Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T02:46:57.647Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Financial shocks and the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment: Evidence from the euro area

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2022

Johannes Gareis*
Affiliation:
Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt, Germany
Eric Mayer
Affiliation:
University of Würzburg, Würzburg, Germany
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We develop an extended real business cycle model with financially constrained firms and non-pledgeable intangible capital. Based on a model-consistent series for firms’ borrowing conditions, we find, within a structural vector autoregression framework, that, in response to an adverse financial shock, tangible investment falls more than intangible investment. This positive co-movement between tangible and intangible investment as well as the relative resilience of intangible investment pose a challenge for the theoretical model. We show that investment-specific adjustment costs help in reconciling the model with the observed empirical evidence. The estimation of the theoretical model using a Bayesian limited information approach yields support for the presence of much larger adjustment costs for intangible investment than for tangible investment.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

Since the Great Recession of 2008–2009, research using dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models has been devoted to studying the macroeconomic effects of financial shocks. Such work shows that this type of disturbance generates fluctuations in real macroeconomic variables.Footnote 1 In this paper, we focus on the effects of financial shocks on the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment. An inspection of the data suggests that adverse financial shocks lead firms to cut back more on tangible investment than on intangible investment. Figure 1 displays the business cycle components of tangible and intangible investment as a whole in the four largest euro area countries, as derived from Eurostat’s national accounts data. We measure tangible investment as machinery and equipment investment plus nonresidential construction investment. Intangible investment is measured as investments in intellectual property products, which, according to the current accounting standard, cover expenditures on research and development (R&D), mineral exploration and evaluation, computer software and databases, entertainment, literary, and artistic originals.Footnote 2 Focusing on the period of the Great Recession, when borrowing conditions for firms in the euro area’s big four economies deteriorated considerably (see, e.g. Gilchrist and Mojon (Reference Gilchrist and Mojon2018)), we can make two observations: First, both tangible investment and intangible investment fell below their trends. Second, intangible investment registered only a small decline, while tangible investment showed a marked drop. Note that these observations also hold for alternative detrending methods.Footnote 3 Furthermore, they are consistent with the findings of Corrado et al. (Reference Corrado, Haskel, Jona-Lasinio and Iommi2018) for European countries and the US based on annual data from the INTAN-Invest database.Footnote 4

Figure 1. Tangible and intangible investment. Note: The figure displays tangible and intangible investment in the four largest euro area countries as a whole, as derived from Eurostat’s national accounts data. Tangible investment is measured as machinery and equipment investment plus non-residential construction investment. Intangible investment is investment in intellectual property products. All data are seasonally adjusted, expressed in real terms and detrended in logs with a one-sided HP filter using a smoothing parameter of $\lambda =1600$ . The shaded areas indicate Center for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) recession dates for the euro area as a whole.

To explore the effects of financial shocks on tangible and intangible investment, we use a modified version of the Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012) model. This model is a real business cycle (RBC) model augmented by financially constrained firms and financial shocks. In this economy, firms use equity and intertemporal debt. Furthermore, they raise funds with interest-free intraperiod loans to finance working capital. Since firms cannot commit to repaying these loans, they face a borrowing constraint. This constraint is subject to stochastic disturbances, that is, financial shocks. In Jermann and Quadrini’s model, firms hire labor from households and hold productive capital, which can be pledged as collateral in debt contracts. A negative financial shock lowers the amount that the firm can borrow and so the firm reduces labor and investment in response to the shock. Here, we distinguish between two different types of productive capital, namely tangible and intangible capital. These two types of capital are assumed to differ in several dimensions. Most importantly, given the limited collateralizability of intangible capital, we assume in our baseline specification that only tangible capital is pledgeable as collateral in debt contracts (see also Lopez and Olivella (Reference Lopez and Olivella2018) and Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019)). Working within this modeling framework, we show that, in response to an adverse financial shock, it is optimal for firms to shift resources toward pledgeable tangible capital and away from nonpledgeable intangible capital in order to mitigate the tightening of financial conditions.Footnote 5 Firms achieve this by sharply reducing intangible investment and increasing tangible investment after the shock is realized. Hence, tangible investment and intangible investment co-move negatively in the aftermath of a financial shock. One possible explanation for the negative co-movement between the two investment types is that it incurs no costs for firms to adjust tangible and intangible capital. We therefore add adjustment costs in the accumulation process for tangible and intangible capital and study the model dynamics.Footnote 6 We show that the presence of investment adjustment costs can alter the firm’s incentives such that the firm reduces tangible investment along with intangible investment. Intuitively, if intangible investment is much more costly to adjust than tangible investment, the firm chooses to reduce tangible investment to a larger extent than intangible investment. As a result, in response to a negative financial shock, the model generates a positive co-movement between tangible and intangible investment as well as a rise in the intangible/tangible investment ratio, that is, intangible investment declines by less than tangible investment does. We are not the only ones to stress that intangible investment has higher adjustment costs than tangible investment. For example, Chiavari and Sampreet (Reference Chiavari and Sampreet2021) also find higher adjustment costs for intangible investment relative to tangible investment by estimating production functions based on data on publicly traded US firms from Compustat. A number of papers have highlighted other, not mutually exclusive, mechanisms operating alongside adjustment costs that also make intangible investment more resilient to shocks. Crouzet and Eberly (Reference Crouzet and Eberly2019) point out that high depreciation rates on intangible capital goods attenuate the response to a monetary policy shock because high depreciation rates dominate the user cost of capital. Döttling and Ratnovski (Reference Döttling and Ratnovski2020) present panel estimates to identified monetary policy shocks that are consistent with this view. It is reasonable to asssume that this mechanism, which is effective for a monetary policy shock, is also effective for financial shocks. Our model also implies that higher depreciation rates on intangible capital mitigate the decline of intangible investment and potentially solves the co-movement problem between intangible and tangible investment in response to a financial shock. In a related strand of literature, e.g., Falato, et al. (Reference Falato, Kadyrzhanova and Sim2013), Rampini and Viswanathan (Reference Rampini and Viswanathan2013) and Caggese and Ander (Reference Caggese and Ander2020), it is argued that firms that rely heavily on intangible investments anticipate future financial constraints and hoard cash as a buffer stock. This is an additional mechanism that explains why firms with high shares of intangible investment are less responsive to shocks. The view that intangible intensive firms hold more cash is also well documented in the finance literature, see Bates et al. (Reference Bates, Kahle and Stulz2009).Footnote 7 In our model, we also provide evidence that an increasing share of intangible capital reduces the debt capacity of firms and makes them more vulnerable to shocks in borrowing constraints due to a lack of alternative sources of financing. Moreover, it is argued in the literature that payment schemes for highly skilled workers that are deferred to a later stage and therefore do not need to be financed by intra-period loans are an additional mechanism that makes intangible investment less sensitive to financial shocks.Footnote 8

As for the broader empirical analysis of this paper, we use quarterly national and financial accounts data from Eurostat and the ECB. We focus on aggregated data for the big four euro area countries due to limited data availability and quality for the euro area as a whole.Footnote 9 Following Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012), we initially use the Solow residual approach to recover a model-consistent series for aggregate financial market conditions from the theoretical model. After we show that this series tracks reasonably well alternative indicators for proxying the degree of borrowing constraints for firms in the euro area big four, we include the constructed series in a structural vector autoregression (SVAR) and examine the effects of identified financial shocks on real economic quantities, notably tangible and intangible investment. We identify financial shocks by applying a recursive identification scheme (see, e.g. Gilchrist and Zakrajsek (Reference Gilchrist and Zakrajsek2012)). That is, we assume that shocks to the financial conditions variable affect real economy variables only with a time lag, while shocks to real economy variables impact the financial conditions variable contemporaneously. Our results suggest that financial shocks lead to economically meaningful and statistically significant declines in aggregate economic activity, household consumption, tangible investment, and intangible investment. Importantly, we find that tangible and intangible investment co-move positively and that intangible investment proves to be much more resilient to financial shocks than tangible investment is. To our knowledge, this is the first paper to empirically investigate the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment in response to financial shocks within a SVAR framework.

Equipped with empirical impulse response functions, we finally estimate the theoretical model using the Bayesian impulse response estimation procedure developed in Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Trabandt, Walentin, Christiano, Trabandt and Walentin2010). The estimation results suggest that adjustment costs for intangible investment are much larger than those for tangible investment. This finding is consistent with results reported in Peters and Taylor (Reference Peters and Taylor2017) and Chiavari and Sampreet (Reference Chiavari and Sampreet2021). In this literature, it is argued that intangible capital has relatively large adjustment costs because adjusting intangible capital requires firms to adjust the number of high-skilled workers (see, e.g. Brown et al. (Reference Brown, Fazzari and Petersen2009)). Our work shows that the relatively high adjustment costs for intangible investment have major implications for the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment in response to financial shocks. When confronted with an unexpected tightening in borrowing conditions, firms attempt to maintain intangible investment by reducing tangible investment in order to minimize adjustment costs. Hence, intangible investment reacts less strongly to financial shocks than tangible investment does. Turning to the comparison between the empirical and the model-implied impulse response functions, we show that the model replicates well the observed transmission of an adverse financial shock based on the SVAR. The theoretical model accounts for the reduction in aggregate economic activity, household consumption, tangible investment, and intangible investment. Importantly, the model predicts a fall in tangible and intangible investment, although intangible investment declines much less than tangible investment.

The effects of financial shocks on tangible and intangible investment have been receiving attention in the literature using DSGE models. Lopez and Olivella (Reference Lopez and Olivella2018) study the role of intangible capital in the transmission of financial shocks using an RBC model with financial and labor market frictions but without costly capital accumulation. Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019) analyze the transmission of various types of financial shocks in the US economy through the lens of an estimated DSGE model which features endogenous growth and investment-specific adjustment costs. One key contribution made by our paper to this literature is to isolate the implications of the presence of investment-specific adjustment costs for the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment in response to financial shocks. Our model shares with Lopez and Olivella (Reference Lopez and Olivella2018) and Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019) the assumption that firms’ borrowing is constrained and that intangible capital cannot be pledged as collateral in debt contracts.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the theoretical model and discusses its dynamic behavior. Section 3 presents empirical evidence on the macroeconomic consequences of identified financial shocks. Section 4 estimates the theoretical model. Section 5 presents counterfactuals for the Great Recession. Section 6 concludes.

2. The model economy

In this section, we formally describe the theoretical framework and discuss the main mechanisms at work. Our model is a RBC model augmented by financially constrained firms and intangible capital. Intangible capital enters the production function as a third input factor, along with tangible capital and labor (see, e.g. McGrattan and Prescott (Reference McGrattan and Prescott2010), Malik et al. (Reference Malik, Ali and Khalid2014) and Lopez and Olivella (Reference Lopez and Olivella2018)). The financial structure is modeled following Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012). The assumption that intangible capital — unlike tangible capital — cannot be used as collateral in debt contracts is borrowed from Lopez and Olivella (Reference Lopez and Olivella2018) and Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019). The notion that intangible capital is less easy to pledge as collateral in debt contracts is supported by theoretical arguments (see, e.g. Shleifer and Vishny (Reference Shleifer and Vishny1992)) and empirical work (see, e.g. Sibilkov (Reference Sibilkov2009)). There is also literature that argues that firms primarily rely on internal funds to finance intangible assets (see, e.g. Falato et al. (Reference Falato, Kadyrzhanova and Sim2013)). The difficulty of using intangible capital as collateral in debt contracts stems from the fact that intangible investments are typically riskier, more firm-specific and less transferable than tangible investments. However, Loumioti (Reference Loumioti2012) shows that some intangible assets, such as patents, might have a limited collateral value. Our model also allows for a limited collateral value of intangibles to check robustness. In our baseline specification, however, we assume that intangible capital cannot be used as collateral at all in order to simplify the analysis in the sense that the role of tangible and intangible capital in firms’ borrowing conditions is clearly defined, which helps to isolate the key mechanisms at work. We model investment adjustment costs following the standard modeling approach of Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans2005). On the household side, we follow Smets and Wouters (Reference Smets and Wouters2003) and assume external consumption habits, which are useful empirically to account for the persistence in the household’s consumption process and thus also in output. The model consists of a representative firm and a representative household. The time period is in quarters.

2.1 The representative firm

The representative firm produces final goods, $Y_t$ , by combining tangible capital, $K_{T,t}$ , with intangible capital, $K_{I,t}$ , and labor, $N_{t}$ . The production technology is given by the following three-factor Cobb—Douglas production function:

(1) \begin{equation} Y_t=K_{T,t}^{\alpha _{K_T}}K_{I,t}^{\alpha _{K_I}}N_{t}^{1-\alpha _{K_T}-\alpha _{K_I}}. \end{equation}

The firm hires labor from households and owns tangible and intangible capital. The law of motion of capital of type $j$ is

(2) \begin{equation} K_{j,t+1}=(1-{\delta _j})K_{j,t}+\left [1-\Phi _j\left (\frac{I_{j,t}}{I_{j,t-1}}\right )\right ]I_{j,t},\quad \text{for}\quad j={T,I}, \end{equation}

where $I_{j,t}$ is the time $t$ investment, $\delta _{j}$ is the depreciation rate, and $\Phi _j(\!\cdot\!)$ is the adjustment cost function, which is a positive convex function of the change in investment. The functional form for $\Phi _j(\!\cdot\!)$ reads:

(3) \begin{equation} \Phi _j\left (\frac{I_{j,t}}{I_{j,t-1}}\right )=\frac{\phi _j}{2}\left (\frac{I_{j,t}}{I_{j,t-1}}-1\right )^2,\quad \text{for}\quad j={T,I}, \end{equation}

where $\phi _j$ is the parameter that characterizes the size of the adjustment costs for investment of type $j$ . Note that $\Phi _j(\!\cdot\!)$ satisfies the following properties: $\Phi _j(1)=\Phi^{\prime}_j(1)=0$ and $\Phi ^{''}_j(1)=\phi _j\geq 0$ . When $\phi _T=\phi _I=0$ , the model economy is equivalent to one without costly capital accumulation.

As in Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012), we assume that firms use two broad categories of financing: equity and debt. Debt is preferred to equity because interest expenses are deductible (see also Hennessy and Whited (Reference Hennessy and Whited2005)). The effective gross interest rate for the firm is given by $R_t=1+r_{t}(1-\tau )$ , where $r_t$ is the interest rate on one-period intertemporal debt, $B_t$ , and $\tau$ is the tax benefit. The firm raises funds with interest-free intraperiod loans, $L_t$ , to finance working capital. This loan, which is repaied at the end of the period $t$ , is defined as

(4) \begin{equation} L_{t}=W_{t}N_{t}+I_{T,t}+I_{I,t}+B_{t}-\frac{B_{t+1}}{R_{t}}+\varphi (D_{t}), \end{equation}

where $W_{t}$ is the wage rate and $\varphi (D_{t})$ are total equity payout costs. The latter comprise the actual equity payout and equity payout adjustment costs, which account for the empirical regularity with which firm managers tend to smooth dividend payments (see, for example, Lintner (Reference Lintner1956) and Brav, et al. (Reference Brav, Graham, Harvey and Michaely2005)). The functional form for $\varphi (D_{t})$ is given by

(5) \begin{equation} \varphi (D_{t})=D_{t}+\kappa (D_t-{D})^2, \end{equation}

where the parameter $\kappa \gt 0$ determines the sensitivity of the equity payout adjustment costs to the actual equity payout, $D_t$ , and $D$ denotes the steady state level of $D_t$ . The firm’s flow of funds constraint is

(6) \begin{equation} W_{t}N_{t}+I_{T,t}+I_{I,t}+B_{t}+\varphi (D_{t})=\frac{B_{t+1}}{R_t}+Y_t. \end{equation}

Substituting equation (4) into equation (6), it is possible to verify that the intraperiod loan is equal to the firm’s production (i.e. $L_t=Y_t$ ).

Following closely Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012), we assume that firms’ debt capacity is limited due to a limited enforceability of debt contracts, as firms can default on their obligations. Crucial to understand the financial contract is the assumption that the firm has all the bargaining power in the renegotiation and that the lender receives only the threat value. More specifically, it is assumed that liquidity can be easily diverted and the lender can only expropriate capital. At any time $t$ , a default may materialize after the realization of revenues but before the redemption of the intraperiod loan. At the time of default, the firm’s total liabilities are $L_t+\frac{B_{t+1}}{1+r_t}$ and the only assets available for liquidation are tangible capital and a fraction $\lambda _I$ of intangible capital. As in Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012), we assume that, at the moment of contracting the loan, the liquidation value of capital is uncertain and with probability $\chi _t$ the lender is able to recover the full value of tangible capital, whereas with probability $1-\chi _t$ the lender recovers zero. When the condition occurs in which capital has a positive liquidation value, the firm offers a payment of $K_{T,t+1}+\lambda _I K_{I,t+1}-B_{t+1}/(1+r_t)$ in period $t$ and promises to pay $B_{t+1}$ tomorrow to make the lender indifferent. If capital has a liquidation value of zero, the firm does not need to make a payment in period $t$ , as the lender has no claims to settle. Based on the anticipated outcome of the renegotiation process between the firm and the lender, we derive the following borrowing constraint for the firm:Footnote 10

(7) \begin{equation} L_{t}\leq{\chi _t}\!\left (K_{T,t+1}+\lambda _I K_{I,t+1}-\frac{B_{t+1}}{1+r_{t}}\right ). \end{equation}

The parameter $\lambda _I$ , with $0\le \lambda _I\le 1$ reflects the limited collateral value of intangible capital.Footnote 11 Equation (7) implies that the maximum amount of the intratemporal loan available to the firm is tied to the value of tangible capital and a limited value of intangible capital net of intertemporal debt. Hence, it is implicitly assumed that firms can also not commit to repay interperiod debt. As in Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012), we conjecture that the borrowing constraint is always satisfied with equality.Footnote 12 Using $L_t=Y_t$ , we can thus rewrite equation (7) as

(8) \begin{equation} Y_{t}={\chi _t}\!\left (K_{T,t+1}+\lambda _I K_{I,t+1}-\frac{B_{t+1}}{1+r_{t}}\right ). \end{equation}

Note that, throughout the paper, we refer to $\chi _t$ as the financial conditions variable. Similar to Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012), this variable is assumed to depend on (unspecified) financial market conditions and is subject to stochastic disturbances, that is, financial shocks.

The optimization problem of the firm is to maximize the expected present value of the future equity payouts, which is given by

(9) \begin{equation} E_{t-1}\sum _{s=0}^\infty \beta ^{s}\frac{U_{C,t+s}}{U_{C,t}}(D_{t+s}), \end{equation}

where $\beta$ is the household’s discount factor, $U_{C,t}$ is the household’s marginal utility of consumption, and $E_{t-1}$ is the expectation operator conditional on information available in period $t-1$ .Footnote 13 The firm chooses $\{D_{t}, Y_{t}, K_{T,t+1}, K_{I,t+1}, I_{T,t}, I_{I,t}, N_t, B_{t+1}\}$ to maximize (9) subject to equations (1), (2), (6), and (8). Denoting by $\mu _t$ the multiplier for the borrowing constraint, we can summarize the first-order conditions for the firm’s optimization problem as follows:

Debt:

(10) \begin{align} 1&={\beta }{R_t}{E_{t-1}}\left (\frac{U_{C,t+1}}{U_{C,t}}\frac{\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t})}{\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t+1})}\right )+{\chi _t}{\mu _{t}}\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t})\frac{R_t}{1+r_{t}}, \end{align}

Labor:

(11) \begin{align} \frac{\partial{Y_{t}}}{\partial{N_{t}}}&=\frac{W_{t}}{1-{\mu _{t}}\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t})}, \end{align}

Tangible capital:

(12) \begin{align} Q_{T,t} &= \beta{E_{t-1}}\Bigg (\frac{U_{C,t+1}}{U_{C,t}}\frac{\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t})}{\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t+1})}\Bigg [\frac{\partial{Y_{t+1}}}{\partial{K_{T,t+1}}}\left (1-\mu _{t+1}\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t+1})\right )+Q_{T,t+1}(1-\delta _T)\Bigg ]\Bigg ) \nonumber \\ &\quad +{\chi _t}\mu _t\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t}), \end{align}

Intangible capital:

(13) \begin{align} Q_{I,t} &= \beta{E_{t-1}}\Bigg (\frac{U_{C,t+1}}{U_{C,t}}\frac{\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t})}{\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t+1})}\Bigg [\frac{\partial{Y_{t+1}}}{\partial{K_{I,t+1}}}\left (1-\mu _{t+1}\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t+1})\right )+Q_{I,t+1}(1-\delta _I)\Bigg ]\Bigg ) \nonumber \\ &\quad +{\chi _t} \lambda _I \mu _t\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t}), \end{align}

Tangible and intangible investment:

(14) \begin{align} \quad Q_{j,t}&=\frac{1-\beta{E_{t-1}}\Bigg (\frac{U_{C,t+1}}{U_{C,t}}\frac{\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t})}{\varphi^{\prime}(D_{t+1})}Q_{j,t+1}\Phi^{\prime}_j\left (\frac{I_{j,t+1}}{I_{j,t}}\right )\left (\frac{I_{j,t+1}}{I_{j,t}}\right )^2\Bigg )}{1-\Phi _j\!\left (\frac{I_{j,t}}{I_{j,t-1}}\right )-\Phi^{\prime}_j\left (\frac{I_{j,t}}{I_{j,t-1}}\right )\left (\frac{I_{j,t}}{I_{j,t-1}}\right )}, \quad \text{for}\quad j={T,I}, \end{align}

where $\frac{\partial{Y_{t}}}{\partial{N_{t}}}$ is the marginal productivity of labor, $\frac{\partial{Y_{t+1}}}{\partial{K_{T,t+1}}}$ and $\frac{\partial{Y_{t+1}}}{\partial{K_{I,t+1}}}$ are the future returns on tangible capital and intangible capital, respectively. $Q_{j,t}$ denotes the current value of type- $j$ capital, and $\varphi '(D_{t})$ is the first derivative of $\varphi (D_{t})$ with respect to $D_t$ .Footnote 14 Equation (10) is the optimally condition for intertemporal debt. It implies that a negative financial shock induces a rise in the multiplier for the borrowing constraint. Equation (11) is the optimally condition for labor demand that requires the firm to equate the marginal productivity of labor to its marginal cost. The marginal cost of labor depends negatively on $\mu _{t}$ . A higher $\mu _t$ (i.e. a tighter borrowing constraint in period $t$ ) increases the effective costs of labor and thus reduces its demand. Equations (12) and (13) are the optimally conditions for tangible capital and intangible capital, respectively. Note that the financial shock $\chi _t$ operates through opposing transmission channels in equilibrium on the value of tangible capital $Q_{T,t}$ . On the one hand, an adverse shock reduces the value of tangible capital and thus the available amount of intra-period loans. This is the direct effect of the shock to the borrowing constraint in equation (7). On the other hand, there exists an opposing indirect transmission channel operating through $\mu _t$ . Concretely, the current value of tangible capital, $Q_{T,t}$ , depends positively on $\mu _{t}$ and negatively on $\mu _{t+1}$ . The higher $\mu _{t}$ , the higher the benefit of acquiring today an additional unit of tangible capital, which allows, by relaxing the borrowing constraint, to increase the current production. Hence, when $\mu _{t}$ rises, the firm demands more tangible capital. Since intangible capital cannot be pledged as collateral in debt contracts when $\lambda _I=0$ , $\mu _t$ has no direct impact on the current value of intangible capital, $Q_{I,t}$ . Similar to tangible capital, intangible capital also depends negatively on $\mu _{t+1}$ . A higher $\mu _{t+1}$ (i.e. a tighter borrowing constraint in period $t+1$ ), decreases the current value of an additional unit of tangible capital, respectively, intangible capital, as the additional capital requires a higher working capital loan in the future. Thus, a higher $\mu _{t+1}$ reduces the demand for both tangible capital and intangible capital. Equation (14) is the Euler equation for investment in capital of type $j$ . Note that when $\phi _T=\phi _I=0$ , it follows that $Q_{T,t}=Q_{I,t}=1$ .

2.2 The representative household

The representative household maximizes its expected lifetime utility, which reads:

(15) \begin{equation} E_{t-1}\sum _{s=0}^\infty \beta ^{s}U_{t+s}(C_{t+s}, N_{t+s}), \end{equation}

where $\beta$ denotes the household’s discount factor, $C_t$ is the consumption, and $N_t$ stands for labor supply. The period utility function is defined as

(16) \begin{equation} U_t=\text{log}(C_{t}-{\epsilon }C_{t-1})+\nu \text{log}(1-N_{t}). \end{equation}

Following Smets and Wouters (Reference Smets and Wouters2003), we assume external habit formation in consumption, with $\epsilon$ measuring the influence of past economy-wide average consumption on current utility. The household’s budget constraint is

(17) \begin{equation} C_t+\frac{B_{t+1}}{1+r_t}+T_t=B_{t}+W_{t}N_{t}+D_{t}, \end{equation}

where $W_t$ denotes the wage rate, $D_t$ is the equity payout, $B_{t+1}$ stands for the new one-period intertemporal bond issued by the firm, $r_t$ is the interest rate, and $T_t=\frac{B_{t+1}}{R_t}-\frac{B_{t+1}}{1+r_t}$ is a lump-sum tax, which is equal to the firm’s tax benefit of debt.

The household chooses $\{C_t, N_t, B_{t+1}\}$ to maximize (15) subject to equation (17). The first-order conditions for the household’s optimization problem are given by

(18) \begin{align}{\beta }(1+r_{t}){E_{t-1}}\left (\frac{U_{C,{t+1}}}{U_{C,t}}\right ) &= 1, \end{align}
(19) \begin{align}U_{N,t}+U_{C,t}W_{t} &=0 \end{align}

where $U_{C,t}\equiv \frac{\partial{U_{t}}}{\partial{C_{t}}}$ is the marginal utility of consumption and $U_{N,t}\equiv \frac{\partial{U_{t}}}{\partial{N_{t}}}$ is the marginal utility of labor supply.

2.3 Discussion

In this section, we discuss the main mechanisms at work. To this end, we show in Figure 2 impulse response functions of selected model variables to a negative one standard deviation financial shock.Footnote 15 The solid lines correspond to the responses when we hold the key model parameters at their calibrated or estimated values (see Section 4), implying, most importantly, that intangible investment is much more costly to adjust than tangible investment. The dashed lines in Figure 2 correspond to the responses for an alternative setting of the investment adjustment cost parameters, where we set $\phi _T=\phi _I=0$ so that the model economy is equivalent to one without costly capital accumulation.

Figure 2. Impulse response functions of selected model variables. Note: The figure displays impulse responses to a negative one standard deviation financial shock. The solid lines correspond to the responses when we hold the model parameters at their calibrated or estimated values, implying, most importantly, that intangible investment is much more costly to adjust than tangible investment. The dashed lines correspond to the responses of a model economy without investment adjustment costs. The marked solid lines correspond to a model economy without investment adjustment costs when we shut down the endogenous feedback of a tightening in $\mu _t$ on the value of tangible capital, $Q_{T,t}$ . Note that the dashed line and the marked solid line in the subplot for Intangible investment correspond to the scale of the y-axis on the right-hand side.

We first discuss the model-implied responses for the latter case. As is evident from the figure, a negative financial shock reduces the available amount of liabilities to finance the firm’s operations, which illustrates the direct effect of tighter financial conditions. In response, the firm reacts by reducing the equity payout. Since it is costly for the firm to change the equity payout, the firm is also forced to reduce labor. Overall, the direct effect from the borrowing constraint dominates, as output, labor, liabilities, intangible investment, and the equity payout decline. However, the indirect effect of the shock operating through an increase in the multiplier $\mu _t$ dominates on impact for the response of tangible investment. Interestingly, the firm increases tangible investment and sharply reduces intangible investment in response to the shock. The reason for this is that the tighter borrowing constraint leads the firm to reallocate resources toward pledgeable tangible capital and away from nonpledgeable intangible capital in order to mitigate the tightening of financial conditions. The firm achieves this by sharply reducing intangible investment and increasing tangible investment after the shock is realized. Hence, tangible investment and intangible investment co-move negatively in the aftermath of the financial shock.Footnote 16 This finding illustrates that the financial shock operates through two opposing transmission channels on the relative attractiveness of tangible capital. On the one hand, the direct borrowing constraint channel reduces the attractiveness of tangible investment as a marginal unit of tangible investment has a smaller relieving effect on the collateral constraint. On the other hand, the current value of tangible capital, $Q_{T,t}$ , depends positively on $\mu _t$ . The higher $\mu _t$ , the higher the benefit of acquiring today an additional unit of tangible capital, which allows, by relaxing the borrowing constraint, to increase the current production. To illustrate the quantitative importance of the direct effect from the tighter borrowing constraint for tangible investment, we shut down the multiplier channel $\mu _t$ on the value of tangible capital, $Q_{T,t}$ . To do so, we simulate the model by fixing the multiplier $\mu _t$ in equation (12) at its steady-state value to prevent that an increase in the multiplier makes tangible investment more attractive. The solid marked lines illustrate that, once the multiplier effect on the value of tangibles $Q_{T,t}$ is shut down, both types of investment decline on impact as the incentive to increase tangible investment disappears. Overall, in equilibrium, the distance between the dashed and the solid marked lines illustrates the importance of the increase of the multiplier $\mu _t$ for the case with no adjustment cost in dominating the direct effect of the borrowing constraint on impact for tangible investment.

One possible explanation for the negative co-movement between the two investment types in response to the financial shock is that it involves no cost for the firm to adjust tangible and intangible capital. The crucial role played by the presence of investment adjustment costs in the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment in the aftermath of a financial shock becomes evident from the solid lines in Figure 2. As can be seen, the tighter borrowing constraint forces the firm to reduce all productions inputs, which is reflected in the fall in labor as well as in tangible and intangible investment. In the presence of investment adjustment costs, it is costly for the firm to change tangible and intangible investment and, therefore, the firm is forced to cut tangible investment along with intangible investment. Intuitively, when intangible investment is much more costly to adjust than tangible investment is, the firm reduces tangible investment to a larger extent than intangible investment in order to minimize adjustment costs. Hence, the model generates a positive co-movement between tangible and intangible investment in the aftermath of the shock, with intangible investment declining much less than tangible investment.

In Figure 3, we take a closer look at the role of the relative size of the adjustment costs for tangible and intangible investment and also discuss the role of depreciation rates and the collateral value of intangible capital. To do so, we display in the figure the response of the intangible/tangible investment ratio in the left-hand side panels along with the responses of tangible and intangible investment in the right-hand side panels. The responses of tangible and intangible investment on the right correspond to the dashed-dotted lines on the left (representing the most favorable calibration of model parameters in terms of solving the co-movement problem), except in the first row where they correspond to the solid line. As the figure illustrates in the first row on the left-hand side, when tangible investment is equally costly to adjust as intangible investment is (i.e. $\phi _T = \phi _I$ = 9), the firm still reduces intangible investment by more than tangible investment so that the intangible/tangible investment ratio declines (dashed line). In this case, the firm is indifferent, in terms of minimizing adjustment costs, between reducing tangible or intangible investment. Thus, the larger decline in intangible investment than in tangible investment is due to the positive impact of the tighter borrowing constraint on the firm’s demand for tangible investment. However, at some point, when the adjustment costs for intangible investment are much higher than those for tangible investment (i.e. $\phi _T = 2, \phi _I$ = 9), the costs of reducing intangible investment to maintain tangible investment outweigh the benefits. On the one hand, the tightening of the borrowing constraint leads the firm to tilt resources toward pledgeable tangible capital at the expense of nonpledgeable intangible capital. On the other hand, the relatively high adjustment costs for intangible investment forces the firm to maintain intangible investment by reducing tangible investment. On balance, when adjustment costs for intangible investment are sufficiently larger than those for tangible investment, the firm reduces tangible investment by more than it reduces intangible investment so that the intangible/tangible investment ratio increases. The panel on the right-hand side in the first row illustrates that the impulse responses for $\phi _T=2$ and $\phi _I=9$ supports two prominent features of the data in response to a shock to the borrowing constraint. First, intangible investment is more resilient to shocks to the collateral constraint than intangible investment. Second, there is a positive co-movement between the impulses of tangibles and intangibles investment. Moreover, investment adjustment costs lead to the typical hump-shaped responses that characterizes the empirical impulse responses.

Figure 3. Impulse response functions of the intangible/tangible investment ratio as well as tangible and intangible investment. Note: The figure displays on the left-hand side the response of the intangible/tangible investment ratio to a negative one standard deviation financial shock based on alternative settings for the investment adjustment cost parameters, the degree of collateralizability, depreciation rates and investment-to-output ratios. In the subplots in the column on the right-hand side, we show the responses for intangible and tangible investment that correspond to the dashed-dotted lines on the left, except in the first row where they correspond to the solid line.

In the model, tangible and intangible capital differ not only in terms of adjustment costs but also in terms of collateralizability, depreciation rates, and investment-to-output ratios, which we address in the following sensitivity analysis. In the panels in the second row, we set the investment adjustment costs to zero but alter the collateralizability of intangibles with $\lambda _I$ moving from no collateralbility, $\lambda _I=0$ , to full collateralizability, $\lambda _I=1$ . The right-hand panel in row two illustrates that full collateralizability solves the negative co-movement in the impulse responses of tangible and intangible investment. Nevertheless, the ratio of intangible to tangible investment falls, as shown in the panel on the left. Since the capital share of tangibles is larger than the share of intangibles, firms have an incentive to cut back more on intangible investment to cushion the tightening of financial conditions in the face of a shrinking debt capacity. However, this incentive weakens as the collateral value of intangible capital increases. Furthermore, the introduction of collateralizability into the model does not accommodate hump-shaped responses of the impulse responses of tangible and intangible investment. In the panels in the third row, we set the investment adjustment costs to zero and assume that intangible capital is not collateralizable, but let the depreciation rates move from $\delta _I=0.025$ to $\delta _I=0.1375$ . The impulse responses are shown on the right, and it can be seen that higher depreciation rates solve the co-movement problem in terms of responses of tangible and intangible investment and mitigate the decline in intangible investment. This is in line with the literature that argues that higher depreciation rates for intangibles tend to dominate the user cost of capital and make other factors, such as variations in financial conditions, relatively unimportant (see, e.g. Crouzet and Eberly (Reference Crouzet and Eberly2019)). Again, variations in the depreciation rate do not lead to hump-shaped responses and do not prevent the investment ratio (left-hand side) from falling, contrary to the data. In the panels in the last row, we illustrate the effects of increasing the intangible investment-to-output ratio from $3.4\%$ , which is the value from the national accounts data, to $6.3\%$ , which is the value for the big four euro area countries when defining intangibles in a broader sense along the lines of Corrado et al. (Reference Corrado, Haskel, Jona-Lasinio and Iommi2018). The impulse response analysis reveals that higher shares of intangible investment do not solve the co-movement problem for the range of values under consideration. The incentive to mitigate financial frictions remains the driving factor in the light of a binding collateral constraint. In sum, the results confirm our main finding within our model that when tangible and intangible investment are not costly to adjust, the intangible/tangible investment ratio falls in response to a negative financial shock.

3. The empirical evidence

In this section, we quantify the macroeconomic consequences of identified financial shocks. To do so, we follow Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012) and use the Solow residual approach in order to construct the series for the financial conditions variable from the theoretical model. Then, we compare this measure to alternative indicators for proxying the degree of borrowing constraints for firms in the euro area big four. Finally, we introduce the constructed series for the financial conditions variable into a SVAR in order to examine the effects of identified financial shocks on real economic quantities, notably tangible, and intangible investment.

3.1 Financial conditions

As in Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012), we use the Solow residual approach to recover the series for the financial conditions variable from the model’s borrowing constraint. As shown in Section 2, the ability of the firm to borrow is affected by the variable $\chi _t$ via equation (8). Rearranging this equation and defining $B^e_{t}\equiv \frac{B_{t+1}}{1+r_t}$ as the end-of-period $t$ debt as well as $K^e_{T,t}\equiv{K_{T,t+1}}$ as the end-of-period $t$ stock of tangible capital, we can rewrite $\chi _t$ as

(20) \begin{equation} \chi _{t}=\frac{Y_{t}}{K^e_{T,t}-B^e_{t}}. \end{equation}

Log-linearizing equation (20) around the steady state, we obtain

(21) \begin{equation} \hat{\chi }_t={\chi }\frac{B^e}{Y}\hat{B}^e_{t}-{\chi }\frac{K^e_T}{Y}\hat{K}^e_{T,t}+\hat{Y}_t, \end{equation}

where the variables without a time subscript denote steady-state values and those with a hat sign represent log-deviations from steady-state values. We can use equation (21) to compute the $\hat{\chi }_t$ series once we have empirical measurements for $\hat{B}^e_{t}$ , $\hat{K}^e_{T,t}$ , and $\hat{Y}_t$ as well as appropriate values for $\chi$ , $\frac{B^e}{Y}$ and $\frac{K^e_T}{Y}$ .

To compute the series for $\hat{B}^e_{t}$ , $\hat{K}^e_{T,t}$ and $\hat{Y}_t$ , we extract the business cycle components of the empirical series for $B^e_{t}$ , $K^e_{T,t}$ and $Y_t$ , respectively.Footnote 17 For the $B^e_{t}$ , $K^e_{T,t}$ and $Y_t$ series, we use aggregated quarterly national and financial accounts data from the four largest euro area countries for the period from 1999.Q1 to 2018.Q4. The data are taken from Eurostat and ECB databases. The beginning of our sample is determined by the financial accounts data, which are available as of 1999.Q1. We construct the series for $B^e_t$ using the cumulative sum of new borrowing of non-financial corporations measured by the net flows of debt securities issued and loans received. The initial debt is set to the outstanding stock of debt securities and loans in 1999.Q1.Footnote 18 To construct the series for $K^e_{T,t}$ , we use the perpetual inventory method based on a geometric depreciation at the constant rate $\delta _T$ . Following Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012), we compute the initial stock of tangible capital so that the tangible capital-to-output ratio fluctuates around a zero growth trend over the period from 1999.Q1 to 2018.Q4.Footnote 19 We assume that $\delta _T=0.025$ , which implies an annual depreciation rate of tangible capital of $10\%$ , and iterate forward using the empirical series for tangible investment, which is measured as machinery and equipment investment plus non-residential construction investment. Furthermore, we use total GDP as an empirical proxy for $Y_t$ . All data are seasonally adjusted and expressed in real terms.Footnote 20 To pin down $\chi$ , $\frac{B^e}{Y}$ and $\frac{K^e_T}{Y}$ , we evaluate the model equations described in Section 2 in the steady state. After calibrating the parameters that govern the steady state of the model, we obtain $\chi =0.13$ , $\frac{B^e}{Y}=3.3$ , and $\frac{K^e_T}{Y}=11$ . Note that we provide a detailed description of the model calibration in Section 4.

Next, given the series for $\hat{B}^e_{t}$ , $\hat{K}^e_{T,t}$ , and $\hat{Y}_t$ as well as the values for $\chi$ , $\frac{B^e}{Y}$ , and $\frac{K^e_T}{Y}$ , we compute the $\hat{\chi }_t$ series. The results are shown in Figure 4. The solid line in the upper panel depicts the level series of $\hat{\chi }_t$ and the solid line in the lower panel depicts the series of the one-period changes in $\hat{\chi }_t$ . As is evident from the figure, the constructed financial conditions variable is pro-cyclical and displays pronounced fluctuations. According to our measure, borrowing conditions for firms in the euro area big four deteriorated prior to the Great Recession and tightened sharply during it. Following a temporary improvement, the measured borrowing conditions also tightened somewhat during the 2011—2013 recession, which is associated with the euro area sovereign debt crisis. Figure 4 further compares our measure to alternative indicators for proxying the degree of firms’ borrowing constraints. In the upper panel of the figure, we compare the level series of $\hat{\chi }_t$ and the credit spread index as provided by Gilchrist and Mojon (Reference Gilchrist and Mojon2018), which carefully measures the cost of market funding for non-financial firms in the four largest euro area countries a whole. For comparison purposes, the credit spread index, which is shown with dashed lines, is multiplied by $-1$ , standardized and rescaled to have the same mean and standard deviation as $\hat{\chi }_t$ . In the lower panel of the figure, we compare the series of the changes in $\hat{\chi }_t$ and the weighted average of the national diffusion indices of the change in bank credit standards for loans to non-financial corporations for the four largest euro area countries.Footnote 21 The bank credit standards indicator is shown by dashed lines. Note that it is multiplied by $-1$ , standardized and rescaled to have the same mean and standard deviation as the changes in $\hat{\chi }_t$ . Our financial conditions variable constructed from the theoretical model is quite good at tracking alternative measures of borrowing constraints for firms in the euro area big four. In particular, all three measures indicate a sharp deterioration in borrowing conditions during the Great Recession.

Figure 4. Constructed financial conditions variable and alternative indicators. Note: Upper panel: The solid line depicts the level series of $\hat{\chi }_t$ . The dashed line depicts the quarterly averages of the monthly series for the credit spread index as provided by Gilchrist and Mojon (Reference Gilchrist and Mojon2018). The credit spread index is multiplied by $-1$ , standardized and rescaled to have the same mean and standard deviation as $\hat{\chi }_t$ . Lower panel: The solid line depicts the series of the one-period changes in $\hat{\chi }_t$ . The dashed line depicts the weighted average of the national diffusion indices of the net tightening of bank credit standards for loans to non-financial corporations for the four largest euro area countries. The series for the change in bank credit standards is multiplied by $-1$ , standardized and rescaled to have the same mean and standard deviation as the changes in $\hat{\chi }_t$ . The shaded areas in the upper and lower panel indicate Center for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) recession dates for the euro area as a whole.

3.2 Estimation results from the SVAR

In this section, we examine the macroeconomic effects of exogenous financial shocks. We do so by introducing the constructed financial conditions variable into a SVAR that comprises the following variables: output, household consumption, tangible investment, and intangible investment. The SVAR takes the following form:

(22) \begin{align} A \begin{bmatrix} \hat{Y}_t \\ \\[-9pt]\hat{C}_{t} \\ \\[-9pt]\hat{I}_{T,t} \\ \\[-9pt]\hat{I}_{I,t} \\ \\[-9pt]\hat{\chi }_t \end{bmatrix} = B(L) \begin{bmatrix} \hat{Y}_{t-1} \\ \\[-9pt]\hat{C}_{t-1} \\ \\[-9pt]\hat{I}_{T,t-1} \\ \\[-9pt]\hat{I}_{I,t-1} \\ \\[-9pt]\hat{\chi }_{t-1} \end{bmatrix} + u_t, \end{align}

where the factor $B(L)$ denotes a lag polynomial, with $L$ denoting the lag operator, $A$ and $B_i$ are $5\times 5$ matrices of coefficients, and $u_t$ is a mean-zero, serially uncorrelated $5\times 1$ vector of stochastic disturbances with a diagonal variance-covariance matrix. To estimate the SVAR, we use aggregated national accounts data from France, Germany, Italy, and Spain, which we obtain from Eurostat’s national accounts database. We measure output as total GDP, household consumption as final consumption of households and nonprofit institutions serving households, tangible investment as machinery and equipment investment plus nonresidential construction investment and intangible investment as investment in intellectual property products. All data are seasonally adjusted, expressed in real terms and detrended in logs using the same detrending procedure used for the construction of the $\hat{\chi }_t$ series. Following the related literature (see, e.g. Lown and Morgan (Reference Lown and Morgan2006), Gilchrist and Zakrajsek (Reference Gilchrist and Zakrajsek2012), and Walentin (Reference Walentin2014)), we identify financial shocks by applying a recursive identification scheme. That is, we assume that financial shocks affect real economy variables only with a time lag, while shocks to real economy variables impact the financial conditions variable contemporaneously. We implement these restrictions by requiring the matrix $A$ to be an unit lower triangular matrix. The SVAR is estimated over the sample from 1999.Q1 to 2018.Q4. Note that the SVAR features a constant and two lags of each variable.

Figure 5 presents the impulse response functions of all variables included in the SVAR to a negative one standard deviation financial shock. The solid lines correspond to the point estimates, and the shaded areas indicate one and two standard deviations confidence intervals, which we obtain from $2000$ bootstrap replications. As can be seen, a negative financial shock causes a significant hump-shaped reduction in the aggregate quantities as well as the constructed financial conditions variable. GDP bottoms out around $0.4$ % below trend around one year after the shock. The fall in household consumption is somewhat less pronounced in terms of amplitude than the decline in output, while the contraction in tangible investment is relatively large. The fall in intangible investment is much smaller at the peak than the decline in tangible investment. The shock also causes a gradual decline in the financial conditions variable, which bottoms out after about one year and reverts to the trend after about four years. Overall, the results suggest that financial shocks lead to economically meaningful and statistically significant declines in output, household consumption, and the two investment aggregates. Importantly, tangible and intangible investment co-move positively in response to the financial shock, with intangible investment declining much less than tangible investment. Note that these results are robust to the specification of additional lags, the use of alternative detrending methods and the introduction of additional variables.Footnote 22 In addition, these results are in line with what Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019) find for the US. In particular, they report that intangible investment roughly drops by only half as much as tangible investment does in response to a debt financing shock.

Figure 5. SVAR- and model-based impulse response functions. Note: The figure displays SVAR- and model-based impulse responses to a negative one standard deviation financial shock. The solid lines are SVAR-based impulse responses and the dashed lines are model-based impulse responses (see Section (4)). The shaded areas denote the one and two standard-deviations confidence intervals around the SVAR-based estimates based on $2{,}000$ bootstrap replications.

Table 1 depicts the amount of variation in the variables included in the SVAR explained by the identified financial shock. The financial shock accounts for a significant fraction of the variation in output, household consumption, tangible investment, and intangible investment. The finding that the financial shock is an important source of variation in intangible investment is consistent with the view that the collateral constraint implies quantitatively important spill over effects from tangible to intangible investment. For the US, Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019) argue that debt financing shocks are more important for variations in tangible investment compared to intangible investment. The structural differences between euro area and US debt and equity markets may be responsible for the divergent outcomes. Interestingly, we find that up to around 60% of the variation in the constructed financial conditions variable is due to the financial shock itself. Hence, a large part of the variation in the constructed financial conditions series is not due to exogenous shifts but, rather, reflects other shocks.

Table 1. Percentage variance due to financial shocks

Note: The table displays SVAR-based variance decompositions from a one standard deviation financial shock. The numbers in square brackets denote the boundaries of the associated 95% confidence interval.

4. Bayesian impulse response matching

In this section, we estimate the theoretical model by using a Bayesian variant of the standard impulse response matching procedure discussed in Rotemberg and Woodford (Reference Rotemberg, Rotemberg and Woodford1997) and Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans2005), which minimizes the weighted distance between the theoretical and empirical impulse response functions. The particular Bayesian variant that we use is developed in Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Trabandt, Walentin, Christiano, Trabandt and Walentin2010) and applied in other papers (see, e.g. Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Trabandt2015, Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Trabandt2016)). Hence, here, we start by presenting the calibrated parameters and the driving process for $\hat{\chi }_t$ .Footnote 23 Next, we describe the prior and posterior distributions of the estimated parameters and investigate the ability of the model to account for the empirical evidence on the macroeconomic effects of financial shocks.

4.1 Calibrated model parameters and driving process for the financial conditions variable

Table 2 provides an overview of the calibrated model parameters. These parameters pertain to the steady-state values of observable variables in the model and can therefore be set with steady-state targets.Footnote 24 We set $\beta =0.995$ , which implies a steady-state annual real interest rate of $2\%$ . The labor disutility parameter, $\nu$ , is set in such a way that the steady-state labor supply is equal to $0.3$ .Footnote 25 We choose the intangible capital income share parameter, $\alpha _{K_I}$ , to have a steady state share of intangible investment in output of $\frac{I_I}{Y}=0.035$ , which is equal to the observed average share of investment in intellectual property products in total GDP for the euro area big four for the period from 1999.Q1 to 2018.Q4. The tangible capital income share parameter, $\alpha _{K_T}$ , is set so as to have a steady state share of labor income in output of $\frac{WN}{Y}=0.64$ . The tax wedge, $\tau$ , is set to $0.3$ . The depreciation rate of tangible capital, $\delta _T$ , is $0.025$ . As for the depreciation rate of intangible capital, $\delta _I$ , we set $\delta _I=0.05$ , which implies an annual depreciation rate of $20\%$ . This magnitude of $\delta _I$ reflects the assumption that intangible assets depreciate faster overall than tangible assets and roughly matches the unweighted average of the annual depreciation rates of R&D ( $15\%$ ), mineral exploration ( $7.5\%$ ), and computer software and databases ( $32\%$ ) as provided in Corrado et al. (Reference Corrado, Haskel, Jona-Lasinio and Iommi2018). We set the steady-state value of $\chi _t$ to have the steady-state end-of-period debt-to-output ratio equal to $\frac{B^e}{Y}=3.3$ , which matches the observed average ratio of the end-of-period debt of nonfinancial corporations over total GDP for the four largest economies of the euro area as a whole for the period from 1999.Q1 to 2018.Q4. Given the values for $\chi$ , $\beta$ , $\frac{{W}{N}}{Y}$ , $\frac{I_I}{Y}$ , $\tau$ , $\delta _T$ , $\delta _I$ , and $\frac{B^e}{Y}$ , the steady-state end-of-period tangible capital-to-output ratio is $\frac{K^e_T}{Y}=11$ . Turning to the assumed driving process for the financial conditions variable, we consider a process with feedback effects from other variables, as in the empirical model. More specifically, we assume that the driving process for $\hat{\chi }_t$ in the theoretical model is identical to the last equation of the SVAR system, which reads:Footnote 26

(23) \begin{align} A^5 \begin{bmatrix} \hat{Y}_t \\ \hat{C}_{t} \\ \hat{I}_{T,t} \\ \hat{I}_{I,t} \\ \hat{\chi }_t \end{bmatrix} = B_0^5 \begin{bmatrix} \hat{Y}_{t-1} \\ \hat{C}_{t-1} \\ \hat{I}_{T,t-1} \\ \hat{I}_{I,t-1} \\ \hat{\chi }_{t-1} \end{bmatrix} + B_1^5 \begin{bmatrix} \hat{Y}_{t-2} \\ \hat{C}_{t-2} \\ \hat{I}_{T,t-2} \\ \hat{I}_{I,t-2} \\ \hat{\chi }_{t-2} \end{bmatrix}+ u_{{\chi },t}, \end{align}

where $A^5$ , $B^5_0$ , and $B^5_1$ are $5\times 1$ row vectors of coefficients that correspond to the 5th row of the matrices $A$ , $B_0$ , and $B_1$ , respectively, and $u_{{\chi },t}$ is the financial shock. Note that this implies that the theoretical model includes the same feedback effects between the financial conditions variable and the real economy variables as given in the SVAR. However, the dynamic behavior of the real economy variables is dictated by the mechanisms embedded in the theoretical model. As a result, the theoretical and the empirical responses of the financial conditions variable to a financial shock are not necessarily identical (see also Ravn et al. (Reference Ravn, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe2012)). The standard deviation of the financial shock, which is also obtained from the SVAR, is set to $\sigma _{u_{\chi }}=0.0014$ .

Table 2. Calibrated model parameters

4.2 Prior and posterior distributions

In the upper half of Table 3, we present the prior distributions of the estimated parameters. We assume that the habit formation parameter, $\epsilon$ , follows a beta distribution. We choose a prior mean of $0.7$ and a standard deviation equal to $0.1$ . The equity payout cost parameter, $\kappa$ , is assumed to follow an inverse gamma distribution and is centered at $0.2$ , as in Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012). The prior probabilities of the investment adjustment cost parameters, $\phi _T$ and $\phi _I$ , are gamma distributions. We set the prior means to $4$ and the standard deviations to $2$ . Hence, we do not force intangible investment to be more persistent than tangible investment and allow for a large parameter domain.

Table 3. Prior and posterior distributions of model parameters

Note: Posterior distributions of model parameters are obtained using the Metropolis-Hastings algorithm with 500,000 draws and a burn-in of 25%. The acceptance rate is 30%.

The lower half of Table 3 reports the posterior mode, mean, and 95% probability intervals for the estimated parameters. We obtain a posterior mean of $0.87$ for the habit formation parameter, implying that household consumption adjusts very slowly to financial shocks. The posterior mean of $\kappa$ is $0.6$ . This value is larger than the value for the US as estimated in Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012). Turning to the investment adjustment cost parameters, we find that the posterior estimates of $\phi _T$ and $\phi _I$ are significantly different from zero, confirming that investment adjustment costs are an important feature of the model for capturing the empirical persistence of both tangible and intangible investment. Interestingly, the posterior mean of the adjustment cost parameter for intangible investment is much higher than that for tangible investment, even though we set the same prior means. Specifically, the posterior mean of $\phi _I$ implies an estimate of the elasticity of intangible investment with respect to a 1% temporary increase in the current price of installed intangible capital of $0.1$ . The corresponding elasticity for tangible investment is found to be $0.5$ . These elasticities are close to those implied by the estimates for the US reported in Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019), who use R&D investment from the national accounts to proxy intangible investment. The finding that intangible investment adjusts much more slowly to its costs than is the case for tangible investment is also fully in accord with what is obtained in the finance literature, as found in Peters and Taylor (Reference Peters and Taylor2017). In addition, the finding is in line with the estimates presented in Chiavari and Sampreet (Reference Chiavari and Sampreet2021), who report higher adjustment costs for intangibles compared to tangible investment. In the literature, many argue that intangible capital (in particular R&D capital) has high adjustment costs and possibly much higher adjustment costs than tangible capital (see, e.g. Himmelberg and Petersen (Reference Himmelberg and Petersen1994), Hall (Reference Hall2002) and Brown et al. (Reference Brown, Fazzari and Petersen2009)), because adjusting intangible capital typically involves adjusting the number of highly educated employees, who have high searching, training or replacement costs. Our estimation results are consistent with this view. Overall, we find that the priors and posteriors are quite different, suggesting that the data are informative about the model’s parameters. Given the relatively large posterior estimates for the habit formation parameter, $\epsilon$ , and the equity payout costs parameter, $\kappa$ , we have performed a sensitivity analysis with respect to these parameters. We found that the posterior estimates for the investment adjustment cost parameters, $\phi _T$ and $\phi _I$ , are not particularly sensitive to lower values of $\epsilon$ and $\kappa$ .

4.3 Model-implied impulse response functions

Figure 5 depicts with dashed lines the model-implied impulse response functions of output, household consumption, tangible investment, intangible investment, and the constructed financial conditions variable to a negative one standard deviation financial shock. As can be seen from the figure, the theoretical model does well at reproducing the observed transmission of financial shocks based on the SVAR results. The model accounts for the hump-shaped reduction in the real economic quantities as well as the constructed financial conditions variable. Most of the model responses are close to the point estimates from the SVAR; and almost all model responses lie within the one standard deviation confidence intervals around the SVAR-based estimates. Importantly, the model predicts a strong fall in tangible investment and a relatively small decline in intangible investment. As explained above, this positive co-movement between tangible and intangible investment as well as the relative resilience of intangible investment poses a challenge for a model without costly capital accumulation.

5. Modeling the responses of tangible and intangible investment during the Great Recession

In this section, we study the dynamics for tangible and intangible investment implied by our model for the period of the Great Recession. To do so, we feed the series of the identified financial shocks from the SVAR into the theoretical model and compute the responses of tangible and intangible investment.

In Figure 6, we recover the series of the identified financial shocks from the SVAR estimated in Section 3. As can be seen, a sequence of large negative disturbances occur prior to and during the Great Recession. Note that the largest negative shock (i.e. -2.4 standard deviations) arises in 2008.Q1, which according to the CEPR marks the peak of the economic expansion in the euro area as a whole before the Great Recession.

Figure 6. Identified financial shocks. Note: The figure displays the series for the identified financial shocks from the SVAR expressed in terms of standard deviations. The standard deviation is $0.13$ basis points. The shaded areas indicate Center for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) recession dates for the euro area as a whole.

The model-implied dynamics for tangible and intangible investment induced by the series of the identified financial shocks from the SVAR are shown for the Great Recession period in Figure 7. We illustrate the corresponding empirical measurements in the same figure to facilitate a visual test of how well the model fits the empirical data. For a description of how the empirical measurements for tangible and intangible investment are constructed see the footnote of Figure 1. The vertical lines represent 2008.Q1. As can be seen from the figure, the model replicates quite well the relative resilience of intangible investment to the Great Recession observed in the data. The model responses for both tangible investment and intangible investment fell below the trend during the period of the Great Recession, whereby intangible investment declined by much less than tangible investment. We observe similar dynamics in the data. Viewed through the lens of our model, the relative resilience of intangible investment to the Great Recession seems to be due to the relative large costs associated with changing intangible investment. According to our model, when confronted with an adverse financial shock, firms attempt to maintain their investment in intangible capital by reducing their investment in tangible capital in order to minimize adjustment costs. Hence, the Great Recession, which according to the results from the SVAR can be associated with a sequence of large negative financial shocks, had a much smaller impact on intangible investment than on tangible investment. Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019) report for the Great Recession that debt financing shocks largely fail to explain the evolution of intangible investment, which constitutes a notable difference between the US and the euro area against the backdrop of our findings. Consistent with the results reported in Table 1, we find in this computation that debt financing shocks matter. While our model accounts very well for the relatively modest decline in intangible investment during the Great Recession, it is also clearly evident from the figure that the drop in tangible investment generated by the model is much smaller than in the data. This result comes as no surprise, since we would not expect our model to match all the variation in the data perfectly. However, the result is interesting insofar as it points to a further asymmetry in the behavior of tangible and intangible investment during the Great Recession beyond that identified in this paper.

Figure 7. Impact of the Great Recession on tangible and intangible investment. Note: The figure displays the responses of tangible and intangible investment around and during the Great Recession. The dashed lines correspond to the model responses induced by the series of the identified financial shocks from the SVAR. The solid lines represent the corresponding empirical series. For a description of how the empirical measurements for tangible and intangible investment are constructed see the footnote of Figure 1. The vertical lines represent 2008.Q1.

6. Conclusion

We investigate the effects of financial shocks on the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment using an extended RBC model with financially constrained firms, pledgeable tangible capital, and nonpledgeable intangible capital. We show that, within this framework, the presence of adjustment costs in the accumulation process for tangible and intangible capital plays a crucial role in the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment in response to financial shocks.

Based on a model-consistent series for firms’ borrowing conditions, we identify within an SVAR framework the effects of financial shocks on tangible and intangible investment in the four largest euro area economies as a whole. We find that an adverse financial shock leads to a sharper fall in tangible investment than in intangible investment.

The estimation of the theoretical model adopting a Bayesian limited information approach provides evidence in favor of relatively high adjustment costs for intangible investment compared to those for tangible investment. This is consistent with what is obtained in the finance literature, as reported in Peters and Taylor (Reference Peters and Taylor2017) and Chiavari and Sampreet (Reference Chiavari and Sampreet2021). The estimated model replicates well the empirical impulse responses of the aggregate quantities. Importantly, the model predicts a relatively sharp decline in tangible investment in response to an adverse financial shock, whereas intangible investment falls much less than tangible investment.

We show that the relative large adjustment costs for intangible investment are crucial to the model’s success in replicating the empirical dynamics of tangible and intangible investment in the aftermath of an adverse financial shock. When it is assumed that adjusting tangible and intangible capital is without costs, it is optimal for the firm to shift resources toward pledgeable tangible capital and away from nonpledgeable intangible capital. Hence, tangible investment and intangible investment co-move negatively in response to the shock. The presence of investment adjustment costs alters the firm’s incentives such that the firm reduces tangible investment along with intangible investment. Intuitively, when it is much more costly to adjust intangible investment than to adjust tangible investment, the firm reduces tangible investment to a larger extent than it does intangible investment. Our modeling approach is deliberately parsimonious in order to put forward this particular feature of the model in generating a positive co-movement between tangible and intangible investment as well as a relatively resilient reaction of intangible investment in response to a financial shock.

A. Appendix

A.1 Sensitivity analysis

In this section, we focus on the procedure used to extract the business cycle components of the data. In Figure 1, we use a one-sided HP filter with a smoothing parameter of $\lambda =1600$ . Here, we replace this detrending procedure by applying a quadratic trend. Figure 8 shows the log-deviations from trend for both tangible and intangible investment in the euro area’s big four economies as a whole obtained after removing a quadratic trend. Comparing this figure with Figure 1, it can be seen that the relative dynamics of tangible and intangible investment are quite similar to those obtained using the one-sided HP filter. In particular, tangible and intangible investment co-move positively during the Great Recession, while the drop in intangible investment is much smaller than the one in tangible investment. This suggests that intangible investment reacts much less strongly to financial shocks than tangible investment does.

Figure 8. Tangible and intangible investment. Note: The figure displays tangible and intangible investment in the four largest euro area countries as a whole, as derived from Eurostat’s national accounts data. Tangible investment is measured as machinery and equipment investment plus non-residential construction investment. Intangible investment is investment in intellectual property products. All data are seasonally adjusted, expressed in real terms and detrended in logs by applying a quadratic trend. The shaded areas indicate Center for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) recession dates for the euro area as a whole.

A.2 Data description

Here, we provide further details on the data used in the paper. Note that all data are derived by means of aggregation based on quarterly national and financial accounts data for the four largest euro area economies in terms of output (i.e. France, Germany, Italy, and Spain). The national accounts data are obtained from Eurostat in nominal seasonally adjusted terms. We convert all nominal variables into real variables using an aggregate GDP deflator, which is a weighted average of the national GDP deflators. We measure output as total GDP, household consumption as final consumption of households and non-profit institutions serving households, tangible investment as machinery and equipment investment plus non-residential construction investment, and intangible investment as investments in intellectual property products. According to the current accounting standard, the latter cover expenditures on research and development (R&D), mineral exploration and evaluation, computer software and databases, entertainment, literary and artistic originals. Note that Eurostat publishes quarterly data for total investments in intellectual property products but not for the individual components. The source of the financial accounts data is the ECB. This data are not adjusted for seasonal variation. We apply the Census X-12 filter to seasonally adjust the data. The national diffusion indices of the change in bank credit standards for loans to non-financial corporations come from the ECB’s Bank Lending Survey. The data on MFI loans are taken from the ECB database. The series of the credit spreads for non-financial corporations in the four largest euro area countries a whole is provided in monthly terms by Gilchrist and Mojon (Reference Gilchrist and Mojon2018). We convert the monthly data to quarterly data by taking 3-month averages.

A.3 Steady state

Here, we list the steady state relations of the theoretical model. The time subscripts are dropped from all variables, because the variables are constant in the steady state. We set the steady state labor supply to $N=0.3$ and the steady state share of labor income in output to $\frac{WN}{Y}=0.64$ . The steady state end-of-period debt-to-output ratio, $\frac{B^e}{Y}$ , and the steady state intangible investment-to-output ratio, $\frac{I_{I}}{Y}$ , are set to $3.3$ and $0.035$ , respectively.

Effective gross interest rate:

(24) \begin{equation} R = \frac{1-\tau }{\beta }+\tau. \end{equation}

Multiplier for the borrowing constraint:

(25) \begin{equation} \mu =\frac{1-R\beta }{\chi }\frac{R-\tau }{R(1-\tau )}. \end{equation}

Output:

(26) \begin{equation} Y=\left (\left (\frac{\alpha _{K_T}(1-\mu )}{\frac{1-{\chi }{\mu }}{\beta }-(1-\delta _T)}\right )^{\alpha _{K_T}}\left (\frac{\alpha _{K_I}(1-\mu )}{\frac{1-{\chi }{\mu \lambda _I}}{\beta }-(1-\delta _I)}\right )^{\alpha _{K_I}}N^{1-\alpha _{K_T}-\alpha _{K_I}}\right )^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha _{K_T}-\alpha _{K_I}}}. \end{equation}

Tangible capital:

(27) \begin{equation} K_{T}=\frac{\alpha _{K_T}(1-\mu ){Y}}{\frac{1-{\chi }{\mu }}{\beta }-(1-\delta _T)}. \end{equation}

Intangible capital:

(28) \begin{equation} K_{I}=\frac{\alpha _{K_I}(1-\mu ){Y}}{\frac{{1-{\chi \lambda _I}{\mu }}}{\beta }-(1-\delta _I)}. \end{equation}

Investment in capital of type $j$ :

(29) \begin{equation} I_{j}=\delta _{j}K_{j},\quad \text{for}\quad j={T,I}. \end{equation}

Current price of installed capital of type $j$ :

(30) \begin{equation} Q_{j}=1,\quad \text{for}\quad j={T,I}. \end{equation}

Wage rate:

(31) \begin{equation} W=\frac{(1-\alpha _{K_T}-\alpha _{K_I})(1-\mu ){Y}}{N}. \end{equation}

Intertemporal debt:

(32) \begin{equation} B=\frac{R-\tau }{1-\tau }\left (K_{T}+\lambda _IK_{I}-\frac{Y}{\chi }\right ). \end{equation}

Equity payout:

(33) \begin{equation} D=Y+B\left (\frac{1}{R}-1\right )-WN-\delta _{T}K_{T}-\delta _{I}K_{I}. \end{equation}

Household consumption:

(34) \begin{equation} C=B\left (1-\frac{1}{R}\right )+WN+D. \end{equation}

Tangible capital income share:

(35) \begin{equation} \alpha _{K_T}=1-\alpha _{K_I}-\frac{WN}{Y}\frac{1}{1-\mu }. \end{equation}

Intangible capital income share:

(36) \begin{equation} \alpha _{K_I}=\frac{I_{I}}{Y}\frac{\frac{1-\mu \lambda _I\chi }{\beta }-(1-\delta _I)}{(1-\mu )\delta _I}. \end{equation}

Labor disutility parameter:

(37) \begin{equation} \nu =\frac{(1-N)W}{(1-\epsilon )C}. \end{equation}

By rearranging equation (27), we obtain the steady state ratio of tangible capital to output:

(38) \begin{equation} \frac{K_{T}}{Y}=\frac{\alpha _{K_T}(1-\mu )}{\frac{1-\chi \mu }{\beta }-(1-\delta _T)}. \end{equation}

Combining this with equation (32), we have

(39) \begin{equation} \frac{B^e}{Y}-\frac{\alpha _{K_T}(1-\mu )}{\frac{1-\chi \mu }{\beta }-(1-\delta _T)}-\lambda _I\frac{\alpha _{K_I}(1-\mu )}{\frac{1-\chi \lambda _I\mu }{\beta }-(1-\delta _I)}+\frac{1}{\chi }=0, \end{equation}

where $\frac{B^e}{Y}\equiv \frac{B}{Y}\frac{1-\tau }{R-\tau }$ is the end-of-period debt-to-output ratio. Given the values for $\beta$ , $\frac{{W}{N}}{Y}$ , $\frac{I_I}{Y}$ , $\tau$ , $\delta _T$ , $\delta _I$ , $\lambda _I$ as well as $\frac{B^e}{Y}$ and using equations (24), (25), (35) and (36), we can numerically solve this expression for the value of $\chi$ .

Footnotes

The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank or the Eurosystem.

1 Important examples are Nolan and Thoenissen (Reference Nolan and Thoenissen2009) and Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012).

2 Investments in intellectual property products accounted for about 20% of total gross fixed capital formation in the big four euro area countries in 2018. Around 50% of these investments consisted of R&D.

3 See Appendix A.1 for a sensitivity analysis.

4 The INTAN-Invest database covers the business sector and allows for a broader measurement of intangible investment by including expenditures for design, branding, new financial products, organizational capital, and firm-specific training. Such expenditures are currently treated as intermediate costs in national accounts. As reported in Corrado et al. (Reference Corrado, Haskel, Jona-Lasinio and Iommi2018), the share of intangible investment in GDP increases by a large amount when including the above mentioned items. For France, the intangible to GDP ratio increases from 4.2% to 8.7%, for Germany from 2.8% to 5.9%, for Italy from 1.9% to 5.3%, and for Spain from 2.1% to 4.8%. As part of our analysis in Section (2.3), we explain the effects of switching from low to high intangible investment ratios as a robustness check.

5 This result also remains in a sensitivity analysis if we take into account limited collateralizability of intangible capital.

6 More specifically, we follow the standard modeling approach of Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans2005) and assume that it is costly for firms to change the levels of tangible and intangible investment between periods.

7 Given the strand of literature on which we built our paper, in particular, Lopez and Olivella (Reference Lopez and Olivella2018) and Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019), we abstract from modeling a cash hoarding channel.

8 For a full discussion see Eisfeldt et al. (Reference Eisfeldt, Falato and Xiaolan2018), Sun and Xiaolan (Reference Sun and Xiaolan2019) and Döttling, Ladika, and Perotti (2020).

9 This pertains in particular to investment in intellectual property products, for which data for Belgium and Cyprus are not available. Moreover, existing data for the Netherlands and Ireland are heavily influenced by the relocation of intellectual property products of large multinational companies and complicate the economic analysis for the euro area as a whole.

10 More specifically, as the firm has all the bargaining power, it must apply that the going concern value is higher than the anticipated value of cash flows to creditors in the two states. Thus, from the perspective of the firm, it needs to hold that $Em_{t+1}V_{t+1} \geq L_t + Em_{t+1}V_{t+1}-\chi _t \!\left (K_{T,t+1}+\lambda _IK_{I,t+1}- \frac{B_{t+1}}{1+r_t} \right )$ , where $V_{t+1}$ denotes the cum-dividend market value of the firm and $m_{t+1}$ is the stochastic discount factor.

11 When we estimate the model, we set $\lambda _I=0$ .

12 The borrowing constraint is always satisfied with equality in the steady state. The assumption that this condition continues to hold in the neighborhood of the steady state allows us to solve the model with a log-linear approximation.

13 This specification of the information set is in line with the restrictions for the identification of financial shocks in the SVAR (see Section 3). It implies that decisions in period $t$ are made before the realization of the shock.

14 Note that, in the tradition of Smets and Wouters (Reference Smets and Wouters2003), we define Tobin’s $Q_{j,t}$ as the ratio of the Lagrangian of the capital accumulation equation and the Lagrangian of the flow of funds constraint $\frac{\lambda ^{K_j}_t}{\lambda ^{B}_t}$ , for $j=T,I$ with $\lambda ^{B}_t=\frac{1}{\varphi^{\prime}(D_t)}$ . $Q_{j,t}$ thus reflects the supply price of capital $\lambda ^{K,j}_t$ relative to the reproduction costs of capital $\lambda ^{B}_t$ . In steady state, we set $Q_j=1$ , for $j=T,I$ .

15 For the sake of argument, we assume here that the financial conditions variable follows an exogenous first-order autoregressive process. More formally, the assumed process is given (in logs) by $\textrm{log}(\chi _t)=(1-\rho _{\chi })\textrm{log}({\chi })+\rho _{\chi }\textrm{log}(\chi _{t-1})+u_{{\chi },t}$ , where $\chi$ is the steady-state value of $\chi _t$ and $u_{{\chi },t}$ is a zero-mean, serially uncorrelated stochastic disturbance with standard deviation $\sigma _{u_{\chi }}$ . We set $\rho _{\chi }=0.95$ and $\sigma _{u_{\chi }}=0.002$ in order to model a persistent and economically meaningful impact of the financial shock. Note that, when we estimate the theoretical model, we consider a driving process with feedback effects from other variables, as in the empirical model (see Section 4).

16 Note that the joint determination of tangible and intangible investment within the same firm is key to trigger and understand the co-movement problem between tangible and intangible investment. If firms are divided into two sectors, one producing tangibles and the other produces intangibles, the co-movement problem is solved by assumption. However, given the strand of literature on which we built our paper, in particular, Lopez and Olivella (Reference Lopez and Olivella2018) and Bianchi et al. (Reference Bianchi, Kung and Morales2019), we choose to model the joint determination of tangible and intangible investment within the same firm. In addition, the two-sector approach also requires adjustment costs in investment to replicate the hump-shaped responses from the SVAR. This means that although the two-sector approach solves the co-movement problem, it fails to replicate the data sufficiently in the absence of investment adjustment costs.

17 Throughout the paper, we detrend the data by taking logs and applying a one-sided HP filter with a smoothing parameter of $\lambda =1600$ . We implement the one-sided HP filter as discussed in Stock and Watson (Reference Stock and Watson1999).

18 We use the cumulative sum of flows rather than the series for the published stocks to remove the impact of any changes in the published stocks that do not arise from transactions.

19 The empirical series for output as well as tangible investment are available as of 1995.Q1. Hence, we started the iteration process for the construction of the $K^e_{T,t}$ series from 1995.Q1.

20 Appendix A.2 provides further details on the data used in the paper.

21 The national diffusion indices are obtained from the ECB’s Bank Lending Survey (BLS), which was not introduced until 2003. They each measure the weighted difference between the percentage of banks reporting that credit standards have tightened over the past three months and the percentage of banks reporting that they have been eased. We aggregate the national results using a weighting scheme based on the national percentage shares in the outstanding amount of loans (all maturities) from monetary financial institutions (MFIs, excluding the Eurosystem) to euro area nonfinancial corporations (see Scopel et al. (Reference Scopel, Hempell and Köhler-Ulbrich2016)).

22 Note that our results are robust to the inclusion of monetary variables. When we include monetary variables in the SVAR, such as the shadow rate for the euro area as provided by Wu and Xia (Reference Wu and Xia2017) and the euro area HICP inflation rate, the point estimates of the impulse responses for tangible and intangible investment as well as the point estimates for the financial conditions index are located within the reported one standard deviation tunnel of our baseline specification. Thus, the reported impulse responses do not significantly change when monetary variables are included.

23 The estimation strategy borrowed from Jermann and Quadrini (Reference Jermann and Quadrini2012) is explicitly designed to avoid circularity. For example, the steady-state value of the capital-to-output ratio $\frac{K^{e}_T}{Y}$ and the depreciation rate $\delta _T$ , which serves as inputs to the perpetual inventory method to construct the financial condition series $\chi _t$ , are independent of the estimated parameters of the model. In other words, any adjustment to the estimated parameters, for example, the investment adjustment cost parameters, does not affect the constructed financial conditions index.

24 For details on the calculation of the steady state, see Appendix A.3.

25 The labor disutility parameter, $\nu$ , depends on the habit persistence parameter, $\epsilon$ , which is determined during the impulse response matching procedure. That is, during the estimation, we update $\nu$ for every parameter draw such that the steady-state labor supply is equal to $0.3$ . In Table 2, we report the value for $\nu$ based on the posterior mean of $\epsilon$ .

26 This approach is adopted from Ravn et al. (Reference Ravn, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe2012), who study the transmission of government spending shocks in a two-country model with deep habits.

References

Bates, T. W., Kahle, K. M. and Stulz, R. M. (2009) Why do U.S. firms hold so much more cash than they used to? Journal of Finance 64(5), 19852021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bianchi, F., Kung, H. and Morales, G. (2019) Growth, slowdowns, and recoveries. Journal of Monetary Economics 101(2), 4763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brav, A., Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R. and Michaely, R. (2005) Payout policy in the 21st century. Journal of Financial Economics 77(3), 483527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, J. R., Fazzari, S. M. and Petersen, B. C. (2009) Financing innovation and growth: Cash flow, external equity, and the 1990s R&D boom. The Journal of Finance 64(1), 151185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caggese, A. and Ander, P. (2020) How stimulative are low real interest rates for intangible capital? Technical report.Google Scholar
Chiavari, A. and Sampreet, G. (2021) The rise of intangible capital and the macroeconomic implications. Technical report.Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. S. and Evans, C. L. (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113(1), 145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. S. and Trabandt, M. (2015) Understanding the great recession. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7(1), 110167.Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. S. and Trabandt, M. (2016) Unemployment and business cycles. Econometrica 84(4), 15231569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Trabandt, M. and Walentin, K. (2010) DSGE models for monetary policy analysis. In: Christiano, L. J., Trabandt, M. and Walentin, K..(eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 3, pp. 285367, Elsevier.Google Scholar
Corrado, C., Haskel, J., Jona-Lasinio, C. and Iommi, M. (2018) Intangible investment in the EU and US before and since the great recession and its contribution to productivity growth. Journal of Infrastructure, Policy and Development 2(1), 1136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crouzet, N. and Eberly, J. C. (2019) Understanding weak capital investment: The role of market concentration and intangibles, National Bureau of Economic Research., Working Paper 25869.Google Scholar
Döttling, R. T. L. and Perotti, E. C. (2020) Creating intangible capital, Available at SSRN 3479152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Döttling, R. and Ratnovski, L. (2020) Monetary policy and intangible investment, Working Paper Series 2444, European Central Bank.Google Scholar
Eisfeldt, A., Falato, A. and Xiaolan, M. Z. (2018) The rise of human capitalist. In: 2018 Meeting Papers 1110, Society for Economic Dynamics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falato, A., Kadyrzhanova, D. and Sim, J. W. (2013) Rising intangible capital, shrinking debt capacity, and the US corporate savings glut, Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2013-67, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilchrist, S. and Mojon, B. (2018) Credit risk in the euro area. Economic Journal 128(608), 118158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilchrist, S. and Zakrajsek, E. (2012) Credit spreads and business cycle fluctuations. American Economic Review 102(4), 16921720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, B. H. (2002) The financing of research and development. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 18(1), 3551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hennessy, C. A. and Whited, T. M. (2005) Debt dynamics. The Journal of Finance 60(3), 11291165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Himmelberg, C. P. and Petersen, B. C. (1994) R&D and internal finance: A panel study of small firms in high-tech industries. The Review of Economics and Statistics 76(1), 3851.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jermann, U. and Quadrini, V. (2012) Macroeconomic effects of financial shocks. American Economic Review 102(1), 238271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lintner, J. (1956) Distribution of incomes of corporations among dividends, retained earnings, and taxes. American Economic Review 46(2), 97113.Google Scholar
Lopez, J. I. and Olivella, V. (2018) The importance of intangible capital for the transmission of financial shocks. Review of Economic Dynamics 30(5), 223238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loumioti, M. (2012) The use of intangible assets as loan collateral, Available at SSRN 1748675.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lown, C. and Morgan, D. P. (2006) The credit cycle and the business cycle: New findings using the loan officer opinion survey. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38(6), 15751597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malik, K. Z., Ali, S. Z. and Khalid, A. M. (2014) Intangible capital in a real business cycle model. Economic Modelling 39(C), 3248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGrattan, E. R. and Prescott, E. C. (2010) Unmeasured investment and the puzzling US boom in the 1990s. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2(4), 88123.Google Scholar
Nolan, C. and Thoenissen, C. (2009) Financial shocks and the US business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 56(4), 596604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, R. H. and Taylor, L. A. (2017) Intangible capital and the investment-q relation. Journal of Financial Economics 123(2), 251272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rampini, A. A. and Viswanathan, S. (2013) Collateral and capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics 109(2), 466492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ravn, M. O., Schmitt-Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2012) Consumption, government spending, and the real exchange rate. Journal of Monetary Economics 59(3), 215234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, J. J. and MWoodford. (1997) An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy. In: Rotemberg, J. J. and Woodford, M. (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 12, pp. 297361, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Scopel, S., Hempell, H. S. and Köhler-Ulbrich, P. (2016) The euro area bank lending survey, European Central Bank, Occasional Paper Series 179.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. W. (1992) Liquidation values and debt capacity: A market equilibrium approach. The Journal of Finance 47(4), 13431366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sibilkov, V. (2009) Asset liquidity and capital structure. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 44(5), 11731196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2003) An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association 1(5), 11231175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. W. (1999) Forecasting inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics 44(2), 293335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sun, Q. and Xiaolan, M. Z. (2019) Financing intangible capital. Journal of Financial Economics 133(3), 564588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walentin, K. (2014) Business cycle implications of mortgage spreads. Journal of Monetary Economics 67(2), 6277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, J. C. and Xia, F. D. (2017) Time-varying lower bound of interest rates in Europe, Chicago Booth, Technical Report 17-06.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Tangible and intangible investment. Note: The figure displays tangible and intangible investment in the four largest euro area countries as a whole, as derived from Eurostat’s national accounts data. Tangible investment is measured as machinery and equipment investment plus non-residential construction investment. Intangible investment is investment in intellectual property products. All data are seasonally adjusted, expressed in real terms and detrended in logs with a one-sided HP filter using a smoothing parameter of $\lambda =1600$. The shaded areas indicate Center for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) recession dates for the euro area as a whole.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Impulse response functions of selected model variables. Note: The figure displays impulse responses to a negative one standard deviation financial shock. The solid lines correspond to the responses when we hold the model parameters at their calibrated or estimated values, implying, most importantly, that intangible investment is much more costly to adjust than tangible investment. The dashed lines correspond to the responses of a model economy without investment adjustment costs. The marked solid lines correspond to a model economy without investment adjustment costs when we shut down the endogenous feedback of a tightening in $\mu _t$ on the value of tangible capital, $Q_{T,t}$. Note that the dashed line and the marked solid line in the subplot for Intangible investment correspond to the scale of the y-axis on the right-hand side.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Impulse response functions of the intangible/tangible investment ratio as well as tangible and intangible investment. Note: The figure displays on the left-hand side the response of the intangible/tangible investment ratio to a negative one standard deviation financial shock based on alternative settings for the investment adjustment cost parameters, the degree of collateralizability, depreciation rates and investment-to-output ratios. In the subplots in the column on the right-hand side, we show the responses for intangible and tangible investment that correspond to the dashed-dotted lines on the left, except in the first row where they correspond to the solid line.

Figure 3

Figure 4. Constructed financial conditions variable and alternative indicators. Note: Upper panel: The solid line depicts the level series of $\hat{\chi }_t$. The dashed line depicts the quarterly averages of the monthly series for the credit spread index as provided by Gilchrist and Mojon (2018). The credit spread index is multiplied by $-1$, standardized and rescaled to have the same mean and standard deviation as $\hat{\chi }_t$. Lower panel: The solid line depicts the series of the one-period changes in $\hat{\chi }_t$. The dashed line depicts the weighted average of the national diffusion indices of the net tightening of bank credit standards for loans to non-financial corporations for the four largest euro area countries. The series for the change in bank credit standards is multiplied by $-1$, standardized and rescaled to have the same mean and standard deviation as the changes in $\hat{\chi }_t$. The shaded areas in the upper and lower panel indicate Center for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) recession dates for the euro area as a whole.

Figure 4

Figure 5. SVAR- and model-based impulse response functions. Note: The figure displays SVAR- and model-based impulse responses to a negative one standard deviation financial shock. The solid lines are SVAR-based impulse responses and the dashed lines are model-based impulse responses (see Section (4)). The shaded areas denote the one and two standard-deviations confidence intervals around the SVAR-based estimates based on $2{,}000$ bootstrap replications.

Figure 5

Table 1. Percentage variance due to financial shocks

Figure 6

Table 2. Calibrated model parameters

Figure 7

Table 3. Prior and posterior distributions of model parameters

Figure 8

Figure 6. Identified financial shocks. Note: The figure displays the series for the identified financial shocks from the SVAR expressed in terms of standard deviations. The standard deviation is $0.13$ basis points. The shaded areas indicate Center for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) recession dates for the euro area as a whole.

Figure 9

Figure 7. Impact of the Great Recession on tangible and intangible investment. Note: The figure displays the responses of tangible and intangible investment around and during the Great Recession. The dashed lines correspond to the model responses induced by the series of the identified financial shocks from the SVAR. The solid lines represent the corresponding empirical series. For a description of how the empirical measurements for tangible and intangible investment are constructed see the footnote of Figure 1. The vertical lines represent 2008.Q1.

Figure 10

Figure 8. Tangible and intangible investment. Note: The figure displays tangible and intangible investment in the four largest euro area countries as a whole, as derived from Eurostat’s national accounts data. Tangible investment is measured as machinery and equipment investment plus non-residential construction investment. Intangible investment is investment in intellectual property products. All data are seasonally adjusted, expressed in real terms and detrended in logs by applying a quadratic trend. The shaded areas indicate Center for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) recession dates for the euro area as a whole.