Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T21:33:06.737Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

How does trade policy uncertainty affect firms’ pollution emissions? Theory and evidence from China

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 February 2024

Xi Lin
Affiliation:
School of Economics and Statistics, Guangzhou University, Guangzhou, China
Geng Huang
Affiliation:
School of Economics, Jinan University, Guangzhou, China
Ling-Yun He*
Affiliation:
School of Economics, Jinan University, Guangzhou, China
*
Corresponding author: Ling-Yun He; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The literature investigates trade-environment relationship at the firm level, but does not focus on the environmental effect of trade policy uncertainty. In the context of de-globalization and Sino-US trade friction, trade policy uncertainty significantly increases. How does trade policy uncertainty affect firms’ pollution emissions? In this study, we incorporate energy, pollution, and trade policy uncertainty into Melitz’s (2003) framework and construct a theoretical model to reveal the relationship between trade policy uncertainty and pollution emissions. Then, we employ the event that the USA granted permanent normal trade relationship to China as a quasi natural experiment. We use difference-in-difference-in-difference model and the data of Chinese manufacturing firms for empirical analysis. Our results indicate that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity of exporting firms, but has no significant impact on emission levels. Given that these firms do not aggravate emission levels under the condition of expanding output scale, we conclude that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty can improve environmental performance. Mechanism analysis shows an interesting finding that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity mainly by improving energy efficiency rather than improving abatement technology and optimizing energy structure. In addition, pollution reductions mainly occur in pollution-intensive and capital-intensive industries as well as coastal regions. Altogether, this study contributes to the literature on trade-environment relationship and trade policy uncertainty.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

The relationship between trade and environment is a longstanding and challenging topic. International trade is regarded as one of the most important factors affecting environmental pollution (Antweiler et al. Reference Antweiler, Copeland and Taylor2001; Shapiro and Walker, Reference Shapiro and Walker2018). The early literature indicates that trade leads to changes in environmental pollution of various countries (Copeland and Taylor, Reference Copeland and Taylor1994; Antweiler et al. Reference Antweiler, Copeland and Taylor2001). The recent literature investigates this relationship at the firm level, and firm-level works can better reveal the mechanism by which trade affects pollution emissions (Cherniwchan, Reference Cherniwchan2017; Cherniwchan et al. Reference Cherniwchan, Copeland and Taylor2017). However, these works are studied from the perspective of free trade or globalization, focusing on the environmental effects of trade liberalization (Cherniwchan, Reference Cherniwchan2017; Gutiérrez and Teshima, Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018), export behavior (Forslid et al. Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018; Rodrigue et al. Reference Rodrigue, Sheng and Tan2022a), and import behavior (Imbruno and Ketterer, Reference Imbruno and Ketterer2018; He and Huang, Reference He and Huang2022). In recent years, with the emergence of de-globalization and Sino-US trade friction, the uncertainty of trade policy significantly increases (He et al. Reference He, Lin and Zhang2020c; Benguria et al. Reference Benguria, Choi, Swenson and Xu2022). Different from free trade policies, such as trade liberalization and promoting imports and exports, trade policy uncertainty caused by trade protection inevitably has differentiated effects on pollution emissions. However, the literature does not pay sufficient attention to the environmental effect of trade policy uncertainty. Therefore, it is crucial to study how trade policy uncertainty affects firms’ pollution emissions.

According to Pierce and Schott (Reference Pierce and Schott2016), trade policy uncertainty refers to that external trade policies (such as tariff) are uncertain in the future, which corresponds to an increase in expected trade costs faced by firms. Firms are major exporters and pollution emitters. Their behaviors and performances are significantly influenced by trade policy uncertainty (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016; Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2017). Handley and Limão (Reference Handley and Limão2015, Reference Handley and Limão2017) indicate that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces expected trade costs and marginal costs of exporting firms, leading to more exports and output expansion. It further enables firms to invest in technology upgrading (Liu and Ma, Reference Liu and Ma2020). On the one hand, both exports and technology upgrading are conducive to improving energy efficiency and thereby reducing emission intensity (Shapiro and Walker, Reference Shapiro and Walker2018; Forslid et al. Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018). On the other hand, larger output scale results in the higher level of pollution emissions (Cherniwchan, Reference Cherniwchan2017; Rodrigue et al. Reference Rodrigue, Sheng and Tan2022b). As a consequence, the impact of trade policy uncertainty on firm-level pollution emissions is complex. However, the literature does not give an answer to this impact. In this study, we focus on answering the following questions: Does trade policy uncertainty aggravate or reduce firms’ pollution emissions? Through which mechanisms? This study not only contributes to the literature on trade-environment relationship and trade policy uncertainty but also provides implications in the context of de-globalization and Sino-US trade friction.

To reveal how trade policy uncertainty affects pollution emissions, we construct a theoretical model based on Melitz’s (Reference Melitz2003) framework. We expand Melitz’s (Reference Melitz2003) framework by incorporating energy and pollution and introducing trade policy uncertainty referring to Handley and Limão (Reference Handley and Limão2017). Given that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces expected trade costs, it enables firms to invest in production technology and thereby improve energy efficiency. We regard energy efficiency as a special channel to analyze how trade policy uncertainty affects emission intensity and emission levels. As the results of theoretical analysis, we deduce three propositions. First, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity of exporting firms. Second, the impact of trade policy uncertainty on emission levels is uncertain, depending on the changes in emission intensity and output scale. Third, improving energy efficiency is an important mechanism for reducing emission intensity.

Then, we follow Pierce and Schott (Reference Pierce and Schott2016) to employ the event that the USA granted permanent normal trade relationship (PNTR) to China as a quasi natural experiment. Before China’s accession to the WTO, the US Congress annually voted on whether to impose MFN tariff (with lower tariff rate) or column 2 tariff (with higher tariff rate) on Chinese products. After joining the WTO, China was granted PNTR by the USA in 2002. Since then, Chinese products can annually apply to MFN tariff. This event evidently reduces trade policy uncertainty faced by Chinese firms, which provides an exogenous shock to identify the variation in uncertainty (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016; Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2017). In addition, China and the USA are the two largest economies in the world. Their relationship is always the focus of the world. Thus, this event is an excellent case to study the impact of trade policy uncertainty.

We employ the data of Chinese manufacturing firms for empirical analysis. We construct a difference-in-difference-in-difference (DDD) model to examine the causal effect of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on firms’ pollution emissions. Besides, we employ the distance from located city to the nearest port and exchange rate as instrumental variables (IV) of exporting. Our conclusion indicates that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty can reduce emission intensity of exporting firms. To explore how the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity, we examine three potential mechanisms. Our results show that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity mainly by improving energy efficiency rather than improving abatement technology and optimizing energy structure. In addition, mainly for pollution-intensive and capital-intensive industries as well as coastal regions, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty helps to pollution reduction.

Altogether, we contribute to the literature in three primary aspects. First, we are the first to theoretically and empirically reveal how trade policy uncertainty affects firm-level pollution emissions. The literature examines the impact of trade policy on firms’ environmental performance, which focuses on trade liberalization or tariff reduction. Cherniwchan (Reference Cherniwchan2017), Gutiérrez and Teshima (Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018), Cui et al. (Reference Cui, Tam, Wang and Zhang2020), and Liu et al. (Reference Liu, Zhang and Liao2022) find that trade liberalization helps to reduce firms’ pollution emissions. He et al. (Reference He, Lin and Liu2020b) give an opposite conclusion that trade liberalization aggravates pollution emissions.Footnote 1 However, these works are studied from the perspective of free trade or globalization. In the context of de-globalization and Sino-US trade friction, previous conclusions on trade liberalization cannot explain the environmental effect of trade policy uncertainty. It is necessary to study the relationship between trade policy and pollution emissions from the perspective of trade policy uncertainty. To reveal this relationship, we innovatively incorporate energy, pollution, and trade policy uncertainty into Melitz’s (2003) framework.Footnote 2 We then employ Chinese data for empirical examination. Our conclusion reveals that trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity mainly by improving energy efficiency. In particular, we propose a theoretical mechanism that trade policy uncertainty reduces expected trade costs, which enables firms to invest more in upgrading production technology and thereby improve energy efficiency.Footnote 3 This finding is different from the literature that regards abatement technology as the mechanism by which trade reduces pollution emissions (Forslid et al. Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018; Rodrigue et al. Reference Rodrigue, Sheng and Tan2022a; Kwon et al. Reference Kwon, Zhao and Zhao2023).

Second, we rely on an exogenous event that the USA granted PNTR to China to provide a novel evidence for the causal effect of exports on firm-level pollution emissions. The literature focuses on the relationship between firms’ export behavior and environmental performance. These works provide evidences to support that exporting firms have better environmental performance relative to non-exporting firms (Roy and Yasar, Reference Roy and Yasar2015; Cui et al. Reference Cui, Lapan and Moschini2016; Holladay, Reference Holladay2016; Banerjee et al. Reference Banerjee, Roy and Yasar2021; Kwon et al. Reference Kwon, Zhao and Zhao2023). Forslid et al. (Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018), and He and Huang (Reference He and Huang2021) explain this relationship by constructing firm-level model based on Melitz’s (2003) framework. Richter and Schiersch (Reference Richter and Schiersch2017) and Lin and He (Reference Lin and He2023a) indicate that firms with higher export intensity are cleaner. Barrows and Ollivier (Reference Barrows and Ollivier2018) show the relationship between exporting product mix and environmental performance. Barrows and Ollivier (Reference Barrows and Ollivier2021) find that foreign demand growth leads to export expansion, which aggravates emissions but reduces emission intensity. However, these works mainly employ export behavior as core variables. These variables are strongly endogenous due to self-selection effect (Melitz, Reference Melitz2003; Lin and He, Reference Lin and He2023a), which is difficult to capture the causal effect of exports. Given that trade policy uncertainty is closely related to firms’ export behavior (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016; Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2017), the event that the USA granted PNTR to China provides an exogenous shock to identify the causal effect of exports.

Third, we contribute to the literature on the impact of trade policy uncertainty from an environmental perspective. The literature investigates micro-level impacts of trade policy uncertainty. Some works find that trade policy uncertainty hinders firms’ exports (Handley, Reference Handley2014; Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2015, Reference Handley and Limão2017; Feng et al. Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017). Other works show that this uncertainty affects labor employment (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016), investment (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016), and innovation (Liu and Ma, Reference Liu and Ma2020). Handley and Limão (Reference Handley and Limão2017) provide an approach to introduce trade policy certainty into Melitz’s (2003) model for theoretical analysis. As an important behavior of firms, firms’ pollution emissions are closely related to the environmental quality of located region. Besides, pollution emissions are influenced by export behavior (Forslid et al. Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018), technical level (Shapiro and Walker, Reference Shapiro and Walker2018), and output scale (Cherniwchan, Reference Cherniwchan2017), implying that trade policy uncertainty is a potential factor affecting pollution emissions. In this study, we reveal a novel impact of trade policy uncertainty on firms’ pollution emissions.

The remainder of this study is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a decomposition of firm-level pollution emissions. Section 3 constructs a theoretical model to analyze the environment effect of trade policy uncertainty. Section 4 introduces empirical strategy and data. Section 5 presents empirical results. Section 6 concludes.

2. A decomposition of firm-level pollution emissions

To reveal the potential mechanism by which trade policy uncertainty affects firms’ pollution emissions, we propose a novel decomposition of pollution emissions. The literature focuses on the decomposition at macro-level (Grossman and Krueger, Reference Grossman and Krueger1991; Antweiler et al. Reference Antweiler, Copeland and Taylor2001). Different from these works, we decompose pollution emissions from the perspective of micro-firms. Our decomposition is also different from other firm-level decomposition (Cherniwchan et al. Reference Cherniwchan, Copeland and Taylor2017).

First, the change in pollution emissions may be driven by the change in technology or output scale (Cherniwchan, Reference Cherniwchan2017; Lin and He, Reference Lin and He2023a). We decompose pollution emissions into emission intensity and output value, as shown in Eq. (1). Emission intensity is emission levels per unit of output value, reflecting the technology related to emissions. Firms with advanced technology have lower emission intensity, and they thereby emit less pollution under the condition of equal output value. Besides, output value is related to production scale. Under the condition of equal emission intensity, firms with larger scale inevitably have more pollution emissions.

(1) \begin{equation} Emissions=\underbrace{\frac{Emissions}{Output}}_{\substack{\textrm{Emission}\\ \textrm{intensity}}}\times \underbrace{Output}_{\substack{\textrm{Output}\\ \textrm{value}}} \end{equation}

Second, we decompose emission intensity to explore the channels of changing emission intensity. The technologies related to pollution emissions include production technology and abatement technology (Liu et al. Reference Liu, Tan and Zhang2021; Lin and He, Reference Lin and He2023a, Reference Lin and He2023b). We decompose emission intensity into the reciprocal of energy efficiency and abatement technology, as shown in equation (2). Energy efficiency is the output value per unit of energy consumption, reflecting the production technology related to energy input (Brucal et al. Reference Brucal, Javorcik and Love2019; Huang et al. Reference Huang, He and Lin2022). Firms with more advanced production technology have higher energy efficiency. They consume less energy per unit of output value and have lower emission intensity. Besides, abatement technology is emission levels per unit of energy consumption. Industrial emissions mainly come from energy consumption (Gutiérrez and Teshima, Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018). Firms with advanced abatement technology have stronger ability to terminally remove pollution (Liu et al. Reference Liu, Tan and Zhang2021). As a result, they emit less pollution per unit of energy consumption and have lower emission intensity (Lin and He, Reference Lin and He2023a).

(2) \begin{equation} \underbrace{\frac{Emissions}{Output}}_{\substack{\textrm{Emission}\\ \textrm{intensity}}}=\underbrace{\frac{Energy}{Output}}_{\substack{\textrm{Reciprocal}\\ \textrm{ of\ energy}\\ \textrm{efficiency}}}\times \underbrace{\frac{Emissions}{Energy}}_{\substack{\textrm{Abatement}\\ \textrm{technology}\\ \textrm{(a)}}}=\underbrace{\frac{Energy}{Output}}_{\substack{\textrm{Reciprocal}\\ \textrm{of\ energy}\\ \textrm{efficiency}}}\times \underbrace{\frac{Emissions}{Coal}}_{\substack{\textrm{Abatement}\\ \textrm{technology}\\ \textrm{(b)}}}\times \underbrace{\frac{Coal}{Energy}}_{\substack{\textrm{Energy}\\ \textrm{structure}}} \end{equation}

Third, emission levels per unit of energy consumption are influenced by energy structure. More emissions are from coal consumption, and other energies (such as fuel oil and clean gas) are cleaner. We decompose abatement technology into emission levels per unit of coal consumption and energy structure, as shown in equation (2). Emission levels per unit of coal consumption are related to abatement technology. Firms with advanced abatement technology have fewer emissions per unit of coal consumption and lower emission intensity (Liu et al. Reference Liu, Tan and Zhang2021). Besides, energy structure is the ratio of coal consumption to total energy consumption, reflecting the proportion of dirty energy. Firms consuming coals have higher emission intensity.

We employ the dataset merged by the Chinese Environmental Statistics Firm Database (CESFD) and the Chinese Industrial Firm Database (CIFD) to decompose the pollution emissions of Chinese firms. We employ sulfur dioxide (SO $_2$ ) as the pollutant to calculate the change rates of pollution emissions and decomposed variables relative to the baseline year (1998), as shown in Figure 1. The left panel shows that on average, firms’ pollution emissions are fluctuating. Output scale keeps increasing, while emission intensity shows a downward trend. In addition, the right panel shows that the decrease of emission intensity is driven by increasing energy efficiency, improving abatement technology, and optimizing energy structure. In particular, the increase in energy efficiency makes the greatest contribution. The changes of energy efficiency and emission intensity show similar trends (especially after 2002).

Figure 1. The change rates of pollution emission and decomposed variables of industrial firms in China, 1998-2012. Data sources: Calculation by the data from the Chinese Environmental Statistics Firm Database (CESFD) and the Chinese Industrial Firm Database (CIFD). Note: We employ SO2 as the pollutant and 1998 as the baseline year. We delete the extreme values ranking in the top and bottom 1%.

From this Figure, there are two findings. The first one suggests that after 2001, Chinese firms expanded output scale and reduced emission intensity. This may be due to the decrease in trade policy uncertainty. The literature supports that Chinese firms expand output and reduce emission intensity after 2001, but these works focus on the impact of trade liberalization rather than trade policy uncertainty (Brandt et al. Reference Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, Wang and Zhang2017; Cui et al. Reference Cui, Tam, Wang and Zhang2020). The second finding is that the change in emission intensity is mainly driven by the channel of energy efficiency. This is similar to Gutiérrez and Teshima (Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018), that is, firms in developing countries mainly reduce emissions by improving energy efficiency. Thus, we focus on employing energy efficiency as a mechanism to analyze the impact of trade policy uncertainty on pollution emissions.

3. Theoretical model

3.1. Model setup

Our major setup is based on Melitz’s (2003) model. We assume that there are two countries (home and foreign countries). Each country consists of a monopolistic competitive industry. Firms have heterogeneous production technologies (i.e. productivity). Each firm produces a product under increasing returns to scale. Different from Melitz’s (2003) model, firms use labor and energy as production factors. Energy consumption produces pollution as by-products. Due to environmental regulation, firms need to pay for pollution emissions, such as pollution tax. To simplify this analysis, we assume that the stringency of environmental regulation is fixed.

3.1.1. Demand

For two countries, the utility function of representative consumers is standard constant elasticity of substitution (CES) form.

(3) \begin{equation} U=\left [ \int _{\omega \in \Omega }q\left ( \omega \right )^{\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma } }d\omega \right ]^{\frac{\sigma }{\sigma -1}} \end{equation}

where $U$ is the utility of representative consumers. $q\left ( \omega \right )$ is the demand of product variety $\omega$ , and $\Omega$ denotes the set of product variety. $\sigma$ is the substitution elasticity among different varieties. $\rho =\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }$ , $\sigma \gt 1$ and $0\lt \rho \lt 1$ .

Then, we calculate the demands of products in domestic and foreign markets.

(4) \begin{align} q_{h}&=\frac{R_{h}P_{h}^{\sigma -1}}{\left ( p_{h} \right )^{\sigma }} \end{align}
(5) \begin{align} q_{x}&=\frac{R_{x}P_{x}^{\sigma -1}}{\left ( p_{x} \right )^{\sigma }} \end{align}

where $q_{h}$ and $q_{x}$ are the demands of products in domestic and export markets. $p_{h}$ and $p_{x}$ are the prices of products in domestic and export markets. $P_{h}$ and $P_{x}$ are aggregate price indexes in domestic and export markets. $R_{h}$ and $R_{x}$ are aggregate expenditure indexes in domestic and export markets.

3.1.2. Production

We assume that firms employ labor and energy in production. Firms’ productivity ( $\varphi$ ) comes from a distribution function $G(\varphi )$ which is subject to the Pareto distribution. After paying fixed cost ( $f$ ) to enter the industry, firms randomly draw their productivity from $G(\varphi )$ . The initial productivity of firms is heterogeneous and exogenous. Firms can upgrade production technology (such as independent innovation and purchasing production equipment) to improve productivity. Investing in production technology requires payment of fixed costs (Bustos, Reference Bustos2011). Each firm decides the optimal investment for production technology according to own profit.

The production function is Cobb-Douglas form, including two kinds of production factors (energy and labor). We incorporate production technology investment referring to Bustos (Reference Bustos2011).

(6) \begin{equation} q=h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi e^{\alpha } l^{1-\alpha } \end{equation}

where $q$ is firms’ output. $e$ and $l$ are the levels of energy consumption and labor employment. $\alpha$ and $1-\alpha$ are the shares in energy and labor inputs. $f_R$ represents the investment in production technology. According to Bustos (Reference Bustos2011), if firms want to upgrade production technology, they need to pay fixed costs. $h\left ( f_R \right )$ is the function for effect of production technology investment. $h'\left ( f_R \right )\gt 0$ and $h\left ( 0 \right )=1$ . When firms invest more in production technology, they gain higher productivity. The marginal effect of production technology investment on profit decreases progressively.Footnote 4

We assume that the wage of labor employment is $w$ ( $w=1$ ) and the price of energy consumption is $P_e$ . Firms’ optimal choice of labor employment and energy consumption is based on the prices of production factors. Namely, the marginal rate of technical substitution is equal to the ratio of wage to energy price ( $MRTS=\cfrac{\ \frac{\partial q}{\partial l} \ }{\ \frac{\partial q}{\partial e} \ } =\frac{1}{P_e}$ ). By calculations, firms’ labor employment and energy consumption are as follows:

(7) \begin{align} l&=\frac{q}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi } \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha }{P_{e}} ^{\alpha } \end{align}
(8) \begin{align} e&=\frac{q}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi } \left ( \frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha } \right ) ^{1-\alpha }{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1} \end{align}

We calculate firms’ energy efficiency by the ratio of output to energy consumption.

(9) \begin{equation} \varphi _e=\frac{q}{e} =h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{1-\alpha }{P_{e}} ^{1-\alpha } \end{equation}

where $\varphi _e$ is firms’ energy efficiency.

Energy consumption produces pollution as by-products. Firms’ emission intensity and emission levels are as follows:

(10) \begin{align} \gamma &=\frac{z}{q}=\frac{z}{e} \times \frac{e}{q} =\frac{\theta }{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi } \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha -1}{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1}\end{align}
(11) \begin{align} z&=\frac{z}{q}\times q=\frac{\theta q}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi } \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha -1}{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1} \end{align}

where $\gamma$ and $z$ are emission intensity and emission levels. $\theta$ is the emission levels per unit of energy consumption, which reflects abatement technology introduced in Section 2.

Firms not only pay fixed costs for production and production technology investment but also pay variable costs for labor and energy. Due to environmental regulation, firms need to pay for pollution emissions. The total cost function of production (or domestic sales) is as follows:

(12) \begin{equation} TC_h=f+f_R+eP_e+l+zP_z=f+f_R+\frac{q{_h} k}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi } \end{equation}

where $TC_h$ is the total cost of domestic sales. $P_z$ is the cost per unit of pollution emissions. $k=\left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha -1}{P_e}^{\alpha -1} \left ( \frac{P_e}{\alpha }+\theta P_z \right )$ .

If firms export to foreign markets, they need to pay additional fixed cost and iceberg cost. The total cost function of exporting is as follows:

(13) \begin{equation} TC_x=f+f_R+f_x+\tau eP_e+\tau l+\tau zP_z=f+f_R+f_x+\frac{\tau q{_x} k}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi } \end{equation}

where $TC_x$ is the total cost of exporting. $f_x$ is the fixed cost of exporting. $\tau$ is iceberg cost, such as tariff.Footnote 5 To simplify the theoretical analysis, we use tariff to represent iceberg cost.

Referring to Handley and Limão (Reference Handley and Limão2017), we design a simple way to introduce trade policy uncertainty. When there is no trade policy uncertainty in foreign country, foreign country imposes a lower tariff $t$ . Iceberg cost is $\tau =1+t$ . When there is a trade policy uncertainty, foreign country has a probability $\delta \left ( 0\lt \delta \lt 1 \right )$ to impose a higher tariff $\left ( t+\bigtriangleup t \right )$ . Foreign country still has a probability $\left ( 1- \delta \right )$ to impose a lower tariff $t$ . That is to say, $\delta$ represents the existence of trade policy uncertainty. In addition, $\bigtriangleup t$ is the difference between higher and lower tariffs. Following Pierce and Schott (Reference Pierce and Schott2016), we use $\bigtriangleup t$ to represent the degree of trade policy uncertainty. $\bigtriangleup t$ is larger, meaning that firms face a higher potential tariff rate. As a result, these firms are influenced by a higher degree of trade policy uncertainty.Footnote 6 In this case, the expected iceberg cost is as follows:

(14) \begin{equation} \tau '=\delta \left ( t+\bigtriangleup t \right ) +\left ( 1-\delta \right ) t+1 \end{equation}

where $\tau '\gt \tau$ and $\frac{\partial \tau '}{\partial \bigtriangleup t} \gt 0$ . When there is a trade policy uncertainty, the expected iceberg cost would be higher. Facing trade policy uncertainty, the total cost function of exporting is as follows:

(15) \begin{equation} {TC_x}'=f+f_R+f_x+\tau 'eP_e+\tau 'l+\tau 'zP_z=f+f_R+f_x+\frac{\tau 'q{_x}' k}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi } \end{equation}

where ${TC_x}'$ is the total cost of exporting in the presence of trade policy uncertainty. We further calculate marginal costs. $MC_h=\frac{k}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }$ is the marginal cost of domestic sales. $MC_x=\frac{\tau k}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }$ and ${MC_x}'=\frac{\tau 'k}{h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }$ are marginal costs of exporting without and with trade policy uncertainty.

3.2. Firm behavior

According to monopolistic competitive industry and the CES utility function of consumers, firms set the profit-maximizing price by a constant markup over marginal cost. We calculate optimal prices of firms’ products in domestic and foreign markets. $p_h=\frac{k}{\rho h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }$ is the price of domestic sales. $p_x=\frac{\tau k}{\rho h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }$ and ${p_x}'=\frac{\tau 'k}{\rho h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }$ are the prices of exporting without and with trade policy uncertainty. We further calculate the volume of sales in domestic and export markets. $q_h=R{_h}P{_h}^{\sigma -1}\left [ \frac{\rho h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }{k} \right ]^\sigma$ is the volume of domestic sales. $q_x=R{_x}P{_x}^{\sigma -1}\left [ \frac{\rho h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }{\tau k} \right ]^\sigma$ and ${q_x}'=R{_x}P{_x}^{\sigma -1}\left [ \frac{\rho h\left ( f_R \right ) \varphi }{\tau 'k} \right ]^\sigma$ are volumes of exports without and with trade policy uncertainty.

We calculate the profit functions of domestic sales and exporting. In particular, exporting firms serve both domestic and foreign markets, which is consistent with Melitz (Reference Melitz2003).

(16) \begin{align} \pi _h&=B{_h}\left [ h\left ( f_R \right )\varphi \right ]^{\sigma -1}-f-f_R \end{align}
(17) \begin{align} \pi _x&=\left ( B{_h}+B{_x}\tau ^{1-\sigma } \right ) \left [ h\left ( f_R \right )\varphi \right ]^{\sigma -1}-f-f_R-f_x \end{align}
(18) \begin{align} {\pi _x}'&=\left ( B{_h}+B{_x}\tau '^{1-\sigma } \right ) \left [ h\left ( f_R \right )\varphi \right ]^{\sigma -1}-f-f_R-f_x \end{align}

where $\pi _h$ is the profit of domestic sales. $B{_h}=\frac{R{_h} P{_h}^{\sigma -1}\rho ^{\sigma -1}}{\sigma k^{\sigma -1}}$ . The profit of firms which sell in the domestic market is not influenced by trade policy uncertainty. In subsequent analysis, we focus on exporting firms.Footnote 7 $\pi _x$ and ${\pi _x}'$ are the profits of exporting firms without and with trade policy uncertainty. $B{_x}=\frac{R{_x} P{_x}^{\sigma -1}\rho ^{\sigma -1}}{\sigma k^{\sigma -1}}$ . These profits are earned from domestic and export markets.

To simply solve the model, we assume the specific form of the function for production technology investment, that is $h\left ( f_R \right )=\left ( 1+f_R \right )^{\frac{b}{\sigma -1} }$ . This function meets $h'\left ( f_R \right )\gt 0$ and $h\left ( 0 \right )=1$ . Due to that the marginal effect of production technology investment on firm profit is decreasing ( $\frac{{\partial ^2}\pi }{\partial \left ( f_R \right )^2 }\lt 0$ ), we get $0\lt b\lt 1$ . For Eqs. (17) and (18), according to the condition of profit maximization ( $\frac{\partial \pi }{\partial f_R } =0$ ), we calculate the optimal levels of production technology investment.

(19) \begin{align} f_{Rx}&=\left ( B{_h}+B{_x}\tau ^{1-\sigma } \right )^{\frac{1}{1-b} }\varphi ^{\frac{\sigma -1}{1-b} }b ^{\frac{1}{1-b} }-1 \end{align}
(20) \begin{align} {f_{Rx}}'&=\left ( B{_h}+B{_x}\tau '^{1-\sigma } \right )^{\frac{1}{1-b} }\varphi ^{\frac{\sigma -1}{1-b} }b ^{\frac{1}{1-b} }-1 \end{align}

where $f_{Rx}$ and ${f_{Rx}}'$ are optimal levels of production technology investment for exporting firms without and with trade policy uncertainty. Since $\tau \lt \tau '$ , we get $f_{Rx}\gt{f_{Rx}}'$ . When there is a trade policy uncertainty, firms invest less in their production technology. This is because exporting firms may be subject to a higher expected tariff in the presence of trade policy uncertainty, and expected iceberg cost faced by firms is also higher. As a result, they reduce the cost for production technology investment.

Furthermore, we put Eq. (14) into Eq. (20) and calculate the partial derivative of $\bigtriangleup t$ .

(21) \begin{equation} \frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t} =\frac{1-\sigma }{1-b} B{_x}\delta \tau '^{-\sigma }\left ( B{_h}+B{_x}\tau '^{1-\sigma } \right )^{\frac{b}{1-b} }\varphi ^{\frac{\sigma -1}{1-b} }b ^{\frac{1}{1-b} }\lt 0 \end{equation}

From Eq. (21), the increase in trade policy uncertainty reduces production technology investment. Conversely, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty helps to upgrade production technology. The reason is that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces expected iceberg cost, making exporting firms invest more in production technology.

3.3. Energy efficiency and pollution emissions

We put $h\left ( f_R \right )=\left ( 1+f_R \right )^{\frac{b}{\sigma -1} }$ as well as equations (19) and (20) into equation (9) to calculate the energy efficiency of exporting firms.

(22) \begin{align} \varphi _{ex}&=\left ( 1+f_{Rx} \right )^{\frac{b}{\sigma -1} } \varphi \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{1-\alpha }{P_{e}} ^{1-\alpha } \end{align}
(23) \begin{align} {\varphi _{ex}}'&=\left ( 1+{f_{Rx}}' \right )^{\frac{b}{\sigma -1} } \varphi \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{1-\alpha }{P_{e}} ^{1-\alpha } \end{align}

where $\varphi _{ex}$ and ${\varphi _{ex}}'$ are the energy efficiency of exporting firms without and with trade policy uncertainty. Since $f_{Rx}\gt{f_{Rx}}'$ , we get $\varphi _{ex}\gt{\varphi _{ex}}'$ . When there is a trade policy uncertainty, exporting firms reduce energy efficiency. The reason is that if exporting firms face trade policy uncertainty, they would be influenced by higher expected iceberg cost and reduce production technology investment. This reduction in production technology investment leads to lower energy efficiency.

In addition, we analyze the impact of change in trade policy uncertainty ( $\bigtriangleup t$ ) on firm-level energy efficiency. For equation (23), we calculate the partial derivative of $\bigtriangleup t$ .

(24) \begin{equation} \frac{\partial{\varphi _{ex}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t} ={\frac{b}{\sigma -1} }\left ( 1+{f_{Rx}}' \right )^{\frac{b-\sigma +1}{\sigma -1} } \frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\varphi \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{1-\alpha }{P_{e}} ^{1-\alpha }\lt 0 \end{equation}

Given that the increase in trade policy uncertainty reduces production technology investment ( $\frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\lt 0$ ), we get $\frac{\partial{\varphi _{ex}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\lt 0$ . This result suggests that the increase in trade policy uncertainty reduces exporting firms’ energy efficiency. Conversely, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty is conducive to improving energy efficiency. This improvement of energy efficiency is driven by decreasing expected iceberg cost and thereby upgrading production technology.

Then, we put $h\left ( f_R \right )=\left ( 1+f_R \right )^{\frac{b}{\sigma -1} }$ as well as equations (19) and (20) into equation (10) to calculate the emission intensity of exporting firms.

(25) \begin{align} \gamma _{x}&=\frac{\theta }{\varphi } \left ( 1+f_{Rx} \right )^{\frac{b}{1-\sigma } } \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha -1}{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1} \end{align}
(26) \begin{align} {\gamma _{x}}'&=\frac{\theta }{\varphi } \left ( 1+{f_{Rx}}' \right )^{\frac{b}{1-\sigma } } \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha -1}{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1} \end{align}

where $\gamma _{x}$ and ${\gamma _{x}}'$ are the emission intensity of exporting firms without and with trade policy uncertainty. Since $f_{Rx}\gt{f_{Rx}}'$ and $\frac{b}{1-\sigma }\lt 0$ , we get $\gamma _{x}\lt{\gamma _{x}}'$ . Exporting firms increase emission intensity in the presence of trade policy uncertainty. The reason is that when there is a trade policy uncertainty, exporting firms reduce production technology investment due to the increase in expected cost and thereby reduce energy efficiency. This leads to higher emission intensity.

Also, we analyze the impact of change in trade policy uncertainty ( $\bigtriangleup t$ ) on emission intensity. We calculate the partial derivative of $\bigtriangleup t$ for equation (26).

(27) \begin{equation} \frac{\partial{\gamma _{x}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t} =\frac{\theta }{\varphi } \left ({\frac{b}{1-\sigma } } \right ) \left ( 1+{f_{Rx}}' \right )^{\frac{b+\sigma -1}{1-\sigma } } \frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha -1}{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1}\gt 0 \end{equation}

Since $\frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\lt 0$ and $\frac{b}{1-\sigma }\lt 0$ , we get $\frac{\partial{\gamma _{x}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\gt 0$ . This result indicates that the increase in trade policy uncertainty increases emission intensity. On the contrary, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. The theoretical mechanism is that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces expected trade cost faced by exporting firms, leading to more investments in production technology and thereby improving energy efficiency. It can help to reduce emission intensity of exporting firms. This implies the following proposition:

Proposition 1. The decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity of exporting firms.

Next, emission levels are the product of emission intensity and output. We put $h\left ( f_R \right )=\left ( 1+f_R \right )^{\frac{b}{\sigma -1} }$ as well as equations (19) and (20) into $q_h$ , $q_x$ , and ${q_x}'$ to calculate the volumes of domestic sales and exports. It is noted that exporting firms’ output includes domestic sales and exports.

(28) \begin{align} q_h+q_x&=RP^{\sigma -1}\left [ \frac{\rho \varphi }{k} \right ]^\sigma \left ( 1+f_R \right )^{\frac{\sigma b}{1-\sigma } }\left ( 1+\frac{1}{\tau ^\sigma } \right ) \end{align}
(29) \begin{align} q_h+{q_x}'&=RP^{\sigma -1}\left [ \frac{\rho \varphi }{k} \right ]^\sigma \left ( 1+{f_R}' \right )^{\frac{\sigma b}{1-\sigma } }\left ( 1+\frac{1}{{\tau '}^\sigma } \right ) \end{align}

where $\left (q_h+q_x \right )$ and $\left (q_h+{q_x}' \right )$ are the outputs of exporting firms without and with trade policy uncertainty. Since $f_{Rx}\gt{f_{Rx}}'$ and $\tau \lt \tau '$ , we get $q_h+q_x \gt q_h+{q_x}'$ . Exporting firms reduce output scale in the presence of trade policy uncertainty. The explanation is that when there is a trade policy uncertainty, exporting firms face higher iceberg cost and reduce production technology investment. As a result, their output scale would be decreased.

We further analyze the impact of change in trade policy uncertainty ( $\bigtriangleup t$ ) on output scale. For equation (29), we calculate the partial derivative of $\bigtriangleup t$ .

(30) \begin{align} \frac{\partial \left ( q_h+{q_x}' \right ) }{\partial \bigtriangleup t} &=RP^{\sigma -1}\left ( \frac{\rho \varphi }{k}\right )^\sigma \left [ \frac{\sigma b}{1-\sigma }\left ( 1+{f_R}' \right )^{\frac{\sigma \left ( b+1 \right )-1 }{1-\sigma } }{\frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}}\left ( 1+\frac{1}{{\tau '}^\sigma } \right )\right.\nonumber\\&\quad \left.-\left ( 1+{f_R}' \right )^{\frac{\sigma b }{1-\sigma } }\frac{\sigma }{{\tau '}^{\sigma +1}}{\frac{\partial{\tau '}}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}} \right ]\lt 0 \end{align}

Since $\frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\lt 0$ and $\frac{\partial{\tau '}}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\gt 0$ , we get $\frac{\partial \left ( q_h+{q_x}' \right ) }{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\lt 0$ . Namely, the increase in trade policy uncertainty reduces output scale. Conversely, if exporting firms face less trade policy uncertainty, they expand output scale. The explanation is that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to more investments in production technology and decrease in expected trade cost, which helps to expanding output of exporting firms.

We put $h\left ( f_R \right )=\left ( 1+f_R \right )^{\frac{b}{\sigma -1} }$ as well as equations (19), (20), (28), and (29) into equation. (11) to calculate the emission levels of exporting firms.

(31) \begin{align} z_{x}&=\frac{\theta \left ( q_h+q_x \right ) }{\varphi } \left ( 1+f_{Rx} \right )^{\frac{b}{1-\sigma } } \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha -1}{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1}\end{align}
(32) \begin{align} {z_{x}}'&=\frac{\theta \left ( q_h+{q_x}'\right ) }{\varphi } \left ( 1+{f_{Rx}}'\right )^{\frac{b}{1-\sigma } } \left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } \right ) ^{\alpha -1}{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1}\end{align}

where $z_{x}$ and ${z_{x}}'$ are emission levels of exporting firms without and with trade policy uncertainty. Based on above analyses, $f_{Rx}\gt{f_{Rx}}'$ , $\frac{b}{1-\sigma }\lt 0$ and $q_h+q_x\gt q_h+{q_x}'$ . Thus, the relative sizes of $z_{x}$ and ${z_{x}}'$ are uncertain. Namely, when exporting firms face trade policy uncertainty, it is uncertain whether they increase or reduce emission levels. The reason is that on the one hand, trade policy uncertainty leads to increasing emission intensity; on the other hand, trade policy uncertainty reduces output scale. Smaller firms have lower emission levels, while firms with higher emission intensity have higher emission levels. As a result, the impact of trade policy uncertainty on emission levels is uncertain.

We continue to analyze the impact of change in trade policy uncertainty ( $\bigtriangleup t$ ) on emission levels. For equation (32), we calculate the partial derivative of $\bigtriangleup t$ .

(33) \begin{align} \frac{\partial{z_{x}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t} &=\frac{\theta }{\varphi }\left ( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right )^{\alpha -1}{P_{e}} ^{\alpha -1}\left [\frac{\partial \left (q_h+{q_x}'\right ) }{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\left ( 1+{f_R}'\right )^{\frac{b}{1-\sigma } }\right.\nonumber\\&\quad\left. +\left (q_h+{q_x}'\right ){\frac{b}{1-\sigma } }\left ( 1+{f_R}'\right )^{\frac{b+\sigma -1}{1-\sigma } }\frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t} \right ] \end{align}

From above analyses, $\frac{\partial \left (q_h+{q_x}'\right ) }{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\lt 0$ , $\frac{\partial{f_{Rx}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\lt 0$ , and $\frac{b}{1-\sigma }\lt 0$ . It is uncertain that $\frac{\partial{z_{x}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}$ is greater or less than 0. The impacts of changing trade policy uncertainty are uncertain. This is because the decrease in trade policy uncertainty not only reduces emission intensity but also expands output scale. Both emission intensity and output scale are correlated with emission levels.

Given that emission levels are the product of emission intensity and output, that is ${z_{x}}' ={\gamma _{x}}'\left ( q_h+{q_x}' \right )$ , we calculate the partial derivative of $\bigtriangleup t$ .

(34) \begin{equation} \frac{\partial{z_{x}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}=\underbrace{\frac{\partial{\gamma _{x}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\left ( q_h+{q_x}' \right ) }_{{\gt 0}}+ \underbrace{\frac{\partial \left ( q_h+{q_x}' \right )}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}{\gamma _{x}}'}_{{\lt 0}} \end{equation}

Equation (34) also suggests that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity and expands output scale. The impact of trade policy uncertainty on emission levels depends on the relative sizes of these two channels. This implies the following proposition:

Proposition 2. The impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on emission levels of exporting firms is uncertain, which depends on the relative changes in emission intensity and output scale.

Finally, emission intensity can be decomposed into energy efficiency and abatement technology, that is $\gamma =\frac{\theta }{\varphi _e}$ . From above analyses, improving energy efficiency can reduce firms’ emission intensity, that is $\frac{\partial \gamma }{\partial \varphi _e} \lt 0$ . The decrease in trade policy uncertainty increases production technology investment and thereby improves energy efficiency, that is $\frac{\partial{\varphi _{ex}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}\lt 0$ .

(35) \begin{equation} \frac{\partial{\gamma _{x}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}=\underbrace{\frac{\partial{\gamma _{x}}'}{\partial{\varphi _{ex}}'}}_{{\lt 0}}\times \underbrace{\frac{\partial{\varphi _{ex}}'}{\partial \bigtriangleup t}}_{{\lt 0}}\gt 0 \end{equation}

This equation indicates that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces exporting firms’ emission intensity by the mechanism of upgrading production technology and thereby improving energy efficiency. This implies the following proposition:

Proposition 3. Improving energy efficiency is an important mechanism by which the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity of exporting firms.

4. Empirical strategy and data

4.1. Identifying the impact of trade policy uncertainty

Our theoretical model has predicted the potential relationship between trade policy uncertainty and firms’ pollution emissions. We employ the data of Chinese manufacturing firms to examine this relationship. We follow Pierce and Schott (Reference Pierce and Schott2016) and regard the permanent normal trade relationship (PNTR) granted to China by the USA in 2002 as a quasi natural experiment. This event has been adopted by other literature to identify the causal effect of trade policy uncertainty (Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2017; Feng et al. Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017; Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2018; Liu and Ma, Reference Liu and Ma2020). We construct a DDD model to analyze the impact of trade policy uncertainty on pollution emissions. We introduce the background of this event and the measurement of industry-level trade policy uncertainty as follows.

4.1.1. Event background

Before China’s entry into the WTO, the USA granted temporary normal trade relationship to China. The US Congress annually voted on whether to grant normal trade relationship to China. If China was granted normal trade relationship, the USA imposed MFN tariff (with lower tariff rate) on Chinese products. Otherwise, the USA imposed column 2 tariff (with higher tariff rate). The column 2 tariff originated from the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act in 1930. This tariff is applicable to countries that do not establish normal trade relationship with the USA. This tariff rate is much higher relative to MFN tariff. In other words, it was uncertain whether the USA granted MFN tariff to China every year. According to Pierce and Schott (Reference Pierce and Schott2016), from 1990 to 1992, the USA continuously refused to grant MFN tariff to China; from 1990 to 2001, the proportion of negative votes is approximately 39%. Taking 2000 as an example, if China failed to be granted MFN tariff, the average tariff rate would be increased from 7% to 31%. We can see that before the USA granted PNTR to China, Chinese firms faced a higher degree of trade policy uncertainty.

After China’s entry into the WTO, the USA granted PNTR to China on January 1, 2002. Since then, the USA granted MFN tariff to China every year. China’s external trade policy uncertainty significantly decreases. Benefiting from this event, the number of Chinese exporting firms rapidly increases, and firms’ export scale expands (Feng et al. Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017). Based on this background, the event that the USA granted PNTR to China in 2002 provides a quasi natural experiment for identifying the causal effect of changing trade policy uncertainty.

According to Pierce and Schott (Reference Pierce and Schott2016), before the USA granted PNTR to China in 2002, the differences in tariff rates between column 2 tariff and MFN tariff for various industries were different. The industries with greater difference in tariff rates experienced greater decrease in trade policy uncertainty after this event. The reason is that if there is a greater difference between two types of tariffs for a given industry, firms would potentially face a higher expected trade cost before the USA granted PNTR to China. After the USA granted PNTR to China, trade policy uncertainty would decrease to a greater extent. On the contrary, if there is only a smaller difference between two types of tariffs for a given industry, the expected trade cost would not decrease too much after the USA granted PNTR to China. Therefore, we can employ the difference between column 2 tariff and MFN tariff for various industries in China before the USA granted PNTR to China to measure the decrease in trade policy uncertainty at the industry level.Footnote 8 In addition, column 2 tariff originates from the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act in 1930, which is strongly exogenous (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016).

4.1.2. The measurement of trade policy uncertainty

We follow Pierce and Schott (Reference Pierce and Schott2016) to measure trade policy uncertainty for various industries in China. The measurement is divided into two steps. The first step is to calculate product-level trade policy uncertainty using the data provided by Feenstra et al. (Reference Feenstra, Romalis and Schott2002).

(36) \begin{equation} TPU_k=Tariff_{k}^{Col2}-Tariff_{k}^{MFN} \end{equation}

where subscript $k$ denotes product. $TPU_k$ is trade policy uncertainty of $k$ product before the USA granted PNTR to China in 2002. $Tariff_{k}^{Col2}$ and $Tariff_{k}^{MFN}$ are the tariff rates of column 2 tariff and MFN tariff imposed by the USA.

The second step is to aggregate product-level trade policy uncertainty at the industry level. Then, we can obtain trade policy uncertainty for each industry in China.

(37) \begin{equation} TPU_s=\frac{{\textstyle \sum _{k\in I_s}^{}n_k TPU_k}}{{\textstyle \sum _{k\in I_s}^{n_k}}} \end{equation}

where subscript $s$ denotes industry. $TPU_s$ is trade policy uncertainty of $s$ industry before the USA granted PNTR to China. $n_k$ is the number of tariff items of $k$ product. $I_s$ is the product set of $s$ industry. The value of $TPU_s$ is greater, meaning that the degree of industry-level trade policy uncertainty before 2002 is higher. After the USA granted PNTR to China in 2002, this industry experienced a greater decrease in trade policy uncertainty.

4.2. Empirical model

Our theoretical section focuses on exporting firms. Compared with firms selling in the domestic market, trade policy uncertainty is more likely to affect exporting firms’ pollution emissions. In addition, the PNTR granted to China refers to the trade policy of USA. Many Chinese exporters regard the USA as a major export destination. This event shock has a greater impact on firms exporting to the USA. Thus, we construct a DDD model to empirically investigate the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on firms’ pollution emissions.

(38) \begin{align}\ln Y_{ispt}&=\beta _{1}TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times USEX_{ispt}+\beta _{2}TPU_{s}\times USEX_{ispt}+\beta _{3}Post_{t}\times USEX_{ispt}\nonumber\\ &\quad+\beta _{4}USEX_{ispt} +X^{\prime}\theta +\mu _{st}+\delta _{pt}+\varepsilon _{ispt} \end{align}

where subscripts $i$ , $s$ , $p$ , and $t$ denote individual firm, industry, province, and time, respectively. $Y_{ispt}$ includes firms’ emission intensity, output value, and emission levels. We employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. $TPU_{s}$ represents the degree of trade policy uncertainty of $s$ industry before the USA granted PNTR to China in 2002. $Post_{t}$ is a time-level dummy before and after 2002. If a firm is in the period of 2002 or after 2002, $Post_{t}=1$ ; otherwise, $Post_{t}=0$ . $USEX_{ispt}$ is a dummy of exporting to the USA. If a firm exports to the USA, $USEX_{ispt}=1$ ; otherwise, $USEX_{ispt}=0$ . The triple interaction term $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times USEX_{ispt}$ is the core variable. We focus on $\beta _{1}$ , which measures the impacts of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on firms’ emission intensity, output value, and emission levels on average. $X^{\prime}$ is control variables at the firm level, including capital intensity ( $\ln KL_{ispt}$ ), financing constraint ( $\ln Constraint_{ispt}$ ) and ownership types ( $SOE_{ispt}$ and $Foreign_{ispt}$ ).Footnote 9 $\mu _{st}$ is industry-year fixed effect, which captures industry-level characteristics, policies, and shocks. For example, tariff changes are reflected at the industry-time level, which affects firms’ environmental performance (Cherniwchan, Reference Cherniwchan2017; Gutiérrez and Teshima, Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018). $\delta _{pt}$ is province-year fixed effect, which captures region-level characteristics, policies, and shocks. For example, environmental regulation is usually reflected at region-time level in China (Shi and Xu, Reference Shi and Xu2018).Footnote 10 $\varepsilon _{ispt}$ is a stochastic error term.

Next, we discuss the endogeneity of core variable ( $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times USEX_{ispt}$ ) in Eq. (38). $TPU_{s}$ is the degree of trade policy uncertainty which is measured by column 2 tariff and MFN tariff imposed by the USA. Column 2 tariff comes from the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act in 1930, which is strongly exogenous (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016; Feng et al. Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017; Liu and Ma, Reference Liu and Ma2020). $Post_{t}$ is an exogenous dummy to distinguish periods. However, $USEX_{ispt}$ is an endogenous dummy of whether firms export to the USA. First, there are omitted factors that may affect exporting and environmental performance (Lin and He, Reference Lin and He2023a). Second, there may be a reverse causal relationship between export behavior and environmental performance. Namely, firms with better environmental performance may self-select to export to the USA (Lin and He, Reference Lin and He2023a). Third, the change in trade policy uncertainty significantly affects firms’ export behavior (Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2017; Feng et al. Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017). As a consequence, the coefficient on core variable may confound the impact of trade policy uncertainty on export behavior.

To address the endogeneity of exporting to the USA, we construct instrumental variables (IV). IV needs to meet the conditions of exogeneity and correlation. We refer to Frankel and Rose (Reference Frankel and Rose2005) and Lin (Reference Lin2017) and employ the distance between the located city of firms and the nearest portFootnote 11 as IV of exporting to the USA. On the one hand, the distance between located city and port is relatively exogenous, which is difficult to directly affect firms’ pollution emissions. On the other hand, this IV is closely correlated with firms’ export behavior. The majority of exports from China to the USA rely on ocean shipping. If firms are closer to the port, these firms have more possibilities to sell products to the USA.

In addition, the distance from the port is a region-level variable. It can only capture region-level variation in firms’ export behavior. The variation in export behavior also reflects at the time level. Referring to Bastos et al., (Reference Bastos, Silva and Verhoogen2018), the exchange rate of US dollar to China YuanFootnote 12 can be regarded as another IV. On the one hand, exchange rate is an exogenous variable. This variable mainly affects firms’ pollution emissions through trade behavior. On the other hand, exchange rate is closely correlated with export behavior. If the exchange rate of US dollar to China Yuan increases, it would be more conducive for Chinese firms to export to the USA. Thus, we employ the interaction term of the distance from the port and exchange rate as IV.

4.3. Data

This study involves three firm-level databases of China. First, our data on firms’ environmental performance are from the Chinese Environmental Statistics Firm Database (CESFD) provided by the Ministry of Ecology and Environment of China from 1998 to 2012. This database contains firm-level information on pollution emissions, energy consumption as well as abatement equipment and capacity. Since 1980, the Ministry of Ecology and Environment of China has established a system of environmental statistics to annually collect data on pollution emissions. This database covers the major industrial emitters monitored by the Ministry of Ecology and Environment. Their emission levels account for 85% of region-level emissions. Statistical items include major pollutants, such as SO $_2$ and chemical oxygen demand (COD). Monitored firms are required to report basic facts, output value, and a large amount of environmental information. In general, this database is a comprehensive, reliable, and authoritative firm-level environmental database in China (Liu et al. Reference Liu, Shadbegian and Zhang2017; Zhang et al. Reference Zhang, Chen and Guo2018; He et al. Reference He, Wang and Zhang2020a).

Second, CESFD covers abundant environmental information, but it does not provide information on exporting and finance. To obtain more firm-level information, we employ the CIFD provided by the National Bureau of Statistics of China from 1998 to 2012. This database covers all state-owned firms and non-state-owned firms with large scale in China. This database provides basic facts about firms as well as information on production, exporting, and finance. According to our design and the method of data processing from Feenstra et al. (Reference Feenstra, Li and Yu2014) and Yu (Reference Yu2015), we process the abnormal and missing data of this database. In particular, manufacturing firms are more likely to be influenced by trade policy uncertainty. We only retain firms from manufacturing industries. We remove any firms whose output value and the value of fixed asset are less than or equal to 0, any firms whose interest expenditure is less than 0, and any firms whose employees are less than 10. In addition, we deflate output value, export value, and interest expenditure by the industrial producer price index of 1998, and deflate the value of fixed asset by the fixed asset investment price index of 1998. Then, we use firm code, name, and former name to match this database with CESFD.

Third, we collect data to identify whether firms export to the USA. This information is from the Chinese Custom Database (CCD) provided by the General Administration of Customs of China from 2000 to 2012. This database records monthly transaction information on exports (including export destination). We sum up this data at the firm-year level. Following Dai et al. (Reference Dai, Maitra and Yu2016), we match this database with the above dataset through firm name as well as the zip code plus the last seven digits of telephone number.

In addition, the data on column 2 tariff and MFN tariff imposed by the USA on China are from Feenstra et al. (Reference Feenstra, Romalis and Schott2002). The literature uses this data to measure trade policy uncertainty faced by Chinese firms (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016, Reference Pierce and Schott2018; Feng et al. Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017; Liu and Ma, Reference Liu and Ma2020). We match this industry-level trade policy uncertainty with firm-level databases.

After matching, we obtain a dataset of 644,122 observations, including 577,539 observations of manufacturing firms. This dataset contains information on trade policy uncertainty as well as firm-level environmental performance, export behavior, and other characteristics. There are 428,615 observations emitting SO $_2$ , 427,227 observations emitting COD, 151,707 observations of exporters and 41,005 observations exporting to the USA, as shown in Table 1.

As suggested by He et al. (Reference He, Wang and Zhang2020a), matching CESFD with other firm-level database may be problematic. We compare the merged dataset with initial CESFD in Table 2. First, there are 1,350,015 observations in initial CESFD and 644,122 observations in merged dataset. Approximately, 47.71% of observations are successfully matched. This matching rate is similar to Lin and He (Reference Lin and He2023a), which matches CESFD with CIFD and CCD from 1998 to 2012. Specifically, from 1998 to 2012, these matching rates are 42.68%-55.62%. The changes in observations of merged dataset and CESFD show similar trends. Second, in initial CESFD, average SO $_2$ and COD emission levels are 282990.7 and 86,017.7 kilograms. In merged dataset, they are 199611.5 and 80,841.6 kilograms. From 1998 to 2012, the change trends in average emission levels of merged dataset and CESFD are almost the same. Thus, after matching, firm-level environmental performance does not significantly change relative to initial CESFD. Our matched dataset is quite representative, which is suitable for empirical analysis.

Table 1. The observations of merged dataset

Table 2. The comparison between merged dataset and CESFD

Notes: Given that initial CESFD does not provide the industry type for each firm, this table shows the information on all industrial firms (including manufacturing firms and other industrial firms).

Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics on main variables. Our dataset includes firms with more and less emissions, exporters and non-exporters, and firms with different characteristics. Besides, different firms face differentiated degrees of decreases in trade policy uncertainty.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics on main variables

5. Empirical results

5.1. Baseline results: 2SLS estimation

We employ Eq. (38) to examine the impact of trade policy uncertainty on firm-level pollution emissions, which refers to the Propositions 1 and 2 in the theoretical section. Specifically, we employ the interaction term of the distance from the port and exchange rate as IV. We use two-stage least square (2SLS) method for analysis. The panel A of Table 4 reports these results. The column (1) shows the result for the first stage of 2SLS estimation. The coefficient on IV ( $\ln Distance_{ispt}\times Exchange_{t}$ ) is negative and significant at the 1% level. This result indicates that both the distance from the port and exchange rate of US dollar to China Yuan are negatively correlated with export behavior. If firms are closer to the port and US dollar can exchange more Chinese yuan, firms are more likely to export products to the USA. It proves that there is a significant correlation between IV and exporting to the USA. In addition, the F value is approximately 527.59, illustrating that this IV is not a weak IV.

Table 4. 2SLS estimation: the impact of trade policy uncertainty on pollution emissions

Notes: In panels A and B, we employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV. In particular, in panel B, we remove any firms with changing located cities. The column (1) shows the first stage of 2SLS estimation, and the dependent variable is whether the firm exports to the USA. Columns (2)-(7) show the second stage, and dependent variables are emission intensity, output value, and emission levels. We employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

Columns (2)-(7) show the results for the second stage. Dependent variables include emission intensity, output value, and emission levels. In columns (2) and (3), we examine the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on firms’ emission intensity. The coefficients on the triple interaction term ( $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times \widehat{USEX_{ispt}}$ ) are negative and significant at the 1% level. These results indicate that for firms which export to the USA, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to lower emission intensity. These results support the Proposition 1. The explanation is that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces expected trade cost. As a consequence, firms invest more in technical upgrading and thereby reduce emission intensity.

In columns (4) and (5), we analyze the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on firms’ output scale. The coefficients on $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times \widehat{USEX_{ispt}}$ are positive and significant at the 1% level. These results suggest that for firms which export to the USA, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to greater output value. Theoretical section explains that on the one hand, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty promotes technology investment and improves production capacity. On the other hand, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty directly expands export scale and then expands output.

According to Eq. (1), emission levels are decomposed into emission intensity and output value. Firms with lower emission intensity have lower emission levels, but firms with greater outputs have more emissions. Combining the results in columns (2)-(5), we cannot conclude that trade policy uncertainty aggravates or reduces emissions. In columns (6) and (7), we investigate the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on firms’ emission levels. The coefficients on $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times \widehat{USEX_{ispt}}$ are not statistically significant. These results suggest that for firms which export to the USA, the impact of trade policy uncertainty on emission levels is not significant. These results confirm the Proposition 2. Namely, the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on emission levels is uncertain, which depends on the changes in emission intensity and output value. The decrease in trade policy uncertainty not only reduces emission intensity but also expands output scale. These two effects offset each other. As a result, the net effect on emission levels is not significant. Combining all columns, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty does not significantly aggravate firms’ emission levels, while firms expand output scale. Besides, these firms reduce emission intensity. Therefore, we conclude that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty helps exporting firms to improve environmental performance.

In addition, the distance from the port is not purely exogenous. The reason is that firms can change located cities and thereby change the distance from the port. Namely, firms which export to the USA may self-select to move to cities which are closer to the port. This may lead to the bias of IV estimation. Thus, we remove the firms which change their located cities. This ensures that our samples are located in the same cities and mitigates the interference of self-selection. The panel B of Table 4 reports these results. The column (1) shows the first stage of 2SLS estimation. We still find that the interaction term is negatively correlated with exporting to the USA. The columns (2)-(7) show the second stage. The results indicate that for firms which export to the USA, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty not only reduces emission intensity but also expands output scale. Trade policy uncertainty has no significant impact on emission levels. After removing firms with changing locations, our conclusion does not change. By a comparison, the specification of panel B can better address the endogeneity of export behavior. In subsequent analyses, we remove any firms with changing located cities.

5.2. Controlling for environmental regulation

5.2.1. Domestic environmental regulation

The above result shows that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces firms’ emission intensity. However, domestic environmental regulation affects both pollution and export behavior (Shi and Xu, Reference Shi and Xu2018). During the period of this study, there are significant changes in environmental regulation in China. Thus, we need to prove that the reduction in firms’ emission intensity is indeed due to decreasing trade policy uncertainty instead of domestic environmental regulation.

According to Shi and Xu (Reference Shi and Xu2018), environmental regulation is mainly reflected at province-time level in China. In Eq. (38), we employ province-year fixed effect to capture the potential effect of environmental regulation. However, our IV (distance from port) is a region-level variable related to the stringency of environmental regulation. Coastal cities usually have stricter environmental regulation. The IV may affect pollution emissions by the channel of domestic environmental regulation. To address this issue, we control for environmental regulation at other levels. Shi and Xu (Reference Shi and Xu2018) suggest that in China, different provinces have differentiated environmental regulations for different industries. Liu et al. (Reference Liu, Tan and Zhang2021) suggest that China’s environmental regulation is reflected at the city level, such as China’s Key Cities for Air Pollution Control. Namely, we should control for the influencing factors at industry-province and city levels.

Columns (1)-(3) of Table 5 report these results. The column (1) controls for industry-province-year fixed effect. The column (2) further controls for city fixed effect. In the column (3), we are stricter in controlling industry-city fixed effect. After controlling for various levels of environmental regulations, we can better identify the environmental effect of trade policy uncertainty. From columns (1)-(3), all results indicate that for firms which export to the USA, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. Even if we strictly control for domestic environmental regulation, our conclusion is still robust.

Table 5. Controlling for environmental regulation

Notes: We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of exporting to the USA and remove any firms with changing located cities. This table only shows the result for the second stage of 2SLS estimation. Dependent variables are SO $_2$ emission intensity. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

5.2.2. Foreign environmental regulation

In addition to domestic environmental regulations, environmental regulations of importing countries are likely to affect exporting firms’ pollution emissions (Antweiler et al. Reference Antweiler, Copeland and Taylor2001). There are time-varying environmental regulations in the USA and other importing countries. Thus, we need to control for foreign environmental regulations.

According to Copeland and Taylor (Reference Copeland and Taylor1994), high-income countries usually have stricter environmental regulations, while low-income countries have looser regulations. We control for export destinations to capture the impacts of foreign environmental regulations. Specifically, we divide export destinations into high-income and low-income countries. Referring to Lin and He (Reference Lin and He2023b), we distinguish between two types of countries according to whether the country is an OECD country. Given that foreign environmental regulations change over time, we control for interaction terms between the dummies of export destinations ( $HighIncome_{ispt}$ and $LowIncome_{ispt}$ ) and the dummies of different years. If a firm exports to OECD countries, $HighIncome_{ispt}=1$ ; otherwise, $HighIncome_{ispt}=0$ . If a firm exports to non-OECD countries, $LowIncome_{ispt}=1$ ; otherwise, $LowIncome_{ispt}=0$ . In addition, our study focuses on the event that the USA granted PNTR to China. We regard the USA as a special export destination. We further control for environmental regulations of the USA by the interaction term between $USEX_{ispt}$ and the dummies of different years.

The column (4) of Table 5 reports these results. We find that for firms exporting to the USA, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to lower emission intensity. Furthermore, we simultaneously control for both domestic and foreign environmental regulations, which is reported in the column (5) of Table 5. The result still shows that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty helps to pollution reduction. After controlling for domestic and foreign environmental regulation, the results are supportive of our baseline conclusion.

5.3. More discussions for export behavior

5.3.1. Exporting to all countries

This study employs the PNTR granted to China by the USA in 2002 as an event shock. This event involves the trade policy of USA, so we mainly focus on firms which export to the USA. According to Feng et al. (Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017), this event shock not only affects firms exporting to the USA but also affects firms exporting to other countries. As a result, we turn to examine the environmental effect of trade policy uncertainty on all exporting firms.

Table 6. More discussion for export behavior

Notes: Panels A and B focus on all exporters and firms’ export intensity, respectively. We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV and remove any firms with changing located cities. The column (1) shows the first stage of 2SLS estimation, and dependent variables are whether the firm exports to foreign countries (in panel A) and export intensity (in panel B). Columns (2)-(4) show the second stage, and dependent variables are emission intensity, output value, and emission levels. We employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

We employ a dummy of exporting to foreign countries ( $EX_{ispt}$ ) to replace $USEX_{ispt}$ . If a firm exports to foreign countries, $EX_{ispt}=1$ ; otherwise, $EX_{ispt}=0$ . We show the result in the panel A of Table 6. We employ the interaction term of the distance from the port and exchange rate as IV of exporting. The column (1) shows that if firms are closer to the port and US dollar exchanges more Chinese yuan, they are more inclined to export products. Other columns show that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity and expands output scale of exporting firms. The impact on emission levels is statistically insignificant. Compared with the panel B of Table 1, trade policy uncertainty has a minor effect on emission intensity of all exporters relative to firms exporting to the USA.

5.3.2. Export intensity

There is a phenomenon that different exporters have different export intensities. Some exporters focus on domestic market, and other exporters depend on foreign markets. According to Richter and Schiersch (Reference Richter and Schiersch2017) and Lin and He (Reference Lin and He2023a), firms with different export intensities have differentiated emissions. Since trade policy uncertainty mainly affects exporters, we infer that trade policy uncertainty may have a greater impact on firms with higher export intensity.

We employ export intensity ( $EXI_{ispt}$ ) to replace $USEX_{ispt}$ . $EXI_{ispt}$ is calculated by the ratio of export to sale value. The panel B of Table 6 reports these results. We employ the interaction term of the distance from the port and exchange rate as IV of export intensity. The column (1) shows that if located cities are closer to the port and US dollar exchanges more Chinese yuan, firms have higher export intensity. Columns (2)-(4) show that for firms with higher export intensity, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity and expands output. The net effect on emission levels is insignificant. These results confirm our inference that trade policy uncertainty has greater environmental effect on firms with higher export intensity.

5.4. The tests for DDD model

5.4.1. Anticipation effect and dynamic effect

A prerequisite for DDD model is that samples from different groups must have the common pre-trend in dependent variables. In this study, the common pre-trend means that firms from different groups had no ex-ante difference in environmental performance before the USA granted PNTR to China in 2002. Above results indicate that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty significantly reduces emission intensity and expands output scale. Thus, we need to examine the anticipation effects of trade policy uncertainty on emission intensity and output scale. We replace $Post_{t}$ of Eq. (38) by the dummies of different years. In this estimation, we focus on firms which export to the USA and all countries. This method also examines the dynamic effect of trade policy uncertainty. Figure 2 shows these results. In panels (a) and (b), we focus on firms which export to the USA and regard 2000 as the baseline period. In panels (b) and (d), we focus on all exporters and regard 1998-1999 as baseline periods.

Figure 2. Anticipation effect and dynamic effect. Note: We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of export behaviors and remove any firms with changing located cities. Panels (a) and (b) focus on firms exporting to the USA and regard 2000 as the baseline period. Panels (c) and (d) focus on all exporters and regard 1998 and 1999 as baseline periods. In panels (a) and (c), dependent variables are emission intensity, and in panels (b) and (d), dependent variables are output value. We employ SO2 as the pollutant. The level of confidence interval is 90%.

First, we employ emission intensity as dependent variables. Panels (a) and (c) show that before 2002, the coefficients are statistically insignificant. After 2002, the coefficients are all negative and essentially significant. These results suggest that compared with the baseline periods, firms’ emission intensity has no significant change before 2002. This proves that before the USA granted PNTR to China, firms from different groups had a common pre-trend in emission intensity. Namely, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity, rather than the ex-ante difference in emission intensity between firms from different groups. In addition, dynamic effects suggest that in the first year of event shock, firms’ emission intensity immediately decreases. In following years (2003-2012), the decrease in trade policy uncertainty always reduces emission intensity, and this effect has an increasing trend.

Second, we employ output value as dependent variables. Panels (b) and (d) show that before 2002, the coefficients are not significant. After 2002, the coefficients are significantly positive. These results suggest that before the USA granted PNTR to China, firms’ output value had a common pre-trend. Namely, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty expands output scale rather than the ex-ante difference in output value. In addition, dynamic effects indicate that after 2002, firms immediately expand output scale. From 2002 to 2012, these effects firstly increase and then decrease. After 2008, these effects begin to decrease continuously. The possible reason is that firms’ exports are influenced by the global economic crisis in 2008, and these firms thereby reduce production scale.

5.4.2. Placebo

To ensure that the change of firms’ environmental performance is caused by the decrease in trade policy uncertainty of the USA granting PNTR to China in 2002, we design a placebo test. Specifically, we employ the samples before this event to construct false event shocks. We assume that the USA granted PNTR to China in 2001 or 2000. We employ these false events and the samples before 2002 to estimate the results. Table 7 reports the results of placebo tests, which focus on exporting to the USA and all countries. In columns (1)-(6), we assume the event of the USA granting PNTR to China occurred in 2001, and in columns (7)-(9), we assume this event occurred in 2000. From all columns, estimated coefficients are not significant. These results suggest that false events cannot change firms’ environmental performance. Namely, before the event of the USA granting PNTR to China, trade policy uncertainty does not affect environmental performance. Our baseline results are definitely driven by the decrease in trade policy uncertainty in 2002.

Table 7. Placebo: changing the time of the event

Notes: In this table, we employ the samples before 2002 for analysis. We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of export behaviors and remove any firms with changing located cities. This table only shows the results for the second stage of 2SLS estimation. In columns (1)-(6), we assume the event that the USA granted PNTR to China occurred in 2001 and focus on exporting to the USA and all countries. In columns (7)-(9), we assume this event occurred in 2002 and focus on all exporters. We employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

5.5. Other robustness checks

To ensure the robustness of this conclusion, we do following robustness checks. Table 8 reports the results of robustness checks. First, in baseline estimation, we employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. The literature considers that for different pollutants, the impacts of trade policy on firm-level pollution emissions are different (Cherniwchan, Reference Cherniwchan2017). To ensure that the impact of trade policy uncertainty on pollution emissions does not vary with pollutants, we employ other pollutant for robustness check. Since SO $_2$ is an air pollutant, we employ COD which is the pollutant in wastewater. COD is one of the key pollutants monitored in China. CESFD provides information on firm-level COD emissions. This result is reported in the column (1). We find that employing COD as the pollutant, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to lower emission intensity. When we employ other pollutant for analysis, our conclusion is still robust.

Table 8. Other robustness checks

Notes: Dependent variables are emission intensity. Except for the column (1), we employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of exporting to the USA and remove any firms with changing located cities. This table only shows the second stage of 2SLS estimation. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

Second, this study employs the ratio of emission levels to output value to calculate firms’ emission intensity. The literature also employs emissions-to-sales and emissions-to-employees ratios to reflect emission intensity (Cherniwchan, Reference Cherniwchan2017). According to Brucal et al. (Reference Brucal, Javorcik and Love2019) and Lin and He (Reference Lin and He2023a), employing output value to calculate emission intensity may lead to markup-driven bias. This is because output value is significantly influenced by markups. In China, manufacturing markups increase rapidly and differentially across firms (Lu and Yu, Reference Lu and Yu2015; Brandt et al. Reference Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, Wang and Zhang2017). The number of employees can reflect the scale of firms and is not influenced by markups. Employing emissions-to-employees ratio can effectively address markup-driven bias. Thus, we employ emissions-to-sales and emissions-to-employees ratios to calculate emission intensity for robustness checks. The columns (2) and (3) report these results, which still show that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. Our conclusion holds very well in the situation of employing other methods to calculate emission intensity.

Third, this study measures trade policy uncertainty according to Pierce and Schott (Reference Pierce and Schott2016). Handley and Limão (Reference Handley and Limão2017) provide another method for measurement. To ensure that our conclusion does not vary with the measurement of trade policy uncertainty, we measure this indicator by the method of Handley and Limão (Reference Handley and Limão2017). This measurement is carried out in two steps. The first one is to calculate product-level trade policy uncertainty by $TPU_k=1-\left (\frac{Tariff_{k}^{Col2}}{Tariff_{k}^{MFN}}\right ) ^{-\sigma }$ . Similar to Handley and Limão (Reference Handley and Limão2017), we set $\sigma =3$ . The second is to aggregate trade policy uncertainty at the industry level. The column (4) reports this result. The result supports that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. Even if we employ other method to measure trade policy uncertainty, our conclusion holds very well.

Fourth, in this study, we employ the data of Chinese firms from 1998 to 2012. To ensure that the impact of trade policy uncertainty on environmental performance does not change in different periods, we employ the samples from different periods for robustness check. From 1998 to 2012, there is an event which brings an uncertainty to international trade and profoundly affects firms’ export behavior. Namely, the global economic crisis occurred in 2008. We remove any samples after 2008. The column (5) reports this result. The result indicates that for 1998-2007, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. When we employ the samples from different periods for analysis, the result is supportive of our conclusion.

Fifth, in China, many firms entered and exited the industry during the period of our study. The PNTR granted to China by the USA occurred in 2002. Some firms did not enter before 2002, and some firms exited after 2002. According to Cherniwchan (Reference Cherniwchan2017), firms’ entry and exit may affect the environmental effects of trade policy. Namely, new entrants may be cleaner, and firms exiting the industry may be dirtier. Thus, we employ the samples that are present before and after 2002 for robustness check, which is reported in the column (5). The result indicates that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to lower emission intensity. Even if we exclude the interference of firms’ entry and exit, our conclusion is still robust.

5.6. Mechanism

Above results show that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to lower emission intensity. The Proposition 3 suggests that improving energy efficiency is an important mechanism. Thus, we employ energy efficiency as a major mechanism to examine how the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. We also examine other potential mechanisms of abatement technology and energy structure.

5.6.1. Energy efficiency

Firms’ pollution emissions mainly come from energy consumption. The reduction in emission intensity may be due to improving energy efficiency (Gutiérrez and Teshima, Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018; Brucal et al. Reference Brucal, Javorcik and Love2019; Lin and He, Reference Lin and He2023a). In theoretical section, we prove that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty is conducive to reducing expected trade cost and enabling firms to invest more in production technology. Then, firms upgrade production technology and thereby improve energy efficiency. The Proposition 3 indicates that energy efficiency is an important mechanism between trade policy uncertainty and emission intensity. We examine the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on energy efficiency, which is reported in Table 9.

Table 9. Mechanism: energy efficiency

Notes: We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of exporting to the USA and remove any firms with changing located cities. This table shows the second stage of 2SLS estimation. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

CESFD provides information on coal, fuel oil, and clean gas consumption. We aggregate firms’ total energy consumption of three energies by standard coal coefficient.Footnote 13 Then, we measure energy efficiency by the ratio of output value to total energy consumption. We examine the impact of trade policy uncertainty on energy efficiency, which is reported in column (1). The coefficient on $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times \widehat{USEX_{ispt}}$ is significantly positive. This result indicates that for firms exporting to the USA, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to higher energy efficiency. This confirms the Proposition 3. Namely, improving energy efficiency is an important mechanism by which the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. The explanation is that decreasing uncertainty reduces expected trade cost of exporting firms. Thus, these firms can invest more to upgrade production technology and thereby improve energy efficiency.

Energy efficiency is measured by the ratio of output value to energy consumption. The improvement in energy efficiency may be due to upgrade production technology or reduce energy consumption. The latter means that firms may use other production factors to replace energy. To eliminate this interference, we examine the impact of trade policy uncertainty on energy consumption. The column (2) reports this result. We find that the estimated coefficient is insignificant. This suggests that trade policy uncertainty has no significant impact on energy consumption. In addition, our baseline results show that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty significantly expands output scale. These firms expand output scale without significant change in energy consumption. We conclude that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty improves energy efficiency through upgrading technology rather than reducing energy consumption.

Pollution emissions mainly come from the consumption of pollution-intensive coal. Relatively, fuel oil and clean gas are cleaner. As a result, coal efficiency may play a more important role in the relationship between trade policy uncertainty and emission intensity. We re-measure energy efficiency by the ratio of output value to coal consumption. We examine the impact of trade policy uncertainty on both coal efficiency and coal consumption. The columns (3) and (4) report these results. The results show that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty improves coal efficiency, but has no significant impact on coal consumption. These results are consistent with the results based on total energy consumption and also support the Proposition 3.

Moreover, our theoretical section suggests that after decreasing trade policy uncertainty, exporting firms improve energy efficiency through upgrading production technology and improving productivity. Actually, energy efficiency is a special kind of production technology and productivity. Thus, we examine the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on productivity. We employ three indicators to represent productivity. The first one is labor productivity which is calculated by output-to-employees ratio. The second is total factor productivity (TFP). We employ labor and capital as production factors and output value as outcome variable. We use ordinary least square (OLS) method and control for industry-year and province-year fixed effects to estimate TFP. For the third indicator, since our production function in theoretical model includes energy, we put energy as a kind of production factor into TFP estimation. Namely, we employ labor, capital, and energy as production factors for TFP estimation. Columns (5)-(7) report these results. We find that estimated coefficients are statistically positive. These results indicate that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty can upgrade production technology and improve productivity (including labor productivity and TFP). These effects further drive the improvement in energy efficiency, and reduce emission intensity.

5.6.2. Abatement technology

Terminal abatement helps to reduce firms’ pollution emissions. The reduction in emission intensity may be due to applying more abatement equipments and improving abatement technology (Forslid et al. Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018; Liu et al. Reference Liu, Tan and Zhang2021). Given that abatement investment requires higher fixed costs, firms with higher productivity and larger scale are more likely to invest in abatement equipment (Forslid et al. Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018). Above analyses have confirmed that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty improves production technology and expands output scale. These effects may indirectly enable firms to invest in abatement equipment and improve abatement technology. Thus, abatement technology is a potential mechanism by which trade policy uncertainty affects emission intensity. We examine the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on abatement technology, which is reported in Table 10.

Table 10. Mechanism: abatement technology

Notes: We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of exporting to the USA and remove any firms with changing located cities. This table shows the second stage of 2SLS estimation. In columns (5)-(7), we employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

CESFD provides abundant information on abatement equipment at the firm level, including the numbers of abatement equipment for waste gas and desulfurization equipment. Abatement equipment can reflect technical level related to terminal pollution reduction. We examine the impact of trade policy uncertainty on the number of abatement equipment. Columns (1) and (2) report these results. The coefficients on $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times \widehat{USEX_{ispt}}$ are statistically insignificant. These results show that trade policy uncertainty cannot significantly change the numbers of abatement equipment. These suggest that abatement investment is not a mechanism by which the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity.

CESFD also provides the information on the capacity of abatement equipment (including abatement equipment for waste gas and desulfurization equipment). This capacity refers to the amount of pollution handled by abatement equipment per hour, which can reflect firm-level abatement technology. We examine the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on the capacity of abatement equipment. Columns (3) and (4) report these results. We find that estimated coefficients are not significant. These results suggest that trade policy uncertainty has no significant impact on the capacities of abatement equipment and desulfurization equipment, which is similar to the results of the number of abatement equipment.

Abatement technology involves firms’ capacity to remove pollution (Gutiérrez and Teshima, Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018; Liu et al. Reference Liu, Tan and Zhang2021). Firms can install more abatement equipments to gain higher removal rate of emissions. In other words, we can employ the removal rate of emissions to reflect abatement technology. CESFD provides the data on the removal levels of pollution. We calculate the levels of pollution generation by the sum of emission levels and removal levels. Then, we calculate the removal rate of emissions by the ratio of removal levels to generation levels. We examine the impact of trade policy uncertainty on the removal rate of emissions. The column (5) shows that the estimated coefficient is not significant. This result implies that trade policy uncertainty does not lead to significant change in the removal rate of emissions.

In the Section 2, we use the emission levels per unit of energy consumption to reflect abatement technology when we decompose emission intensity. This is because firms’ pollution emissions mainly come from energy consumption. Firms with advanced abatement technology have stronger capacity to remove emissions and thereby reduce emission levels per unit of energy consumption (Gutiérrez and Teshima, Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018; Lin and He, Reference Lin and He2023a). We examine the impact of trade policy uncertainty on emissions-to-energy ratio. In addition, given that pollution emissions are mainly from pollution-intensive coal consumption, we employ the ratio of emission levels to coal consumption for analysis. Columns (6)-(7) report these results. We find that estimated coefficients are insignificant. These results indicate that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty cannot affect the emission levels per unit of energy consumption (or coal consumption).

Altogether, Table 10 indicates that trade policy uncertainty has no significant impact on firms’ abatement equipment and abatement technology. Thus, abatement technology is not the mechanism by which the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. This conclusion is similar to Gutiérrez and Teshima (Reference Gutiérrez and Teshima2018). Namely, firms in developing countries reduce emissions by improving energy efficiency rather than improving abatement technology. In addition, this conclusion is different from the literature that shows abatement technology is the mechanism by which trade affects firms’ pollution emissions (Forslid et al. Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018; Rodrigue et al. Reference Rodrigue, Sheng and Tan2022a; Kwon et al. Reference Kwon, Zhao and Zhao2023). However, these works focus on firms’ export and import behaviors as well as trade liberalization, and we analyze the mechanism for trade policy uncertainty.

5.6.3. Energy structure

Optimizing energy structure contributes to pollution reduction. The reduction in emission intensity may be due to that firms reduce pollution-intensive coal consumption, and they input more clean-intensive energies (fuel oil and clean gas). Considering that the cost of clean energy is relatively higher, firms with lower productivity and smaller scale prefer to consume coal with lower cost. Above results show that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty improves production technology and expands output scale, which may indirectly promote firms to input more clean energies and optimize energy structure. That is to say, energy structure is a potential mechanism by which trade policy uncertainty affects emission intensity.

Energy structure represents the proportions of pollution-intensive and clean-intensive energies. We separately employ the ratios of coal, fuel oil and clean gas consumptions to total energy consumption to calculate energy structure. Firms consuming more coals have higher emission intensity, while firms relying on fuel oil and clean gas are cleaner. We examine the impact of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on energy structure. Table 11 reports these results. From the column (1), the coefficient on $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times \widehat{USEX_{ispt}}$ is significantly positive. This result suggests that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to higher coal-to-energy ratio. From the column (2), the estimated coefficient is not significant. This indicates that trade policy uncertainty has no significant impact on the ratio of fuel oil to total energy. The column (3) shows that the estimated coefficient is significantly negative. This implies that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty makes firms input less clean gas and reduce gas-to-energy ratio.

Table 11. Mechanism: energy structure

Notes: We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of exporting to the USA and remove any firms with changing located cities. This table shows the second stage of 2SLS estimation. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

Altogether, Table 11 suggests that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty increases the proportion of pollution-intensive coal consumption, and reduces the proportion of clean-intensive energy consumption. Namely, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty cannot optimize energy structure to the cleaner production. Firms’ energy structure becomes dirtier. The possible reason is that after the USA granted PNTR to China in 2002, Chinese firms make use of low-cost advantage to enter the export market and expand export scale (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016; Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2017; Feng et al. Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017). To further reduce costs, these firms may input lower-cost but dirtier coal. Therefore, energy structure is not the mechanism by which the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity.

5.7. Heterogeneous tests

5.7.1. Different industries

We employ pollution intensity and factor intensity to distinguish different industries. Based on these classifications, we examine the heterogeneous impacts of trade policy uncertainty on pollution emissions in terms of different industry types. Table 12 reports these results.

Table 12. Heterogeneous tests: different industries

Notes: We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of exporting to the USA and remove any firms with changing located cities. This table shows the second stage of 2SLS estimation. Dependent variables include emission intensity and emission levels. We employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

First, Shapiro (Reference Shapiro2021) indicates that trade policy has an environmental bias. Tariffs for pollution-intensive industries are fewer relative to clean-intensive industries. Industrial emissions mainly come from pollution-intensive industries. These industries are major industries of environmental supervision and control, and they have greater potential for pollution reduction. Thus, we infer that for pollution-intensive industries, trade policy uncertainty has a greater impact on pollution emissions. We calculate average emission intensity from 1998 to 2012 at the industry levelFootnote 14 to distinguish between pollution-intensive and clean-intensive industries and examine the heterogeneous impacts of trade policy uncertainty.

From columns (1) and (3), the coefficients on $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times \widehat{USEX_{ispt}}$ are significantly negative. For pollution-intensive and clean-intensive industries, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces emission intensity. The absolute value of the coefficient in column (1) is relatively greater. These confirm our inference. The decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to a greater pollution reduction for pollution-intensive industries. The possible reason is that these industries have more emissions and are strictly regulated, which has greater potential for pollution reduction. From columns (2) and (4), estimated coefficients are not significant.

Second, for a long time, China has an advantage of exports in labor-intensive industries (He et al. Reference He, Lin and Zhang2020c). These industries represent backward technology, and they are difficult to gain technical upgrading. On the contrary, capital-intensive industries have advanced technology and play an important role in technical upgrading. Capital-intensive industries are more likely to benefit from decreasing trade policy uncertainty. In addition, capital-intensive industries are usually pollution-intensive industries with greater potential to reduce emissions. Thus, we infer that for capital-intensive industries, trade policy uncertainty has greater impact on pollution emissions. We refer to Lin and He (Reference Lin and He2023a) and calculate industry-level capital intensity.Footnote 15 Then, we distinguish between capital-intensive and labor-intensive industries to examine the heterogeneous impacts of trade policy uncertainty.

From columns (5) and (7), estimated coefficients are significantly negative. For capital-intensive and labor-intensive industries, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty leads to lower emission intensity. The absolute value of the coefficient in the column (5) is relatively greater. These results confirm our inference. The decrease in trade policy uncertainty causes a greater effect on pollution reduction of capital-intensive industries. The possible reasons are that on the one hand, capital-intensive industries represent advanced technology, which are more likely to gain technical upgrading. On the other hand, capital-intensive industries are pollution-intensive and have greater potential for pollution reduction. From columns (6) and (8), estimated coefficients are statistically insignificant.

5.7.2. Different regions

We employ geographical location to distinguish different regions. Geographic location is closely related to firms’ export behavior as well as trade policy uncertainty. Compared with inland provinces in China, coastal provinces are developed and have lower trade costs. Coastal firms are more likely to export products and be influenced by trade policy uncertainty. Thus, we infer that for coastal provinces, trade policy uncertainty has a greater impact on pollution emissions.

We distinguish between coastal and inland provinces to examine the heterogeneous impacts of trade policy uncertainty on pollution emissions. Table 13 reports these results. From the column (1), the coefficient on $TPU_{s}\times Post_{t}\times \widehat{USEX_{ispt}}$ is significantly negative. However, the coefficient is statistically insignificant in column (3). These results suggest that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty can only reduce emission intensity in coastal provinces, but has no significant impact on emission intensity in inland provinces. These results confirm our inference. Namely, pollution reduction caused by decreasing trade policy uncertainty mainly occurs in coastal provinces. The possible reason is that coastal provinces have lower trade costs, and firms located in these provinces are easily influenced by trade policy uncertainty. From columns (2) and (4), estimated coefficients are not significant.

Table 13. Heterogeneous tests: different regions

Notes: We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of exporting to the USA and remove any firms with changing located cities. This table shows the result for the second stage of 2SLS estimation. Dependent variables include emission intensity and emission levels. We employ SO $_2$ as the pollutant. The figures in parentheses are robust standard errors clustered at firm level. Significance: ***1%, **5%, *10%.

6. Conclusion

In this study, we theoretically and empirically investigate the impact of trade policy uncertainty on firm-level pollution emissions. Based on Melitz’s (2003) framework, we incorporate energy, pollution, and trade policy uncertainty to construct a theoretical model with heterogeneous firms. Regarding energy efficiency as a channel, we reveal the potential effect of trade policy uncertainty on emission intensity and emission levels. Then, we employ the data of Chinese manufacturing firms for empirical analysis. Specifically, we employ the event that the USA granted PNTR to China in 2002 as a quasi natural experiment and construct a DDD model to identify the causal effect of decrease in trade policy uncertainty on firms’ pollution emissions.

Our results indicate that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty can reduce emission intensity and expand output scale of exporting firms, but the net effect on emission levels is not significant. Given that these firms do not significantly aggravate emission levels under the condition of output expansion, we conclude that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty improves environmental performance. Energy efficiency is the important mechanism between trade policy uncertainty and emission intensity. The decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces firms’ emission intensity mainly by upgrading production technology and thereby improving energy efficiency rather than improving abatement technology and optimizing energy structure. In addition, the pollution reduction caused by decreasing trade policy uncertainty mainly occurs in pollution-intensive and capital-intensive industries as well as coastal regions.

Altogether, we enrich the literature on trade-environment relationship and trade policy uncertainty by theoretically and empirically studying the impact of trade policy uncertainty on firm-level pollution emissions. In the context of de-globalization and Sino-US trade friction, our conclusions provide important implications. First, although the Sino-US trade war has been suspended, trade policy uncertainty still exists. Given that the decrease in trade policy uncertainty can improve firms’ environmental performance, it is necessary to strengthen economic and trade ties among countries in the world. Namely, to achieve environmental protection and sustainable development, countries should promote free trade, reduce trade protection and thereby decrease the uncertainty of trade policy. Second, in view of that pollution reduction caused by decreasing trade policy uncertainty mainly occurs in exporting firms, it is important to promote the exports of firms. In particular, we should focus on firms’ exports in pollution-intensive and capital-intensive industries as well as coastal regions. Third, the decrease in trade policy uncertainty reduces pollution emissions mainly by improving energy efficiency rather than improving abatement technology and optimizing energy structure. In this process, it is critical to guide firms to improve energy efficiency. However, firms cannot neglect to improve abatement technology and optimize energy structure, which are also important ways to achieve pollution reduction.

Financial support

This project is supported by the National Major Project of the National SocialScience Foundation of China (Grant No. 20&ZD109).

Footnotes

1 Different from these works, we reveal the impact of trade policy uncertainty on firms’ pollution emissions. Trade policy uncertainty and trade liberalization are two different concepts. Trade liberalization is a certain phenomenon that trade policies (such as tariffs) gradually decrease. Trade policy uncertainty refers to that external trade policies (such as tariffs) are uncertain in the future. It further leads to the uncertainty of trade costs, revenue, and profit of exporting firms, which brings a series of adverse effects (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016).

2 Shapiro and Walker (2018), Forslid et al. (Reference Forslid, Okubo and Ulltveit-Moe2018) and Rodrigue et al. (Reference Rodrigue, Sheng and Tan2022a) also extend Melitz’s (2003) model to analyze the relationship between trade and environment, which provide important theoretical foundations for subsequent analyses. Our theoretical framework is different from these works. First, the literature mainly focuses on the environmental effects of exporting and trade liberalization. Our study introduces trade policy uncertainty referring to Handley and Limão (Reference Handley and Limão2017) to analyze the environmental effect of this uncertainty. Trade policy uncertainty is different from trade liberalization in theoretical models, although both of them affect trade costs. Trade liberalization is a certain event that directly affects trade costs. Trade policy uncertainty affects expected trade costs, which indirectly affects production, profit, and behaviors of firms. Second, the literature mainly employs productivity and abatement investment as the mechanisms by which trade affects firms’ pollution emissions. This study is the first to incorporate both energy consumption and energy efficiency. In particular, energy consumption produces pollution emissions. Thus, we can theoretically analyze a novel mechanism that trade policy uncertainty affects firms’ pollution emissions through energy efficiency.

3 Imbruno and Ketterer (2018) and He and Huang (Reference He and Huang2022) also theoretically analyze the role of production technology between trade and firms’ environmental performance. Imbruno and Ketterer (Reference Imbruno and Ketterer2018) analyze the role of energy efficiency. He and Huang (Reference He and Huang2022) use Melitz’s (2003) model as the basic framework. Our theoretical analysis is different from these works. First, these two works focus on the impact of importing intermediate products. Our study analyzes the impact of trade policy uncertainty. Second, our study provides a more detailed process for the mechanism that trade policy uncertainty affects expected trade costs and investment in production technology. Then, it upgrades production technology and thereby improves energy efficiency.

4 Without this assumption, firms would continue to invest in production technology to gain more profits. As a result, firms do not have the optimal investment for production technology.

5 According to Melitz (Reference Melitz2003) and Bustos (Reference Bustos2011), tariff only affects variable costs rather than all costs. This is because tariffs need to be paid only after starting to export and vary with changes in export value.

6 If $\bigtriangleup t$ is smaller, firms’ behaviors are unlikely to be affected by trade policy uncertainty regardless of higher or lower tariffs imposed by foreign country. It is because this higher tariff is not much higher than lower tariff, and they only have slightly different impacts on firms’ behaviors. If $\bigtriangleup t$ is larger, this uncertainty would force firms to adjust their behaviors. This is because firms have a probability to face a much higher tariff. Firms would worry about higher trade cost in the future, which may bring a series of adverse effects (Pierce and Schott, Reference Pierce and Schott2016).

7 It does not mean that firms which sell in domestic market are entirely unaffected by trade policy uncertainty. Actually, trade policy uncertainty also affects domestic sales firms, but the impact of this uncertainty on exporting firms is much greater (Feng et al. Reference Feng, Li and Swenson2017; Liu and Ma, Reference Liu and Ma2020). To simplify theoretical analysis, we focus on exporting firms.

8 In this study, we focus on the environmental effect of decreasing trade policy uncertainty caused by the USA granted PNTR to China. In the context of de-globalization and Sino-US trade friction, trade policy uncertainty significantly increases (He et al. Reference He, Lin and Zhang2020c; Benguria et al. Reference Benguria, Choi, Swenson and Xu2022). However, there are some similarities between these two events. First, both of them involve trade relationship between China and the USA which are the two largest economies in the world. Second, they are reflected in tariff uncertainty. Therefore, analyzing the impact of such uncertainty can provide implications for current de-globalization and Sino-US trade friction.

9 Capital intensity ( $KL_{ispt}$ ) is calculated by the ratio of the value of fixed asset to the number of employees. Financing constraint ( $Constraint_{ispt}$ ) is calculated by the ratio of interest expenditure to the value of fixed asset. If a firm is state-owned firm, $SOE_{ispt}=1$ ; otherwise, $SOE_{ispt}=0$ . If a firm is foreign-funded firm, $Foreign_{ispt}=1$ ; otherwise, $Foreign_{ispt}=0$ .

10 We do not control for firm fixed effect. The reason is that we employ the PNTR granted to China by the USA as an event shock, and employ DDD model to identify the impact of trade policy uncertainty. This shock occurred in 2002. In China, many firms did not enter the industry before 2002, and many firms exited after 2002. If we control for firm fixed effect, it is equivalent to estimating the result within the same firms. There is a problem that some firms enter (or exit) after 2002. These firms only have information after (or before) the shock, but have no information before (or after) the shock. In this case, the DDD estimation would be biased.

11 Data sources: Our calculation is according to the data of Gaud map.

12 Data sources: The China Statistical Yearbook.

13 Data source: The China Energy Statistical Yearbook.

14 Data source: Our calculations by the data from the China Statistical Yearbook.

15 Data source: Our calculations by the data from the China Statistical Yearbook.

References

Antweiler, W., Copeland, B. R. and Taylor, M. S. (2001) Is free trade good for the environment? American Economic Review 91(4), 877908.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, S. N., Roy, J. and Yasar, M. (2021) Exporting and pollution abatement expenditure: Evidence from firm-level data. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 105, 102403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrows, G. and Ollivier, H. (2018) Cleaner firms or cleaner products? How product mix shapes emission intensity from manufacturing. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 88, 134158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrows, G. and Ollivier, H. (2021) Foreign demand, developing country exports, and CO2 emissions: Firm-level evidence from India. Journal of Development Economics 149, 102578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bastos, P., Silva, J. and Verhoogen, E. (2018) Export destinations and input prices. American Economic Review 108(2), 353392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benguria, F., Choi, J., Swenson, D. L. and Xu, M. (2022) Anxiety or pain? The impact of tariffs and uncertainty on Chinese firms in the trade war. Journal of International Economics 137, 103608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandt, L., Van Biesebroeck, J., Wang, L. and Zhang, Y. (2017) WTO accession and performance of Chinese manufacturing firms. American Economic Review 107(9), 27842820.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brucal, A., Javorcik, B. and Love, I. (2019) Good for the environment, good for business: Foreign acquisitions and energy intensity. Journal of International Economics 121(6), 103247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bustos, P. (2011) Trade liberalization, exports and technology upgrading: Evidence on the impact of mercosur on Argentinian firms. American Economic Review 101(1), 304340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherniwchan, J. (2017) Trade liberalization and the environment: Evidence from NAFTA and U.S. manufacturing. Journal of International Economics 105, 130149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherniwchan, J., Copeland, B. R. and Taylor, M. S. (2017) Trade and the environment: New methods, measurements, and results. Annual Review of Economics 9(1), 5985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, B. R. and Taylor, M. S. (1994) North-South trade and the environment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(3), 755787.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cui, J., Lapan, H. and Moschini, G. (2016) Productivity, export, and environmental performance: Air pollutants in the United States. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 98(2), 447467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cui, J., Tam, O. K., Wang, B. and Zhang, Y. (2020) The environmental effect of trade liberalization: Evidence from China’s manufacturing firms. The World Economy 43(12), 33573383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dai, M., Maitra, M. and Yu, M. (2016) Unexceptional exporter performance in China? The role of processing trade. Journal of Development Economics 121, 177189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feenstra, R. C., Romalis, J. and Schott, P. K. (2002). US Imports, Exports and Tariff Data, 1989-2001. 9387, NBER, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Feenstra, R. C., Li, Z. and Yu, M. (2014) Exports and credit constraints under incomplete information: Theory and evidence from China. Review of Economics and Statistics 96(4), 729744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feng, L., Li, Z. and Swenson, D. L. (2017) Trade policy uncertainty and exports: Evidence from China’s WTO accession. Journal of International Economics. 106, 2036.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forslid, R., Okubo, T. and Ulltveit-Moe, K. H. (2018) Why are firms that export cleaner? International trade, abatement and environmental emissions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 91, 166183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankel, J. and Rose, A. (2005) Is trade good or bad for the environment? Sorting out the causality. Review of Economics and Statistics 87(1), 8591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. M. and Krueger, A. B. (1991) Environmental impacts of a North American free trade agreement. 3914, NBER Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gutiérrez, E. and Teshima, K. (2018) Abatement expenditures, technology choice, and environmental performance: evidence from firm responses to import competition in Mexico. Journal of Development Economics 133, 264274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handley, K. (2014) Exporting under trade policy uncertainty: Theory and evidence. Journal of International Economics 94(1), 5066.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handley, K. and Limão, N. (2015) Trade and investment under policy uncertainty: Theory and firm evidence. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7(4), 189222.Google Scholar
Handley, K. and Limão, N. (2017) Policy uncertainty, trade and welfare: Theory and evidence for China and the U.S. American Economic Review 107(9), 27312783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, G., Wang, S. and Zhang, B. (2020a) Watering down environmental protection in China. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 135(4), 21352185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, L.-Y. and Huang, G. (2021) How can export improve firms’ energy efficiency? The role of innovation investment. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 59, 9097.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, L.-Y. and Huang, G. (2022) Are China’s trade interests overestimated? Evidence from firms’ importing behavior and pollution emissions. China Economic Review 71, 101738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, L.-Y., Lin, X. and Liu, Q. (2020b) How did free trade reshape the transitional China? Evidence from heterogeneous exporters and firm-level pollution emissions. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 56(8), 16511676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, L.-Y., Lin, X. and Zhang, Z. X. (2020c) The impact of de-globalization on China’s economic transformation: Evidence from manufacturing export. Journal of Policy Modeling. 42(3), 628660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holladay, J. S. (2016) Exporters and the environment. The Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d’économique 49(1), 147172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, G., He, L.-Y. and Lin, X. (2022) Robot adoption and energy performance: Evidence from Chinese industrial firms. Energy Economics 107, 105837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imbruno, M. and Ketterer, T. D. (2018) Energy efficiency gains from importing intermediate inputs: Firm-level evidence from Indonesia. Journal of Development Economics. 135, 117141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kwon, O., Zhao, H. and Zhao, M. Q. (2023) Global firms and emissions: Investigating the dual channels of emissions abatement. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 118, 102772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lin, F. (2017) Trade openness and air pollution: City-level empirical evidence from China. China Economic Review 45, 7888.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lin, X. and He, L.-Y. (2023a) The more the merrier? Evidence from firm-level exports and environmental performance in China. Environmental and Resource Economics 84(1), 125172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lin, X. and He, L.-Y. (2023b) Going global and pollution in home country: Evidence from Chinese industrial firms. Economics of Transition and Institutional Change 31(4), 11351174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, M., Zhang, B. and Liao, X. (2022) Can trade liberalization promote green production? Evidence from China’s manufacturing enterprises. Journal of Asian Economics 79, 101369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, M., Shadbegian, R. and Zhang, B. (2017) Does environmental regulation affect labor demand in China? Evidence from the textile printing and dyeing industry. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 86, 277294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, M., Tan, R. and Zhang, B. (2021) The costs of “blue sky”: Environmental regulation, technology upgrading, and labor demand in China. Journal of Development Economics 150, 102610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, Q. and Ma, H. (2020) Trade policy uncertainty and innovation: Firm level evidence from China’s WTO accession. Journal of International Economics 127, 103387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lu, Y. and Yu, L. (2015) Trade liberalization and markup dispersion: Evidence from China’s WTO accession. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 7(4), 221253.Google Scholar
Melitz, M. J. (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6), 16951725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierce, J. R. and Schott, P. K. (2016) The surprisingly swift decline of US manufacturing employment. American Economic Review 106(7), 16321662.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierce, J. R. and Schott, P. K. (2018) Investment responses to trade liberalization: Evidence from U.S industries and plants. Journal of International Economics 115, 203222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richter, P. M. and Schiersch, A. (2017) CO2 emission intensity and exporting: Evidence from german firm-level data. European Economic Review 98, 373391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrigue, J., Sheng, D. and Tan, Y. (2022a) Exporting, abatement, and firm-level emissions: Evidence from China’s accession to the WTO. The Review of Economics and Statistics 145. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_01194. Google Scholar
Rodrigue, J., Sheng, D. and Tan, Y. (2022b) The curious case of the missing Chinese emissions. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 9(4), 755805.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roy, J. and Yasar, M. (2015) Energy efficiency and exporting: Evidence from firm-level data. Energy Economics 52, 127135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, J. S. (2021) The environmental bias of trade policy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 136(2), 831886.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, J. S. and Walker, R. (2018) Why is pollution from US manufacturing declining? The roles of environmental regulation, productivity, and trade. American Economic Review 108(12), 38143854.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shi, X. and Xu, Z. (2018) Environmental regulation and firm exports: Evidence from the eleventh five-year plan in China. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 89, 187200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yu, M. (2015) Processing trade, tariff reductions and firm productivity: Evidence from Chinese firms. The Economic Journal 125(585), 943988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, B., Chen, X. and Guo, H. (2018) Does central supervision enhance local environmental enforcement? Quasi-experimental evidence from China. Journal of Public Economics 164, 7090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The change rates of pollution emission and decomposed variables of industrial firms in China, 1998-2012. Data sources: Calculation by the data from the Chinese Environmental Statistics Firm Database (CESFD) and the Chinese Industrial Firm Database (CIFD). Note: We employ SO2 as the pollutant and 1998 as the baseline year. We delete the extreme values ranking in the top and bottom 1%.

Figure 1

Table 1. The observations of merged dataset

Figure 2

Table 2. The comparison between merged dataset and CESFD

Figure 3

Table 3. Descriptive statistics on main variables

Figure 4

Table 4. 2SLS estimation: the impact of trade policy uncertainty on pollution emissions

Figure 5

Table 5. Controlling for environmental regulation

Figure 6

Table 6. More discussion for export behavior

Figure 7

Figure 2. Anticipation effect and dynamic effect. Note: We employ the interaction term of distance from port and exchange rate as IV of export behaviors and remove any firms with changing located cities. Panels (a) and (b) focus on firms exporting to the USA and regard 2000 as the baseline period. Panels (c) and (d) focus on all exporters and regard 1998 and 1999 as baseline periods. In panels (a) and (c), dependent variables are emission intensity, and in panels (b) and (d), dependent variables are output value. We employ SO2 as the pollutant. The level of confidence interval is 90%.

Figure 8

Table 7. Placebo: changing the time of the event

Figure 9

Table 8. Other robustness checks

Figure 10

Table 9. Mechanism: energy efficiency

Figure 11

Table 10. Mechanism: abatement technology

Figure 12

Table 11. Mechanism: energy structure

Figure 13

Table 12. Heterogeneous tests: different industries

Figure 14

Table 13. Heterogeneous tests: different regions