Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T01:49:00.708Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE ROLE OF INVESTMENT-SPECIFIC TECHNOLOGY SHOCKS IN DRIVING INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS CYCLES: A BAYESIAN APPROACH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 November 2016

Jaya Dey*
Affiliation:
Saint Louis University
*
Address correspondence to: Jaya Dey, Department of Economics, 220 Cook Hall, Saint Louis University, St. Louis, MO 63103, USA; e-mail: [email protected].
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

This paper uses a Bayesian approach to estimate a standard international real business cycle model augmented with preferences with zero wealth effect, variable capacity utilization, and investment adjustment costs. First, I find that the bulk of fluctuations in country-specific outputs, consumption, investments, and international relative prices can be attributed to country-specific neutral technology, investment-specific technology, and preference shocks. Second, my estimated model with economically meaningful shocks simultaneously accounts for the negative correlation between the real exchange rate and relative consumption and the negative correlation between the terms of trade and relative output. Last, through a marginal likelihood comparison exercise, I find that the success of the model depends on preferences with zero wealth effects; other frictions and alternative asset market structures play a less important role.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

Footnotes

I am grateful to Bill Dupor, Nan Li, Paul Evans, and Masao Ogaki for their guidance. I also thank Aubhik Khan, Julia Thomas, Joe Kaboski, Fabrizio Perri, Patrick Kehoe, Ariel Burstein, Jesper Linde, Giancarlo Corsetti, Jesús Fernández-Villaverde, Gianluca Violante, Kenneth West, and the seminar participants at the 2011 Computational Economics and Finance Meeting, the Ohio State University, Oklahoma State University, Kansas University, the 2010 Southern Economic Association Meeting, and the 2010 Midwest Economics Association Meeting which greatly improved the quality of the paper. I am thankful to Pau Rabanal for providing me with the relevant data. All errors are my own.

References

REFERENCES

Adolfson, M., Laséen, S., Lindé, J., and Villani, M. (2007) Bayesian estimation of an open economy DSGE model with incomplete pass-through. Journal of International Economics 72 (2), 481511.Google Scholar
Altig, D., Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., and Linde, J. (2011) Firm-specific capital, nominal rigidities and the business cycle. Review of Economic Dynamics 14 (2), 225247.Google Scholar
An, S. and Schorfheide, F. (2007) Bayesian analysis of DSGE models. Econometric Reviews 26 (2–4), 113172.Google Scholar
Backus, D., Kehoe, P., and Kydland, F.E. (1995) International business cycles: Theory and evidence. In Cooley, T. (ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, pp. 331356. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Backus, D. and Smith, G.W. (1993) Consumption and real exchange rates in dynamic economies with non-traded goods. Journal of International Economics 35, 297316.Google Scholar
Basu, P. and Thoenissen, C. (2011) International business cycles and the relative price of investment goods. Canadian Journal of Economics 44 (2), 580606.Google Scholar
Baxter, M. and Crucini, M.J. (1995) Business cycles and the asset structure of foreign trade. International Economic Review 36 (4).Google Scholar
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., and Gilchrist, S. (1999) The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In Taylor, J.B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, 1st ed., Vol. 1, Chap. 21, pp. 13411393.Google Scholar
Carlstrom, C. and Fuerst, T. (1997) Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations: A computable general equilibrium analysis. American Economic Review 87, 893910.Google Scholar
Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., and Evans, C. (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113 (1), 145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiano, L., Ilut, C., Motto, R., and Rostagno, M. (2008) Monetary Policy and a Stock Market Boom–Bust Cycle. Working paper 0955, European Central Bank.Google Scholar
Christoffel, K., Coenen, G. and Warne, A. (2008) The New Area-Wide Model of the Euro Area: A Micro-Founded Open-Economy Model for Forecasting and Policy Analysis. ECB working paper 944.Google Scholar
Corsetti, G., Dedola, L., and Leduc, S. (2008) International risk sharing and the transmission of productivity shocks. Review of Economic Studies 75, 443473.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Walque, G., Smets, F., and Wouters, R. (2005) An Estimated Two-Country DSGE Model for the Euro Area and the US Economy. Working paper, National Bank of Belgium.Google Scholar
Enders, Z. and Muller, G.J. (2009) On the international transmission of technology shocks. Journal of International Economics 78 (1), 4559.Google Scholar
Fernández-Villaverde, J. and Rubio-Ramírez, J.F. (2004) Comparing dynamic equilibrium models to data: A Bayesian approach. Journal of Econometrics 123, 153187.Google Scholar
Fisher, J.D.M. (2006) The dynamic effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks. Journal of Political Economy 114 (3), 413451.Google Scholar
Gali, J. (1999) Technology, employment, and the business cycle: Do technology shocks explain aggregate fluctuations? American Economic Review 89 (1), 249271.Google Scholar
Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., and Huffman, G.W. (1988) Investment, capacity utilization and the real business cycle. American Economic Review 78, 402417.Google Scholar
Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., and Krusell, P. (1997) Long-run implications of investment-specific technological change. American Economic Review 87 (June), 342362.Google Scholar
Heathcote, J. and Perri, F. (2002) Financial autarky and international business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 601627.Google Scholar
Heathcote, J. and Perri, F. (2013) The international diversification puzzle is not as bad as you think. Journal of Political Economy 121 (6), 11081159.Google Scholar
Ireland, P. (2013) Stochastic growth in the United States and Euro Area. Journal of the European Economic Association 11 (1), 124.Google Scholar
Jacob, P. and Peersman, G. (2013) Dissecting the dynamics of the US trade balance in an estimated equilibrium model. Journal of International Economics, 90 (2), pp. 302315.Google Scholar
Justiniano, A. and Preston, B. (2010) Can structural small open economy models account for the influence of foreign disturbances? Journal of International Economics 81, 6174.Google Scholar
Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G., and Tambalotti, A. (2010) Investment shocks and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 57 (2), 132145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G., and Tambalotti, A. (2011) Investment shocks and the relative price of investment. Review of Economic Dynamics 14 (1), 101121.Google Scholar
King, R.G., Plosser, C.I., Stock, J.H., and Watson, M.W. (1991) Stochastic trends and economic fluctuations. American Economic Review 81 (4), 819840.Google Scholar
Kollmann, R. (2013) Global banks, financial shocks and international business cycles: Evidence from an estimated model. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45 (2), 159195.Google Scholar
Komunjer, I. and Ng, S. (2011) Dynamic identification of DSGE models. Econometrica 79 (6), 19952032.Google Scholar
Lubik, T.A. and Schorfheide, F. (2006) A Bayesian look at new open economy macroeconomics. In Mark, G. and Rogoff, K. (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2005, pp. 313366. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Mandelman, F., Rabanal, P., Rubio-Ramírez, J.F., and Vilán, D. (2011) Investment-specific technology shocks and international business cycles: An empirical assessment. Review of Economic Dynamics 14 (1), 136155.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. (2000) The six major puzzles in international macroeconomics: Is there a common cause? In Bernanke, Ben S. and Rogoff, Kenneth (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 2000. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Rabanal, P. and Tuesta, V. (2010) Euro-dollar real exchange rate dynamics in an estimated two-country model: An assessment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34, 780797.Google Scholar
Raffo, A. (2007) Net exports, consumption volatility and international business cycle models. Journal of International Economics 75, 1429.Google Scholar
Raffo, A. (2010) Technology Shocks: Novel Implications for International Business Cycles. International finance discussion paper 992, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.).Google Scholar
Schmitt-Grohé, S. and Uribe, M. (2012) What's news in business cycles. Econometrica 80, 27332764.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2003) An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the Euro area. Journal of European Economic Association 1 (5), 11231175.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2007) Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian approach. American Economic Review 97 (3), 586606.Google Scholar