Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T21:30:05.439Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HOME TO MARKET: IMPLICATIONS FOR THE CONSUMPTION TO OUTPUT RATIO

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 July 2017

Kellie Forrester*
Affiliation:
California State Polytechnic University Pomona
*
Address correspondence to: Kellie Forrester, California State Polytechnic University Pomona, 3801 West Temple Ave., Pomona, CA 91768, USA; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

The United States' postwar period has seen an increase in aggregate market hours worked, a decline in home production hours, and an increase in the consumption to output ratio. A multisector growth model that allows for an increase in total factor productivity in the market sector relative to the home sector can account for these phenomena. Households shift hours to the more productive market sector and purchase measured market goods in favor of unmeasured home goods. This channel accounts for a quarter of the increase in the consumption to output ratio observed in the data from 1950 to 2007.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I am most grateful for the helpful comments from Peter Rupert, Espen Henriksen, Marek Kapicka, Javier Birchenall, Finn Kydland, Tom Cooley, Richard Rogerson, Carlos Zarazaga, Carlos Garriga, Ellen McGrattan, Julian Neira, Zach Bethune, and Rish Singhania. I also appreciate comments from Rachel Ngai and seminar participants at the 2013 Midwest Macroeconomics Conference at the University of Minnesota and participants at the UC Santa Barbara Macro Seminar. All errors are my own.

References

REFERENCES

Acemoğlu, Daron and Guerrieri, Veronica (2008) Capital deepening and nonbalanced economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 116, 467498.Google Scholar
Akbulut, Rahşan (2011) Sectoral changes and the increase in women's labor force participation. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 240264.Google Scholar
Attanasio, Orazio P. (1993) A Cohort Analysis of Saving Behavior by U.S. Households. NBER working papers 4454, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess, Rogerson, Richard, and Wright, Randall (1991) Homework in macroeconomics: Household production and aggregate fluctuations. Journal of Political Economy 99, 1166–87.Google Scholar
Bridgman, Benjamin (2013) Home Productivity. BEA working papers 0091, Bureau of Economic Analysis.Google Scholar
Chen, Kaiji, Ayşe Ịmrohoroğlu, and Selahattin Ịmrohoroğlu (2006) Secular Trends in U.S Saving and Consumption. Computing in Economics and Finance 2006 no. 494, Society for Computational Economics.Google Scholar
Cociuba, Simona, Prescott, Edward, and Ueberfeldt, Alexander (2012) U.S. hours and productivity behavior using CPS hours-worked data: 1947:III–2011:IV. Unpublished paper.Google Scholar
Cortés, Patricia and Tessada, José (2011) Low-skilled immigration and the labor supply of highly skilled women. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 3, 88123.Google Scholar
Fitoussi, Jean-Paul, Sen, Amartya, and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2010) Mis- Measuring Our Lives: Why GDP Doesn't Add Up. New York, NY: The New Press.Google Scholar
Gokhale, Jagadeesh, Kotliko, Laurence J., and Sabelhaus, John (1996) Understanding the Postwar Decline in U.S. Saving: A Cohort Analysis, NBER working papers 5571, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.Google Scholar
Gollin, Douglas, Parente, Stephen L., and Rogerson, Richard (2007) The food problem and the evolution of international income levels. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 12301255.Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. (2015) Secular stagnation: A supply-side view. American Economic Review 105, 5459.Google Scholar
Hazan, Moshe and Zoabi, Hosny (2015) Do highly educated women choose smaller families? Economic Journal 125, 11911226.Google Scholar
Judd, K. L. (1998) Numerical Methods in Economics. Scientic and Engineering: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Laitner, John (2000) Structural change and economic growth. Review of Economic Studies 67, 545561.Google Scholar
Mazzolari, Francesca and Ragusa, Giuseppe (2013) Spillovers from high- skill consumption to low-skill labor markets. Review of Economics and Statistics 95, 7486.Google Scholar
Ngai, L. Rachel and Pissarides, Christopher A. (2007) Structural change in a multisector model of growth. American Economic Review 97, 429443.Google Scholar
Ngai, L. Rachel and Pissarides, Christopher A. (2008) Trends in hours and economic growth. Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 239256.Google Scholar
Ramey, Valerie A. and Francis, Neville (2009) A century of work and leisure. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1, 189224.Google Scholar
Rogerson, Richard (2008) Structural transformation and the deterioration of european labor market outcomes. Journal of Political Economy 116, 235259.Google Scholar
Rupert, Peter, Rogerson, Richard, and Wright, Randall (2000) Homework in labor economics: Household production and intertemporal substitution. Journal of Monetary Economics 46, 557579.Google Scholar