Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T07:00:10.387Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

WHY IS OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY MUTE? RESTORING ITS RIGHTFUL VOICE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 January 2018

Olivier de La Grandville*
Affiliation:
Stanford University and Goethe University, Frankfurt am Main
*
Address correspondence to: Olivier de La Grandville, Department of Management Science and Engineering, Stanford University, Huang Engineering Center, Via Ortega 475, Stanford, CA 94305, USA; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

Optimal growth theory as it stands today does not work. Using strictly concave utility functions systematically inflicts on the economy distortions that are either historically unobserved or unacceptable by society. Moreover, we show that the traditional approach is incompatible with competitive equilibrium: Any economy initially in such equilibrium will always veer away into unwanted trajectories if its investment is planned using a concave utility function. We then propose a rule for the optimal savings-investment rate based on competitive equilibrium that simultaneously generates three intertemporal optima for society. The rule always leads to reasonable time paths for all central economic variables, even under very different hypotheses about the future evolution of population and technical progress.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

A preliminary preprint of this article appeared in our book Economic Growth: a Unified Approach [La Grandville (2017)]. I want to acknowledge the invaluable help extended to me by my colleague Ernst Hairer without which I would not have been able to put the utility functions to the test of competitive equilibrium. The numerical solutions of the resulting differential equations and the spectacular diagrams are due to him. I am also very grateful to Kenneth Arrow, Michael Binder, Giuseppe De Arcangelis, Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Robert Chirinko, Daniela Federici, Robert Feicht, Giancarlo Gandolfo, Jean-Marie Grether, Erich Gundlach, Andreas Irmen, Bjarne Jensen, Anastasia Litina, Miguel Leon-Ledesma, Rainer Klump, Peter McAdam, Bernardo Maggi, Enrico Saltari, Wolfgang Stummer, Robert Solow, Juerg Weber, and Milad Zarin-Nejadan, as well as to participants in seminars at Stanford, Frankfurt, Luxembourg, and Rome (La Sapienza) for their highly helpful remarks. The very constructive comments and suggestions of two referees are also gratefully acknowledged.

References

REFERENCES

Dorfman, Robert (1969) An economic interpretation of optimal control theory. American Economic Review 59 (5), 817831.Google Scholar
Goodwin, Richard M. (1961) The optimal growth path for an underdeveloped economy. Economic Journal 71 (284), 756774.Google Scholar
Intriligator, M. D. (1971) Mathematical Optimisation and Economic Theory. London, New York: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Johnston, Louis and Williamson, Samuel H. (2013) What was the U.S. GDP then? http://www.measuringworth.com/datasets/usgdp/result.php.Google Scholar
Kamikigashi, T. and Roy, S. (2006) Dynamic optimisation with a non-smooth, non-convex technology: the case of a linear objective function. Journal of Economic Theory 29, 325340.Google Scholar
King, Robert G. and Rebelo, Sergio T. (1993) Transitional dynamics and economic growth in the neoclassical model. American Economic Review 83 (4), 908931.Google Scholar
Klump, Rainer and de La Grandville, Olivier (2000) Economic growth and the elasticity of substitution: Two theorems and some suggestions. The American Economic Review 90 (1), 282291.Google Scholar
La Grandville, Olivier de (1989) In quest of the Slutsky diamond. American Economic Review 79 (3), 468481.Google Scholar
La Grandville, Olivier de (2011) A new property of general means of order p, with applications to economic growth. Australian Journal of Mathematical Analysis with Applications 8 (1), Article 3.Google Scholar
La Grandville, Olivier de (2017) Economic Growth - A Unified Approach, with a foreword and two special contributions by Solow, Robert M., 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
La Grandville, Olivier de and Solow, Robert M. (2006) A conjecture on general means. Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics 7 (1), Article 3.Google Scholar
Ramsey, Frank (1928) A mathematical theory of saving. The Economic Journal 38 (152), 543559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ryuzo, Sato (2006) Biased Technical Change and Economic Conservation Laws. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Thanh, Nam Phan and Minh, Mach Nguyet (2008) Proof of a conjecture on general means. Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics 9 (3), Article 86.Google Scholar
Yuhn, Ky Hyang (1991) Economic growth, technical change biases, and the elasticity of substitution: A test of the de La Grandville Hypothesis. Review of Economics and Statistics 73 (2), 340346.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

de La Grandville supplementary material

de La Grandville supplementary material 1

Download de La Grandville supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.1 MB