Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-8ctnn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T17:25:08.712Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Optimal capital taxation in an economy with innovation-driven growth

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 October 2021

Ping-Ho Chen
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Tunghai University, Taichung, Taiwan
Angus C. Chu
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Macau, Macau, China
Hsun Chu*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Tunghai University, Taichung, Taiwan
Ching-Chong Lai
Affiliation:
Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica, Taipei, Taiwan Department of Economics, National Cheng Chi University, Taipei, Taiwan Institute of Economics, National Sun Yat-Sen University, Kaohsiung, Taiwan Department of Economics, Feng Chia University, Taichung, Taiwan
*
*Corresponding author: Hsun Chu. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

This paper investigates optimal capital taxation in an innovation-driven growth model. We examine how the optimal capital tax rate varies with externalities associated with R&D and innovation. Our results show that the optimal capital tax rate is higher when (i) the “stepping on toes effect” is smaller, (ii) the “standing on shoulders effect” is stronger, or (iii) the extent of creative destruction is smaller. The optimal capital tax rate is more likely to be positive when there is underinvestment in R&D. Moreover, the optimal capital tax rate and the monopolistic markup exhibit an inverted-U relationship. By calibrating our model to the US economy, we find that the optimal capital tax rate is positive, at a rate of around 6.6%. Finally, we consider a number of extensions and find that the result of a positive optimal capital tax is robust.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2021

References

Acemoglu, D. (1998) Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 10551089.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60, 323351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., Akcigit, U. and Fernndez-Villaverde, J. (2013) Optimal Capital versus Labor Taxation with Innovation-Led Growth. NBER Working Paper: 19086.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aiyagari, S. R. (1995) Optimal capital income taxation with incomplete markets, borrowing constraints, and constant discounting. Journal of Political Economy 103, 11581175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andolfatto, D., Hendry, S. and Moran, K. (2008) Are inflation expectations rational?. Journal of Monetary Economics 55, 406422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ang, J. B. and Madsen, J. B. (2015) What drives ideas production across the world?. Macroeconomic Dynamics 19, 79115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnold, J. M., Brys, B., Heady, C., Johansson, A., Schwellnus, C. and Vartia, L. (2011) Tax policy for economic recovery and growth. Economic Journal 121, F59F80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkeson, A., Chari, V. V and Kehoe, P. J. (1999) Taxing capital income: A bad idea. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 23, 317.Google Scholar
Bloom, N., Schankerman, M. and Reenen, J. V. (2013) Identifying technology spillovers and product market rivalry. Econometrica 81, 13471393.Google Scholar
Carey, D. and Tchilingurian, H. (2000) Average Effective Tax Rates on Capital, Labor and Consumption. OECD Working Paper: 258.Google Scholar
Chamley, C. (1986) Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica 54, 607622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamley, C. (2001) Capital income taxation, wealth redistribution and borrowing constraints. Journal of Public Economics 79, 5569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, C. W. and Lai, C. C. (2020) A note on optimal capital taxation with preference externalities. Macroeconomic Dynamics 24, 729746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chari, V. V., Christiano, L. J. and Kehoe, P. J. (1994) Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model. Journal of Political Economy 102, 67622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chari, V. V. and Kehoe, P. J. (1990) Sustainable plans. Journal of Political Economy 98, 783802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chari, V. V. and Kehoe, P. J. (1999) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. In: Taylor, J. B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics 1C. Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 1671–1745.Google Scholar
Chari, V. V., Nicolini, J. P. and Teles, P. (2020) Optimal capital taxation revisited. Journal of Monetary Economics 116, 147165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, B. L., Chen, H. J. and Wang, P. (2021) Long-run tax incidence in a human-capital-based endogenous growth model with labor-market frictions. Macroeconomic Dynamics 25, 337–378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, B. L. and Lu, C. H. (2013) Optimal factor tax incidence in two-sector human capital-based models. Journal of Public Economics 97, 7594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, P., Chu, A., Chu, H. and Lai, C. C. (2019) Optimal Capital Taxation in an Economy with Innovation-Driven Growth. MPRA Working Paper 101228.Google Scholar
Chen, S. H. and Guo, J. T. (2013) Progressive taxation and macroeconomic (In) stability with productive government spending. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, 951963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chetty, R., Guren, A., Manoli, D. and Weber, A. (2011) Are micro and macro labor supply elasticities consistent? A review of evidence on the intensive and extensive margins. American Economic Review 101, 471475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. and Cozzi, G. (2014) R&D and economic growth in a cash-in-advance economy. International Economic Review 55, 507524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. and Cozzi, G. (2018) Effects of patents versus R&D subsidies on income inequality. Review of Economic Dynamics 29, 6884.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A., Lai, C. C. and Liao, C. H. (2019). A tale of two growth engines: Interactive effects of monetary policy and intellectual property rights. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 51, 20292052.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Comin, D. (2004) R&D: A small contribution to productivity growth. Journal of Economic Growth 9, 391421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conesa, J. C., Kitao, S. and Krueger, D. (2009) Taxing capital? Not a bad idea after all!. American Economic Review 99, 2538.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coto-Martínez, J., Sanchez-Losada, F. and Garriga, C. (2007) Optimal taxation with imperfect competition and aggregate returns to specialization. Journal of the European Economic Association 5, 12691299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cozzi, G. (2004) Rat race, redistribution, and growth. Review of Economic Dynamics 7, 900915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domeij, D. (2005) Optimal capital taxation and labor market search. Review of Economic Dynamics 8, 623650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eicher, T. S. and Turnovsky, S. J. (2001) Transitional dynamics in a two-sector non-scale growth model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 25, 85113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Einiö, E. (2014) R&D subsidies and company performance: Evidence from geographic variation in government funding based on the ERDF population-density rule. Review of Economics and Statistics 96, 710728.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erosa, A. and Gervais, M. (2002) Optimal taxation in life-cycle economies. Journal of Economic Theory 105, 338369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farhi, E. and Werning, I. (2010) Progressive estate taxation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125, 635673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farhi, E. and Werning, I. (2013) Estate taxation with altruism heterogeneity. American Economic Review 103, 489495.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gali, J. (1994) Government size and macroeconomic stability. European Economic Review 38, 117132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golosov, M., Kocherlakota, N. and Tsyvinski, A. (2003) Optimal indirect and capital taxation. Review of Economic Studies 70, 569587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golosov, M. and Tsyvinski, A. (2015) Policy implications of dynamic public finance. Annual Reviews of Economics 7, 147171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golosov, M., Tsyvinski, A. and Werning, I. (2006) New dynamic public finance: A user’s guide. NBER Macroeconomic Annual 21, 317363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. M. and Helpman, E. (1991) Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Review of Economic Studies 58, 4361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guo, J. T. and Lansing, K. J. (1998) Indeterminacy and stabilization policy. Journal of Economic Theory 82, 481490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imrohoroglu, S. (1998) A quantitative analysis of capital income taxation. International Economic Review 39, 307328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iwaisako, T. (2016) Effects of patent protection on optimal corporate income and consumption taxes in an R&D-based growth model. Southern Economic Journal 83, 590608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iwaisako, T. and Futagami, K. (2013) Patent protection, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Economic Theory 52, 631668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jermann, U. and Quadrini, V. (2012) Macroeconomic effects of financial shocks. American Economic Review 102, 238271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I. (1995) R&D-based models of economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 103, 759784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I. and Williams, J. C. (1998) Measuring the social return to R&D. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 11191135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I. and Williams, J. C. (2000) Too much of a good thing? The economics of investment in R&D. Journal of Economic Growth 5, 6585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, L., Manuelli, R. and Rossi, P. (1997) On the optimal taxation of capital income. Journal of Economic Theory 73, 93117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, K. L. (1985) Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics 28, 5983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, K. L. (1997) The Optimal Tax Rate for Capital is Negative. NBER Working Paper: 6004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, K. L. (2002) Capital-income taxation with imperfect competition. American Economic Review 92, 417–421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lach, S. (2002) Do R&D subsidies stimulate or displace private R&D? Evidence from Israel. Journal of Industrial Economics 50, 369390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laitner, J. and Stolyarov, D. (2004) Aggregate returns to scale and embodied technical change: Theory and measurement using stock market data. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 191233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lansing, K. J. (1999) Optimal redistributive capital taxation in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economics 73, 423453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Long, X. and Pelloni, A. (2017) Factor income taxation in a horizontal innovation model. Journal of Public Economics 154, 137159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lu, C. C. and Chen, B. L. (2015) Optimal capital taxation in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economic Theory 17, 257269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R. E. (1990) Supply-side economics: An analytical review. Oxford Economic Papers 42, 293–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maoz, Y. D. (2010) Labor hours in the United States and Europe: The role of different leisure preferences. Macroeconomic Dynamics 14, 231241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattesini, F. and Rossi, L. (2012). Monetary policy and automatic stabilizers: The role of progressive taxation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44, 825862.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, J. A. (1971) An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Review of Economic Studies 38, 175208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neves, P. C. and Sequeira, T. N. (2018) Spillovers in the production of knowledge: A meta-regression analysis. Research Policy 47, 750767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petrucci, A. (2015) Optimal income taxation in models with endogenous fertility. Journal of Macroeconomics 43, 216225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, T. and Saez, E. (2013) A theory of optimal inheritance taxation. Econometrica 81, 18511886.Google Scholar
Rogerson, R. and Wallenius, J. (2009) Micro and macro elasticities in a life cycle model with taxes. Journal of Economic Theory 144, 22772292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, P. (1990) Endogenous technological progress. Journal of Political Economy 98, S71S102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scrimgeour, D. (2015) Dynamic scoring in a Romer-style economy. Southern Economic Journal 81, 697723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sequeira, T. N. and Neves, P. C. (2020) Stepping on toes in the production of knowledge: A meta-regression analysis. Applied Economics 52, 260274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokey, N. L. (1991) Credible public policy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 15, 627656.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Straub, L. and Werning, I. (2020) Positive long-run capital taxation: Chamley-Judd revisited. American Economic Review 110, 86119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yang, Y. (2018) On the optimality of IPR protection with blocking patents. Review of Economic Dynamics 27, 205230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zeng, J. and Zhang, J. (2002) Long-run growth effects of taxation in a non-scale growth model with innovation. Economics Letters 75, 391–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar