Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-8ctnn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T14:54:02.224Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

POLICY AND WELFARE EFFECTS OF WITHIN-PERIOD COMMITMENT

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 March 2014

Fernando M. Martin*
Affiliation:
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
*
Address correspondence to: Fernando M. Martin, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 63166, USA; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

Consider the problem of a benevolent government that needs to finance the provision of a public good with distortionary taxes and cannot commit to policies beyond the current period. In such a case, public expenditure is inefficiently low. If the government further loses the ability to set tax rates before production in the period takes place, then it will not internalize how its policy choices distort current factor markets. Thus, to counterbalance the costs of future distortions, it increases public good provision. For a calibrated economy, removing within-period commitment implies a welfare gain worth half a percent of yearly consumption. A similar gain can be obtained if instead, capital depreciation is allowed to be fully deducted from taxable income.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Amano, Robert A. and Wirjanto, Tony S. (1997) Intratemporal substitution and government spending. Review of Economics and Statistics 79 (4), 605609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azzimonti, Marina, Sarte, Pierre-Daniel, and Soares, Jorge (2009) Distortionary taxes and public investment when government promises are not enforceable. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 33 (9), 16621681.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohn, Henning and Inman, Robert P. (1996) Balanced-budget rules and public deficits: Evidence from the U.S. states. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 45 (1), 1376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, Patrick J.. (1990) Sustainable plans. Journal of Political Economy 98 (4), 784802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Debortoli, Davide and Nunes, Ricardo (2010) Fiscal policy under loose commitment. Journal of Economic Theory 145, 10051032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, Jeremy, Hercowitz, Zvi, and Huffman, Gregory W. (1988) Investment, capital utilization, and the real business cycle. American Economic Review 78, 402417.Google Scholar
Guo, Jang-Ting and Lansing, Kevin J. (1997) Tax structure and welfare in a model of optimal fiscal policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review 33 (1), 1123.Google Scholar
Guo, Jang-Ting and Lansing, Kevin J. (1999) Optimal taxation of capital income with imperfectly competitive product markets. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23, 967995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, Kenneth L. (1998) Numerical Methods in Economics. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Klein, Paul, Krusell, Per, and Ríos-Rull, José-Víctor (2008) Time-consistent public expenditures. Review of Economic Studies 75 (3), 789808.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Paul and Ríos-Rull, José-Víctor (2003) Time-consistent optimal fiscal policy. International Economic Review 44 (4), 12171246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, Per, Martin, Fernando M., and Ríos-Rull, José-Víctor (2006) Time-Consistent Debt. Mimeo, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Krusell, Per and Smith, Anthony (2003) Consumption–savings decisions with quasi-geometric discounting. Econometrica 71 (1), 365375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, Fernando M. (2009) A positive theory of government debt. Review of Economic Dynamics 12 (4), 608631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, Fernando M. (2010) Markov-perfect capital and labor taxes. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (3), 503521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maskin, Eric and Tirole, Jean (2001) Markov perfect equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory 100, 191219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nieh, Chien-Chung and Ho, Tsung-wu (2006) Does the expansionary government spending crowd out the private consumption? Cointegration analysis in panel data. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46 (1), 133148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortigueira, Salvador (2006) Markov-perfect optimal taxation. Review of Economic Dynamics 9, 153178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortigueira, Salvador, Pereira, Joana, and Pichler, Paul (2012) Markov-Perfect Optimal Fiscal Policy: The Case of Unbalanced Budgets. Mimeo, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid.Google Scholar
Pecorino, Paul (1993) Tax structure and growth in a model with human capital. Journal of Public Economics 52, 251271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelan, Christopher and Stacchetti, Ennio (2001) Sequential equilibria in a Ramsey tax model. Econometrica 69 (6), 14911518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stockman, David R. (2001) Balanced-budget rules: Welfare loss and optimal policies. Review of Economic Dynamics 4, 438459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokey, Nancy L. and Rebelo, Sergio (1995) Growth effects of flat-rate taxes. Journal of Political Economy 103 (3), 519550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, John B. (2011) An empirical analysis of the revival of fiscal activism in the 2000s. Journal of Economic Literature 49 (3), 686702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turnovsky, Stephen J. and Brock, William A. (1980) Time consistency and optimal government policies in perfect foresight equilibrium. Journal of Public Economics 13, 183212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhu, Xiaodong (1995) Endogenous capital utilization, investor's effort, and optimal fiscal policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 36, 655677.CrossRefGoogle Scholar