Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7fkt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T14:27:04.290Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

ON THE INTERGENERATIONAL SHARING OF COHORT-SPECIFIC SHOCKS ON PERMANENT INCOME

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 December 2009

Kenji Miyazaki
Affiliation:
Hosei University
Makoto Saito*
Affiliation:
Hitotsubashi University
Tomoaki Yamada
Affiliation:
Meiji University
*
Address correspondence to: Makoto Saito, Faculty of Economics, Hitotsubashi University: 2-1, Naka, Kunitachi, Tokyo, 186-8601, Japan; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

This paper investigates the intergenerational sharing of shocks on the permanent income of new entry cohorts when prior-to-entry markets are missing. When Lucas trees are traded among generations, procyclical cohort-specific shocks are shared partially via the movement of asset prices; cohorts with lower endowments may benefit more from asset pricing dynamics than cohorts with higher endowments. Given a reasonable set of parameters concerning the Japanese labor market, the evaluated welfare loss ranges from 1% to 3% in terms of the certainty equivalence consumption level. The first-best outcome may be achieved by either a combination of subsidies and taxes or the introduction of prior-to-entry markets.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Baker, G., Gibbs, M., and Holmstrom, B. (1994) The internal economics of the firm: Evidence from personnel data. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 881919.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, L. and Mankiw, N.G. (2007) Intergenerational risk sharing in the spirit of Arrow, Debreu, and Rawls, with applications to Social Security design. Journal of Political Economy 111, 523547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benzoni, L., Collin-Dufresne, P., and Goldstein, R.S. (2007) Portfolio choice over the life-cycle when the stock and labor markets are cointegrated. Journal of Finance 62 (5), 21232167.Google Scholar
Bohn, H. (1998) Risk Sharing in a Stochastic Overlapping Generations Economy. Mimeo, University of California, Santa Barbara.Google Scholar
Campbell, J., Cocco, J., Gomes, F., and Maenhout, P. (2001) Investing retirement wealth: A life-cycle model. In Campbell, J.Y. and Feldstein, M. (eds.), Risk Aspects of Investment-Based Social Security Reform, pp. 439473. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. and Nosbusch, Y. (2007) Intergenerational risk sharing and equilibrium asset prices. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 22512268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, D. and Lemieux, T. (2001) Can falling supply explain the rising return to college for younger men? A cohort-based analysis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (2), 705746.Google Scholar
Constantinides, G.M. and Duffie, D. (1996) Asset pricing with heterogeneous consumers. Journal of Political Economy 104 (2), 219240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeMange, G. (2002) On the optimality of intergenerational risk sharing. Economic Theory 31, 2146.Google Scholar
den Haan, W.J. (2007) Assessing the Accuracy of the Aggregate Law of Motion in Models with Heterogeneous Agents. Forthcoming in Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control.Google Scholar
Epstein, L.G. and Zin, S.E. (1989) Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: A theoretical framework. Econometrica 57, 937969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Genda, Y. (1997) One chance: Generations and wage differentials. Monthly Journal of the Japanese Institute of Labor 39 (10), 212. [In Japanese]Google Scholar
Gibbons, R. and Waldman, M. (2006) Enriching a theory of wage and promotion dynamics inside firms. Journal of Labor Economics 24, 59108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, R. and Varian, H. (1988) Intergenerational risk sharing. Journal of Public Economics 37, 185202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayashi, F. and Prescott, E. (2004) Data Appendix to ‘The 1990s in Japan: A Lost Decade.’ Available at fhayashi.fc2web.com/Hayashi-Prescott1.htm. Accessed 17 April 2009.Google Scholar
Huffman, G.W. (1987) A dynamic equilibrium model of asset prices and transaction volume. Journal of Political Economy 95, 138159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahn, L.B. (2007) The Long-Term Labor Market Consequences of Graduating College in a Bad Economy. Mimeo, Harvard University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kletzer, L.G. and Fairlie, R.W. (2003) The long-term costs of job displacement for young adult workers. Industrial Labor Relations Review 56, 683698.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D.M. and Porteus, E.L. (1978) Temporal resolution of uncertainty and dynamic choice theory. Econometrica 46, 185200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, D. and Kubler, F. (2003) Pareto improving Social Security reform when financial markets are incomplete!? American Economic Review 96, 737755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, P. and Smith, A. Jr., (1998) Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. Journal of Political Economy 106, 867896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications (2000) National Survey of Family Income and Expenditure 1999. Tokyo, Japan.Google Scholar
Ministry of Labour and Welfare (2004) Basic Survey on Wage Structure 2003. Tokyo, Japan.Google Scholar
Ohta, S. (1999) Business cycles and job changes: 1965–94. In Nakamura, J. and Nakamura, M. (eds.), The Structural Adjustment of the Japanese Economy and the Decumulation Market, pp. 1342. Tokyo: Nippon-Hyoron-Sha. [In Japanese]Google Scholar
Ohtake, F. and Inoki, T. (1997) Cohort-specific effect on the Japanese labor market. In Asako, K., Fukuda, S., and Yoshino, N. (eds.), The Japanese Economy in Transition: A Macroeconomic Analysis, pp. 297320. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press. [In Japanese]Google Scholar
Ohtake, F. and Saito, M. (1998) Population aging and consumption inequality in Japan. Review of Income and Wealth 44, 361381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okamura, K. (2000) The effect of cohort size in Japan: Career-phase model approach. Monthly Journal of Labor Studies 42 (8), 36–50. [In Japanese]Google Scholar
Poterba, J.M. and Summers, L.H. (1988) Mean reversion in stock prices. Journal of Financial Economics 22, 2759.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shiller, R. (1999) Social Security and intergenerational, intragenerational, and international risk sharing. Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 50, 165204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smetters, K.A. (2004) Trading with the Unborn: A New Perspective on Capital Income Taxation. Mimeo, University of Pennsylvania.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tauchen, G. (1986) Finite state Markov chain approximation to univariate and vector autoregressions. Economic Letters 20, 177181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Wachter, T. and Bender, S. (2006) In the right place at the wrong time: The role of firms and luck in young workers' careers. American Economic Review 96, 16791705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar