Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T10:47:55.859Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A NOTE ON INCREASING HAZARD FUNCTIONS AND THE MONETARY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 June 2014

Fang Yao*
Affiliation:
Reserve Bank of New Zealand and University of Erlangen-Nuremberg
*
Address correspondence to: Fang Yao, P.O. Box 2498, Wellington 6140, New Zealand; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

This note studies the implications of the price reset hazard function for the monetary transmission mechanism of sticky price models. I first document some general analytical results that highlight the central role of the price (accumulative) distribution in linking the hazard function and the impulse response function. I find that nominal rigidity underlying increasing hazard functions is more successful than real rigidity in replicating realistic macro persistence. In addition, numerical simulations show that the interaction between the increasing hazard function and the real rigidity provides a powerful propagation mechanism for monetary shocks.

Type
Notes
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Alvarez, L.J. (2007) What Do Micro Price Data Tell Us on the Validity of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve? Kiel working paper 1330, Kiel Institute for the World Economy.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, L. (1994) Credible disinflation with staggered price-setting. American Economic Review 84 (1), 282289.Google Scholar
Ball, L. and Romer, D. (1990) Real rigidities and the non-neutrality of money. Review of Economic Studies 57 (2), 183203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, G.A. (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (3), 383398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costain, J. and Nakov, A. (2011) Price adjustments in a general model of state-dependent pricing. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43, 385406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golosov, M. and Lucas, R.E. (2007) Menu costs and Phillips curves. Journal of Political Economy 115, 171199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiley, M.T. (2002) Partial adjustment and staggered price setting. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 34 (2), 283-2-98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klenow, P.J. and Kryvtsov, O. (2008) State-dependent or time-dependent pricing: Does it matter for recent U.S. inflation? Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (3), 863904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mankiw, N.G. (2001) The inexorable and mysterious tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Economic Journal 111 (471), C4561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mash, R. (2004) Optimising Microfoundations for Inflation Persistence. Economics series working paper 183, Department of Economics, University of Oxford.Google Scholar
Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2008) Five facts about prices: A reevaluation of menu cost models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (4), 14151464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheedy, K.D. (2010) Intrinsic inflation persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 57 (8), 10491061.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, J.B. (1993) Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39, 195214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whelan, K. (2007) Staggered price contracts and inflation persistence: Some general results. International Economic Review 48 (1), 111145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolman, A.L. (1999) Sticky prices, marginal cost, and the behavior of inflation. Economic Quarterly 3 (Fall), 2948.Google Scholar