Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T01:01:16.083Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

LEARNING AND THE EVOLUTION OF THE FED’S INFLATION TARGET

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 May 2019

Fabio Milani*
Affiliation:
University of California

Abstract

This paper tries to infer and compare the evolution of the Federal Reserve’s (unobserved) inflation target series by estimating a monetary model under the alternative assumptions of rational expectations or subjective expectations and learning. In the estimated model that assumes that economic agents have rational expectations, the implied inflation target displays large shifts over time: it starts at 2% in the early 1960s, it rises to 8% in the 1970s, and it falls to 4% and 2% in the 1980s and 1990s. When the assumption of rational expectations is relaxed in favor of learning by the policymaker, the inferred target is, instead, remarkably stable over time. The target assumes values between 2% and 3% over the whole postwar sample. The findings suggest changing beliefs and learning by the Federal Reserve as major endogenous causes of the perceived variation in the inflation target. When the model is allowed to take the central bank’s evolving beliefs into account, the joint evolution of US inflation, output, and monetary policy decisions can be explained without requiring large exogenous changes in the inflation target.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© 2019 Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

A previous version of this paper was titled “The Evolution of the Fed’s Inflation Target in an Estimated Model under RE and Learning”. I would like to thank the Editor, Associate Editor, and two anonymous referees for comments and suggestions.

References

Belaygorod, A. and Dueker, M. (2005) Discrete monetary policy changes and changing inflation targets in estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 87(6), 719733.Google Scholar
Branch, W. and Evans, G. (2006) A simple recursive forecasting model. Economics Letters 91(2), 158166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bullard, J. and Eusepi, S. (2005) Did the great inflation occur despite policymaker commitment to a Taylor rule. Review of Economic Dynamics 8(2), 324359.Google Scholar
Clarida, R., Galí, J. and Gertler, M. (2000) The science of monetary policy: A new Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 37, 16611707.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cogley, T. and T.Sargent, J. (2005) The conquest of US inflation: Learning and robustness to model uncertainty. Review of Economic Dynamics 8(2), 528563.Google Scholar
Croushore, D. (1998) Evaluating Inflation Forecasts, WP 98-14. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Del Negro, M. and Eusepi, S. (2011) Fitting observed inflation expectations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 35(12), 21052131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dennis, R. (2004) Inferring policy objectives from economic outcomes. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 66, 735764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erceg, C. and Levin, A. (2003) Imperfect credibility and inflation persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 50(4), 915944.Google Scholar
Evans, G. and Honkapohja, S. (1999) Learning dynamics. In: Taylor, J. B., and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, Chapter 7, vol. 1, Part A, pp. 449542. Elsevier.Google Scholar
Evans, G. W. and Honkapohja, S. (2001) Learning and Expectations in Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Favero, C.A. and Rovelli, F. (2003) Macroeconomic stability and the preferences of the Fed: A formal analysis, 1961-98. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 35, 545556.Google Scholar
Ireland, P. (2007) Changes in the Federal Reserves inflation target: Causes and consequences. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39(8), 18511882.Google Scholar
Kozicki, S. and Tinsley, P. (2005) Permanent and transitory policy shocks in an empirical macro model with asymmetric information. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 29, 19852015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lansing, K. (2000) Learning about a shift in trend output: Implications for monetary policy and inflation, WP 2000-16. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.Google Scholar
Leigh, D. (2008) Estimating the Federal Reserve’s implicit inflation target: A state space approach. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32(6), 20132030.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lubik, T. and Schorfheide, F. (2004) Testing for indeterminacy: An application to U.S. monetary policy. American Economic Review 94(1), 190217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milani, F. (2004) Adaptive learning and inflation persistence. UC Irvine Economics WP 05-06-07.Google Scholar
Milani, F. (2006) A Bayesian DSGE model with infinite-horizon learning: Do “Mechanical” sources of persistence become superfluous? International Journal of Central Banking 2(6), 87106.Google Scholar
Milani, F. (2007) Expectations, learning and macroeconomic persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 54(7), 20652082.Google Scholar
Milani, F. (2008) Learning, monetary policy rules, and macroeconomic stability. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32(10), 31483165.Google Scholar
Milani, F. (2011) Expectation shocks and learning as drivers of the business cycle. Economic Journal 121(552), 379401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milani, F. (2017) Sentiment and the U.S. business cycle. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 82, 289311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Molnar, L. and Ormeno, A. (2015) Using survey data of inflation expectations in the estimation of learning and rational expectations models. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 47, 673699.Google Scholar
Orphanides, A. (2001) Monetary policy rules based on real-time data. American Economic Review 91(4), 964985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orphanides, A. and Williams, J. (2005) The decline of activist stabilization policy: Natural rate misperceptions, learning, and expectations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 29(11), 19271950.Google Scholar
Primiceri, G. (2006) Why inflation rose and fell: Policymakers’ beliefs and postwar stabilization policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121, 867901.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sargent, T. J. (1999) The Conquest of American Inflation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sims, C. A. (2000) Solving linear rational expectations models. Computational Economics 20, 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2007) Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review 97(3), 586–560.Google Scholar
Surico, P. (2008) Measuring the time inconsistency of US monetary policy. Economica 75(297), 2238.Google Scholar
Tambalotti, A. (2003) Inflation, productivity and monetary policy: From the great stagflation to the new economy, mimeo, Federal Reserve of New York.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar