the middle-income trap: 152188. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Chow, D. C. K. 2003. The legal system of the People's Republic of China in a nutshell. St. Paul, MN: West.Google Scholar
David, P. 1985. Clio and the economics of QWERTY. American Economic Review, 75 (2): 227332.Google Scholar
Davis, G. F. 2015. What is organizational research for? Administrative Science Quarterly, 60 (2): 179188.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48 (2): 147160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Draper, T. 1996. A struggle for power: The American Revolution. New York: Times Books.Google Scholar
Feng, N. H. 2007. To steal a book is just an elegant offense? Discussion on books’ copyright protection in imperial China. Library and Information Service, 51 (11): 5861.Google Scholar
Ferguson, N. (Ed.). 1999. Virtual history: Alternatives and counterfactuals. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Fisher, W. W. 1999. The growth of intellectual property: A history of the ownership of ideas in the United States. Working paper, Harvard Law School. [Cited 15 July 2016]. Available from URL: www.cyber.law.harvard.edu Google Scholar
Friedman, W. A., & Jones, G. 2011. Business history: Time for debate. Business History Review, 85 (1): 18.Google Scholar
Galtsova, P. 2008. Intellectual property reform in Russia: Analysis of part four of the Russian Civil Code. Master's thesis, Faculty of Law, Lund University, Sweden.Google Scholar
Gordon, J. S. 2005. Empire of wealth: The epic history of American economic power. New York: Harper Perennial.Google Scholar
Gould, S. J. 1993. Poe's greatest hit. Natural History, 102 (7): 1019.Google Scholar
Greif, A., & Laitin, D. 2004. A theory of endogenous institutional change. American Political Science Review, 98 (4): 633652.Google Scholar
Hall, P. A., & Taylor, R. 1996. Political science and the three new institutionalisms. Political Studies, 44: 936957.Google Scholar
Hill, C. W. L. 2007. Digital piracy: Causes, consequences, and strategic responses. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24 (1): 925.Google Scholar
Hofstede, G. 2007. Asian management in the 21st century. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24 (4): 411420.Google Scholar
Howell, A. 2015. Indigenous innovation with heterogeneous risk and new firm survival in a transitioning Chinese economy. Research Policy, 44 (10): 18661876.Google Scholar
Hu, M.-C., & Mathews, J. A. 2008. China's national innovation capacity. Research Policy, 37 (9): 14651479.Google Scholar
Ingram, P., & Silverman, B. 2002. Introduction. In Ingram, P. & Silverman, B. (Eds.), The new institutionalism in strategic management: 130. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
IP Commission, The (The Commission on the Theft of American Intellectual Property). 2013. The IP commission report. Seattle: National Bureau of Asian Research.Google Scholar
Jaffe, A. B., & Lerner, J. 2007. Innovation and its discontents. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Jandhyala, S. 2015. International and domestic dynamics of intellectual property protection. Journal of World Business, 50 (2): 284293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johns, A. 2009. Piracy: The intellectual property wars from Gutenberg to Gates. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Jones, G., & Khanna, T. 2006. Bringing history (back) into international business. Journal of International Business Studies, 37 (4): 453468.Google Scholar
Khan, B. Z. 2005. The democratization of invention: Patents and copyrights in American economic development, 1790-1920. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Khan, B. Z. 2013. Selling ideas: An international perspective on patenting and markets for technological innovations, 1790–1930. Business History Review, 87 (1): 3968.Google Scholar
Khan, B. Z., & Sokoloff, K. L. 2001. The early development of intellectual property institutions in the United States. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (3): 233246.Google Scholar
Khan, B. Z., & Sokoloff, K. L. 2004. Institutions and democratic invention in nineteenth-century America. American Economic Review, 94 (2): 395401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khoury, T., & Peng, M. W. 2011. Does institutional reform of intellectual property rights lead to more inbound FDI? Evidence from Latin America and the Caribbean. Journal of World Business, 46 (3): 337345.Google Scholar
Kieser, A. 1994. Why organization theory needs historical analyses – and how this should be performed. Organization Science, 5 (4): 608620.Google Scholar
Klochikhin, E. A. 2012. Russia's innovation policy: Stubborn path-dependencies and new approaches. Research Policy, 41 (9): 16201630.Google Scholar
Kumar, N. 2003. Intellectual property rights, technology, and economic development: Experiences of Asian countries. Economic and Political Weekly, January 18: 209226.Google Scholar
Lewin, A. Y. 2015. Letter from the editor. Management and Organization Review, 11 (1): 13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewin, A. Y., Kenney, M., & Murmann, J. P. (Eds.). 2016. China's innovation challenge: Overcoming the middle-income trap. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Li, S. 2004. Why is property right protection lacking in China? An institutional explanation. California Management Review, 46 (3): 100115.Google Scholar
Li, X. 2012. Behind the recent surge of Chinese patenting: An institutional view. Research Policy, 41 (1): 236249.Google Scholar
Liang, Z., & Xue, L. 2010. The evolution of China's IPR system and its impact on the patenting behaviors and strategies of multinationals in China. International Journal of Technology Management, 51 (5): 469496.Google Scholar
Liu, F., Simon, D. F., Sun, Y., & Cao, C. 2011. China's innovation policies: Evolution, institutional structure, and trajectory. Research Policy, 40 (7): 917937.Google Scholar
Lohr, S. 2002. The intellectual property debate takes a page from 19th-century America. New York Times , October 14.Google Scholar
Lopes, T. D. S., & Casson, M. 2012. Brand protection and the globalization of British business. Business History Review, 86 (2): 287310.Google Scholar
Lubman, S. 1999. Bird in a cage: Legal reform in China after Mao. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Marquis, C., & Raynard, M. 2015. Institutional strategies in emerging markets. Academy of Management Annals, 9 (1): 291335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mazzoleni, R., & Nelson, R. R. 1998. The benefits and costs of strong patent protection: A contribution to the current debate. Research Policy, 27 (3): 273284.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. 2016. Bourgeois equality: How ideas, not capital or institutions, enriched the world. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McKinsey Global Institute (McKinsey). 2015. The China effect on global innovation . Report.Google Scholar
Mertha, A. C. 2007. The politics of piracy: Intellectual property in contemporary China. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, J. W., Boli, J., Thomas, G. M., & Ramirez, F. O. 1997. World society and the nation-state. American Journal of Sociology, 103 (1): 144181.Google Scholar
Meyer, K. E., & Peng, M. W. 2016. Theoretical foundations of emerging economy business research. Journal of International Business Studies, 47 (1): 322.Google Scholar
Moser, P. 2013. Patents and innovation: Evidence from economic history. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27 (1): 2344.Google Scholar
Moser, P., & Voena, A. 2012. Compulsory licensing: Evidence from the Trading with the Enemy Act. American Economic Review, 102 (2): 396427.Google Scholar
Naghavi, A. 2007. Strategic intellectual property rights policy and North-South technology transfer. Review of World Economics, 143 (1): 5578.Google Scholar
Neustadt, R. E., & May, E. R. 1986. Thinking in time: The uses of history for decision-makers. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Paulson, H. 2015. Dealing with China: An insider unmasks the new economic superpower. New York: Grand Central.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2003. Institutional transitions and strategic choices. Academy of Management Review, 28 (2): 275296.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2013. An institution-based view of IPR protection. Business Horizons, 56 (2): 135139.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., Ahlstrom, D., Carraher, S. M., & Shi, W. 2017. An institution-based view of global IPR history. Journal of International Business Studies , forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W., Sun, S. L., Pinkham, B., & Chen, H. 2009. The institution-based view as a third leg for a strategy tripod. Academy of Management Perspectives, 23 (4): 6381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W., Wang, D. Y. L., & Jiang, Y. 2008. An institution-based view of international business strategy: A focus on emerging economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 39 (5): 920936.Google Scholar
Pierson, P. 2004. Politics in time: History, institutions, and social analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Poncet, S. 2005. A fragmented China: Measure and determinants of Chinese domestic market disintegration. Review of International Economics, 13 (3): 409430.Google Scholar
Pouillard, V. 2011. Design piracy in the fashion industries of Paris and New York in the interwar years. Business History Review, 85 (2): 319344.Google Scholar
Quinn, A. H. 1998. Edgar Allan Poe: A critical biography. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Raustiala, K., & Sprigman, C. 2012. The knockoff economy: How imitation sparks innovation. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Raustiala, K., & Sprigman, C. 2013. Fake it till you make it: The good news about China's knockoff economy. Foreign Affairs, 92 (4): 2530.Google Scholar
Robinson, R. 2016. How Google stole the work of millions of authors. Wall Street Journal , February 8.Google Scholar
Scott, W. R. 2014. Institutions and organizations: Ideas, interests, and identities. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Shenkar, O. 2010. Copycats: How smart companies use imitation to gain a strategic edge. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Shi, W., Sun, S. L., Pinkham, B. C., & Peng, M. W. 2014. Domestic alliance network to attract foreign partners: Evidence from international joint ventures in China. Journal of International Business Studies, 45 (3): 338362.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1961. Administrative behavior (2nd ed.). New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Singh, K. 2007. The limited relevance of culture to strategy. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24 (4): 421428.Google Scholar
Sokoloff, K. L., & Khan, B. Z. 1990. The democratization of invention during early industrialization: Evidence from the United States, 1790–1846. Journal of Economic History, 50 (2): 363378.Google Scholar
State Intellectual Property Office (SIPO). 2010. National patent development strategy (2011–2020). Beijing: SIPO.Google Scholar
Steinmo, S., Thelen, K., & Longstreth, F. (Eds.) 1992. Structuring politics: Historical institutionalism in comparative analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Suttmeier, R. P., & Yao, X. 2011. China's IP transition: Rethinking intellectual property rights in a rising China. NBR Special Report 29. Seattle: National Bureau of Asian Research.Google Scholar
The Economist . 2014. Intellectual property in China: Patent fiction. December 13: 7374.Google Scholar
The Economist . 2016. Counterfeiting and piracy: Stamping it out. April 23: 5152.Google Scholar
Thompson, K. 1986. Exporting entertainment: America in the world film market, 1907–1934. London: British Film Institute.Google Scholar
Tomalin, C. 2011. Charles Dickens: A life. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
US Trade Representative (USTR). 2010. National trade estimate report on foreign trade barriers. Washington, DC: USTR.Google Scholar
Usselman, S. 1999. Patents, engineering professionals, and the pipelines of innovation: The internalization of technical discovery by nineteenth-century American railroads. In Lamoreaux, N. R., Raff, D. M. G., & Temin, P. (Eds.), Learning by doing in markets, firms, and countries: 61102. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Weber, M., Baehr, P. R., & Wells, G. C. 2002. The Protestant ethic and the ‘spirit’ of capitalism and other writings. New York: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, P. J., & Yin, E. 2014. Accelerated innovation: The new challenge from China. MIT Sloan Management Review, 55 (4): 2734.Google Scholar
Wren, D. 1987. Management history: Issues and ideas of teaching and research. Journal of Management, 13 (2): 339350.Google Scholar
Yu, P. K. 2008. Intellectual property, economic development, and the China puzzle. In Hansen, H. C. (Ed.), Intellectual property law and policy: 9901023. Portland, OR: Hart Publishing.Google Scholar
Yu, P. K. 2011. The TRIPS enforcement dispute. Nebraska Law Review, 89: 10461131.Google Scholar
Yu, P. K. 2013. Five oft–repeated questions about China's recent rise as a patent power. Cardozo Law Review de Novo, 78114.Google Scholar
Yu, P. K. 2014a. The curious case of fake Beijing Olympics merchandise. In Calboli, I. & Lee, E. (Eds.), Trademark protection and territoriality challenges in a global economy: 259282. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Yu, P. K. 2014b. The sweet and sour story of Chinese intellectual property rights. In Dutfeld, G. & Suthersanen, U. (Eds.), Technology, progress, and prosperity. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Zimmerman, A. 2013. Contending with Chinese counterfeits: Culture, growth, and management responses. Business Horizons, 56 (2): 141148.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. IPR civil cases in China and the United States

Figure 1

Figure 1. The costs and benefits of IPR protection and enforcement institutions