Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-29T01:43:25.883Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

FISCAL POLICY AND THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 May 2016

Santanu Chatterjee*
Affiliation:
University of Georgia
Azer Mursagulov
Affiliation:
Ministry of Finance, Republic of Azerbaijan
*
Address correspondence to: Santanu Chatterjee, Department of Economics, Terry College of Business, University of Georgia, Athens, GA 30602, USA; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

This paper examines the mechanisms through which government spending affects the dynamics of the real exchange rate. Using a two-sector dependent open economy model with intersectoral mobility costs for private capital, we show that public investment generates (i) a nonmonotonic U-shaped adjustment path for the real exchange rate with sharp intertemporal trade-offs and (ii) a crowding-in of private consumption, consistent with stylized facts. The effects of public consumption, however, are in sharp contrast to those of public investment. The effect of government spending on the real exchange rate depends critically on (i) the sectoral composition of public spending, (ii) the underlying financing policy, (iii) the sectoral intensity of private capital in production, (iv) the relative sectoral productivity of public infrastructure, (v) the elasticity of substitution in production, and (vi) intersectoral mobility costs for capital. In deriving these results, we identify conditions under which the predictions of the neoclassical open economy model can be reconciled with empirical regularities. Our results underscore the importance of decoupling the effects of government investment from those of government consumption in understanding the relationship between fiscal policy and the real exchange rate.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Abbas, S.M., Bouhga-Hagbe, J., Fatás, A., Mauro, P., and Velloso, R. (2011) Fiscal policy and the current account. IMF Economic Review 59, 603629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agenor, P. (2012) Public Capital, Growth and Welfare: Analytical Foundations for Public Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Agenor, P. and Aizenman, J. (2010) Aid, volatility, and poverty traps. Journal of Development Economics 91, 17.Google Scholar
Ahmad, Y., Lo, M., and Mykhaylova, O. (2013) Causes of nonlinearities in low-order models of the real exchange rate. Journal of International Economics 91 (1), 128141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aschauer, D.A. (1989) Is public expenditure productive? Journal of Monetary Economics 23, 177200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asea, P. and Mendoza, E. (1994) The Balassa–Samuelson model: A general-equilibrium appraisal. Review of International Economics 2, 244267.Google Scholar
Auerbach, A. and Kotlikoff, L. (1987) Dynamic Fiscal Policy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. (1990) Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. Journal of Political Economy 98, S103S125.Google Scholar
Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995) Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Berg, A., Mirzoev, T., Portillo, R., and Zanna, L-F. (2010) The Short-Run Macroeconomics of Aid Inflows: Understanding the Interaction of Fiscal and Reserve Policy. Working paper 10/65, IMF.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. and Perotti, R. (2002) An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 13291368.Google Scholar
Bom, P. and Ligthart, J. (2014) What have we learned from three decades of research on the productivity of public capital? Journal of Economic Surveys 28, 889916.Google Scholar
Bouakez, H., Chihi, F., and Normandin, M. (2011) Fiscal Policy and External Adjustment: New Evidence. Working paper 11-23, CIRPÉE.Google Scholar
Bouakez, H. and Eyquem, A. (2011) Government Spending, Monetary Policy, and the Real Exchange Rate. Working paper, HEC Montreal.Google Scholar
Brock, P. and Turnovsky, S. (1994) The dependent economy model with both traded and nontraded capital goods. Review of International Economics 2, 306325 Google Scholar
Caporale, G., Ciferri, D., and Girardi, A. (2011) Fiscal shocks and real exchange rate dynamics: Some evidence for Latin America. Journal of International Money and Finance 30, 709723.Google Scholar
Cerra, V., Tekin, S., and Turnovsky, S. (2010) Foreign transfers and real exchange rate adjustments in a financially constrained dependent economy. Open Economies Review 20, 147181.Google Scholar
Chatterjee, S. (2007) Should the private sector provide public capital? Macroeconomic Dynamics 11, 318346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chatterjee, S. and Morshed, M. (2011) Infrastrucutre provision and macroeconomic performance. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 35, 11511386.Google Scholar
Cheung, Y. and Lai, K. (2000) On cross-country differences in the persistence of real exchange rates. Journal of International Economics 50, 375397.Google Scholar
Chowdhury, I. (2004) Sources of exchange rate fluctuations: Empirical evidence from six emerging market countries. Applied Financial Economics 14, 697705.Google Scholar
Corsetti, G., Meier, A., and Müller, G. (2012) Fiscal stimulus with spending reversals. Review of Economics and Statistics 94, 878895.Google Scholar
Corsetti, G. and Müller, G. (2006) Twin deficits: Squaring theory, evidence and common sense. Economic Policy 21 (48), 597638.Google Scholar
Cushman, D. and Michael, N. (2011) Non-linear trends in real exchange rates: A panel unit root test approach. Journal of International Money and Finance 30, 16191637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dornbusch, R. (1976) Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84, 11611176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, J. and Gersovitz, M. (1989) Country risk and the organization of international capital transfer. In Calvo, G., Findlay, R., Kouri, P., and de Macedo, J. Braga (eds.), Debt,Stabilization and Development: Essays in Memory of Carlos Diaz-Alejandro, pp. 109129. Oxford, UK:Blackwell.Google Scholar
Edwards, S. and Savastano, M. (1999) Exchange Rates in Emerging Economies: What Do We Know? What Do We Need to Know? Working paper 7228, NBER.Google Scholar
Enders, Z., Müller, G., and Scholl, A. (2011) How do fiscal and technology shocks affect real exchange rates? New evidence for the United States. Journal of International Economics 83 (1), 5369.Google Scholar
Engel, C. (1993) Real exchange rates and relative prices: An empirical investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 3550.Google Scholar
Engel, C. (1999) Accounting for U.S. real exchange rate changes. Journal of Political Economy 107, 507538.Google Scholar
Fatas, A. and Mihov, I. (2001) The Effects of Fiscal Policy on Consumption and Employment: Theory and Evidence. Manuscript, INSEAD.Google Scholar
Fisher, W.H. and Turnovsky, S.J. (1998) Public investment, congestion, and private capital accumulation. Economic Journal 108, 399413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Froot, K. and Rogoff, K. (1995) The EMS, the EMU, and the transition to a common currency. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 6, 269317.Google Scholar
Galstyan, V. and Lane, P. (2009) The composition of government spending and the real exchange rate. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41, 12331249.Google Scholar
Glomm, G. and Ravikumar, B. (1994) Public investment in infrastructure in a simple growth model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 18, 1173–87.Google Scholar
Gramlich, E.M. (1994) Infrastructure investment: A review essay. Journal of Economic Literature 32, 1176–96.Google Scholar
Guvenen, F., (2006) Reconciling conflicting evidence on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution: A macroeconomic perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 14511472.Google Scholar
Hayashi, F. (1982) Tobin's marginal q and average q: A neoclassical interpretation. Econometrica 50, 213224.Google Scholar
Jones, R. (1975) Income distribution and effective protection in a multicommodity trade model. Journal of Economic Theory 11: 115.Google Scholar
Kim, S. and Roubini, N. (2008) Twin deficit or twin divergence? Fiscal policy, current account, and real exchange rate in the U.S. Journal of International Economics 74, 362383.Google Scholar
Knetter, M. (1993) International comparisons of pricing to market behavior. American Economic Review 83, 473486.Google Scholar
Kollmann, R. (2010) Government purchases and the real exchange rate. Open Economies Review 21 (1), 4964.Google Scholar
La Porta, R., and Shleifer, A. (2014) Informality and development. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28, 109–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, W. (1974) Short-run and long-run equilibrium for a small open economy. Journal of Political Economy 82, 955–67.Google Scholar
McKinsey Global Institute (2013) Infrastructure Productivity: How to Save $1 Trillion a Year. London: McKinsey & Company.Google Scholar
Monacelli, T. and Perotti, R. (2010) Fiscal policy, the real exchange rate and traded goods. Economic Journal 120 (544), 437461.Google Scholar
Morshed, M. and Turnovsky, S. (2004) Sectoral adjustment costs and real exchange rate dynamics in a two-sector dependent economy. Journal of International Economics 63, 147177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mussa, M. (1978) Dynamic adjustment in the Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelson model. Journal of Political Economy 86, 775–91.Google Scholar
Neary, P. (1982) Intersectoral capital mobility, wage stickiness, and the case for adjustment assistance. In Bhagwati, J. (ed.), Import Competition and Response. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, M. (1989) Fiscal deficits and relative prices in a growing world economy. Journal of Monetary Economics 23, 461484.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, M. (1993) Model Trending Real Exchange Rates. Working paper 11, CIDER.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. (1995) Exchange rate dynamics redux. Journal of Political Economy 103, 624660.Google Scholar
Ortiguera, S. and Santos, M. (1997) On the speed of convergence in endogenous growth models. American Economic Review 87, 383399.Google Scholar
Ravn, M., Schmitt-Grohe, S., and Uribe, M. (2012) Consumption, government spending, and the real exchange rate. Journal of Monetary Economics 59, 215234.Google Scholar
Rioja, F. (2003) Filling potholes: Macroeconomic effects of maintenance vs. new investments in public infrastructure. Journal of Public Economics 87, 22812304.Google Scholar
Sen, P. and Turnovsky, S. (1990) Investment tax credit in an open economy. Journal of Public Economics 42, 277309.Google Scholar
Taylor, M. (1995) The economics of exchange rates. Journal of Economic Literature 33, 1347.Google Scholar
Taylor, M., Peel, D., and Sarno, L. (2001) Non-linear mean reversion in real exchange rates: Toward a solution to the purchasing power parity puzzles. International Economic Review 42, 10151042.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, S. (1997) Fiscal policy in a growing economy with public capital. Macroeconomic Dynamics 1, 615631.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, S. (1997) International Macroeconomic Dynamics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Urban Land Institute and Ernst & Young (2013) Infrastructure 2013: Global Priorities, Global Insights. Washington, DC: Urban Land Institute.Google Scholar
Uribe, M. and Schmitt-Grohe, S. (2003) Closing small open economy models. Journal of International Economics 61, 163185.Google Scholar
van der Ploeg, F. (2011) Natural resources: Curse or blessing? Journal of Economic Literature 49, 366420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Wincoop, E. (1993) Structural adjustment and the construction sector. European Economic Review 37, 177201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar