Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-14T05:22:43.718Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

WHAT DRIVES IDEAS PRODUCTION ACROSS THE WORLD?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 July 2013

James B. Ang*
Affiliation:
Monash University
Jakob B. Madsen
Affiliation:
Monash University
*
Address correspondence to: James B. Ang, Department of Economics, Monash University, 900 Dandenong Road, Caulfield East, Vic 3145, Australia; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

The ideas production function is at the heart of endogenous growth theory. Using data for Europe, its offshoots, and the Asian Tiger economies over the period from 1870 to 2010, this paper provides direct estimates of an ideas production function that explicitly distinguishes between the first- and second-generation endogenous growth models while allowing for human capital and international knowledge spillovers through various channels. The estimates show strong intertemporal and cross-country knowledge spillovers, provide robust support for Schumpeterian growth theory, and suggest that human capital and some channels of international knowledge spillover are influential for ideas production.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Aghion, Philippe and Howitt, Peter (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60, 323351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, Philippe and Howitt, Peter (1998) Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Ang, James B. and Madsen, Jakob (2013) International R&D spillovers and productivity trends in the Asian miracle economies. Economic Inquiry 51, 15231541CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ang, James B. and Madsen, Jakob B. (2011) Can second-generation endogenous growth models explain productivity trends and knowledge production in the Asian miracle economies? Review of Economics and Statistics 93, 13601373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, Robert J. and Lee, Jong Wha (2010) A New Data Set of Educational Attainment in the World, 1950–2010. NBER working paper 15902.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bils, Mark and Klenow, Peter J. (2000) Does schooling cause growth? American Economic Review 90, 11601183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bottazzi, L. and Peri, G. (2003) Innovation, demand, and knowledge spillovers: Evidence from European patent data. European Economic Review 47, 687710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braun, R. Anton and Nakajima, Tomoyuki (2009) Pareto Optimal Pro-cyclical Research and Development. CIRJE F-Series CIRJE-F-617, CIRJE, Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo.Google Scholar
Braun, R. Anton, Okada, Toshihiro, and Sudo, Nao (2008) U.S. R&D and Japanese Medium Term Cycles. Discussion paper series 43, School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University.Google Scholar
Caballero, Ricardo J. and Jaffe, Adam B. (1993) How High Are the Giants' Shoulders: An Empirical Assessment of Knowledge Spillovers and Creative Destruction in a Model of Economic Growth. NBER working paper 4370.Google Scholar
Choi, I. (2001) Unit root tests for panel data. Journal of International Money and Finance 20, 249272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coe, David T. and Helpman, Elhanan (1995) International R&D spillovers. European Economic Review 39, 859897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coe, David T., Helpman, Elhanan, and Hoffmaister, Alexander W (2009) International R&D spillovers and institution. European Economic Review 53, 723741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dernis, Helene, Dominique, Guellec, and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, Bruno (2001) Using patent counts for cross-country comparisons of technology output. STI Review (OECD) 27, 129146.Google Scholar
Dowrick, Steve and Gemmell, Norman (1991) Industrialisation, catching up and economic growth: A comparative study across the world's capitalist economies. Economic Journal 101, 263275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschenkron, Alexander (1952) Economic backwardness in historical perspective. In Hoselitz, Bert (ed.), The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas, pp. 329. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gorodnichenko, Yuriy, Svejnar, Jan, and Terrell, Katherine (2010) Globalization and innovation in emerging markets. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2, 194226.Google Scholar
Griliches, Zvi (1979) Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics 10, 92116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griliches, Zvi (1990) Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature 28, 16611707.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M. (1998) Comments on Alan V. Deardorff: Determinants of bilateral trade: Does gravity work in a neoclassical world? In Frankel, Jeffrey A. (ed.), The Regionalization of the World Economy, pp. 2931. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanan (1991) Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Review of Economic Studies 58, 4361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ha, Joonkyung and Howitt, Peter (2007) Accounting for trends in productivity and R&D: A Schumpeterian critique of semi-endogenous growth theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39, 733774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Robert E. (1988) The relation between price and marginal cost in U.S. industry. Journal of Political Economy 96, 921947.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanushek, Eric A. and Woessmann, Ludger (2010) The Economics of International Differences in Educational Achievement. NBER working paper 15949.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howitt, Peter (1999) Steady endogenous growth with population and R&D inputs growing. Journal of Political Economy 107, 715730.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howitt, Peter (2000) Endogenous growth and cross-country income differences. American Economic Review 90, 829846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Im, Kyung So, Pesaran, M. Hashem, and Shin, Yongcheol (2003) Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics 115, 5374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Charles (1995) Time series tests of endogenous growth models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 495525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keller, Wolfgang (2002) Geographic localization of international technology diffusion. American Economic Review 92, 120142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin, A., Lin, C.F., and Chu, C. (2002) Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and finite-sample properties. Journal of Econometrics 108, 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtenberg, Frank R. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, Bruno (1998) International R&D spillovers: A comment. European Economic Review 42, 14831491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddala, G.S. and Wu, S. (1999) A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and a new simple test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61, 631652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddison, Angus (2008) Statistics on World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP, 1–2006 AD. http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/ (online database). Groningen Growth and Development Centre, University of Groningen.Google Scholar
Madsen, Jakob B. (2007) Technology spillover through trade and TFP convergence: 135 years of evidence for the OECD countries. Journal of International Economics 72, 464480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madsen, Jakob B. (2008a) Economic growth, TFP convergence and the world export of ideas: A century of evidence. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 110, 145167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madsen, Jakob B. (2008b) Semi-endogenous versus Schumpeterian growth models: Testing the knowledge production function using international data. Journal of Economic Growth 13, 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madsen, Jakob B. (2010) The anatomy of growth in the OECD since 1870. Journal of Monetary Economics 57, 753767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madsen, Jakob B. and Ang, James B. (2009) Endogenous Growth Accounting and the Asian Growth Miracle. Paper presented at the 14th Australasian Macroeconomics Workshop, April 2009.Google Scholar
Madsen, Jakob B., Saxena, Shishir, and Ang, James B. (2010) The Indian growth miracle and endogenous growth. Journal of Development Economics 93, 3748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrisson, Christian and Murtin, Fabrice (2009) The century of education. Journal of Human Capital 3, 142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2003) OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
OECD (2009) OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2009 (Complete Edition). Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Pakes, A. and Schankerman, M. (1984) The rate of obsolescence of patents, research gestation lags, and the private rate of return to research resources. In Griliches, Z. (ed.), R&D, Patents, and Productivity, pp. 7388. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Peretto, Pietro F. (1998) Technological change and population growth. Journal of Economic Growth 3, 283311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peretto, Pietro and Smulders, Sjak (2002) Technological distance, growth and scale effects. Economic Journal 112, 603624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, Michael and Stern, Scott (2000) Measuring the “Ideas” Production Function: Evidence from International Patent Output. National Bureau of Economic Research working papers 7891.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pritchett, Lant (2006) Does learning to add up add up? The returns to schooling in aggregate data. In Hanushek, Eric and Welch, Finis (eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Education, pp. 635695. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Psacharopoulos, George and Patrinos, Harry Anthony (2004) Returns to investment in education: A further update. Education Economics 12, 111134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, Paul M. (1990) Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98, S71102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segerstrom, Paul S. (1998) Endogenous growth without scale effects. American Economic Review 88, 12901310.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. (1994) Perspectives on growth theory. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, 4554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Timmer, Marcel and van Ark, Bart (2000) Capital Formation and Productivity Growth in South Korea and Taiwan: Beating Diminishing Returns through Realising the Catch-Up Potential. Paper presented at the 26th General Conference of the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth, Cracow, Poland.Google Scholar
Ulku, Hulya (2007a) R&D, innovation, and growth: Evidence from four manufacturing sectors in OECD countries. Oxford Economic Papers 59, 513535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ulku, Hulya (2007b) R&D, innovation and output: Evidence from OECD and non-OECD countries. Applied Economics 39, 291307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vandenbussche, Jérôme, Aghion, Philippe, and Meghir, Costas (2006) Growth, distance to frontier and composition of human capital. Journal of Economic Growth 11, 97127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Venturini, Francesco (2012) Looking into the black-box of the Schumpeterian growth theories: An empirical assessment of R&D races. European Economic Review 56, 15301545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar