Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T19:26:15.743Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

EDUCATION, INEQUALITY, AND DEVELOPMENT IN A DUAL ECONOMY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 September 2014

Kazuhiro Yuki*
Affiliation:
Kyoto University
*
Address correspondence to: Kazuhiro Yuki, Faculty of Economics, Kyoto University, Yoshida-hommachi, Sakyo-ku, Kyoto, 606-8501, Japan; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

This paper develops a dynamic dual-economy model and examines how the long-run outcome of an economy depends on the initial distribution of wealth and sectoral productivity. It is shown that, for fast transformation into a developed economy, the initial distribution must be such that extreme poverty is not prevalent so that most people can take education to acquire basic skills and the size of the “middle class” is large enough so that an adequate number of people can access education to acquire advanced skills. Both conditions seem to have held in successful East Asian nations, where, as in the model economy undergoing such transformation, the fraction of workers with advanced skills rose greatly and inequalities between these workers and others fell over time. In contrast, if the former condition holds but the latter does not, which would be the case for many nations falling into the “middle income trap,” consistent with facts, the fraction of workers with basic skills and the share of the modern sector rise, but inequality between workers with advanced skills and with basic skills worsens and the traditional sector persists for long periods. If the former condition does not hold, which would be true for the poorest economies, the dual structure and high inequality between workers without basic skills and others persist for very long periods. Consistently, Hanushek and Woessmann (2012) [Hanushek, Eric A. and Ludger Woessmann (2012) Do better schools lead to more growth? Cognitive skills, economic outcomes, and causation. Journal of Economic Growth 17, 267–321] find that the share of students with basic skills and that of top performance have significant effects on economic growth that are complementary to each other.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron and Zilibotti, Fabrizio (2001) Productivity differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 563606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akbulut, Rahşan (2011) Sectoral changes and the increase in women's labor force participation. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 240264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alfo, Marco, Trovato, Giovanni, and Waldman, Robert J. (2008) Testing for country heterogeneity in growth models using a finite mixture approach. Journal of Applied Econometics 23, 487514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, Abhijit and Newman, Andrew (1998) Information, the dual economy, and development. Review of Economic Studies 65, 631653.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, Thorsten, Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, and Levine, Ross (2007) Finance, inequality and the poor. Journal of Economic Growth 12, 2749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colclough, Christopher, Kingdon, Geeta, and Patrinos, Harry (2010) The changing pattern of wage returns to education and its implications. Development Policy Review 28, 733747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deininger, Klaus and Olinto, Pedro (2000) Asset Distribution, Inequality, and Growth. Mimeo, World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterly, William (2001) The middle class consensus and economic development. Journal of Economic Growth 6, 317335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, Oded (2005) From stagnation to growth: Unified growth theory. In Aghion, Philippe and Durlauf, Steven (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1A, pp. 171293. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Galor, Oded and Moav, Omer (2004) From physical to human capital accumulation: Inequality in the process of development. Review of Economic Studies 71, 10011026.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, Oded and Moav, Omer (2006) Das human-kapital: A theory of the demise of the class structure. Review of Economic Studies 73, 85117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, Oded, Moav, Omer, and Vollrath, Dietrich (2009) Inequality in landownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Review of Economic Studies 76, 143179.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, Oded and Zeira, Joseph (1993) Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies 60, 3552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gersback, Hans and Siemens, Lars-H. R. (2010) Land reforms and economic development. Macroeconomic Dynamics 14, 527547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, Gary D. and Prescott, Edward C. (2002) Malthus to Solow. American Economic Review 92, 12051217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanushek, Eric A. and Woessmann, Ludger (2008) The role of cognitive skills in economic development. Journal of Economic Literature 46, 607668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanushek, Eric A. and Woessmann, Ludger (2012) Do better schools lead to more growth? Cognitive skills, economic outcomes, and causation. Journal of Economic Growth 17, 267321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hippe, Ralph and Baten, Joerg (2012) “Keep them Ignorant.” Did Inequality in Land Distribution Delay Regional Numeracy Development? Mimeo, University of Tuebingen.Google Scholar
Kongsamut, Piyabha, Rebelo, Sergio, and Xie, Danyang (2001) Beyond balanced growth. Review of Economic Studies 68, 869882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laitner, John (2000) Structural change and economic growth. Review of Economic Studies 67, 545561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La, Porta, , Rafael and Shleifer, Andrei (2008) The unofficial economy and economic development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 35, 275352.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. Jr., (2004) Life earnings and rural–urban migration. Journal of Political Economy 112, S29S59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, Stuart and Zhang, Jie (2012) Income inequality and economic growth with altruistic bequests and human capital investment. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16, 331354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ngai, Rachel and Pissarides, Christopher (2007) Structural change in a multi-sector model of growth. American Economic Review 97, 429443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2009) Is Informal Normal? Towards More and Better Jobs. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Owen, Ann L., Videras, Julio, and Davis, Lewis (2009) Do all countries follow the same growth process? Journal of Economic Growth 14, 265286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paap, Richard, Franses, Philip H., and van Dijk, Dick (2005) Does Africa grow slower than Asia, Latin America and the Middle East? Evidence from a new data-based classification method. Journal of Development Economics 77, 553570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Proto, Eugenio (2007) Land and the transition from a dual to a modern economy. Journal of Development Economics 83, 88108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rahman, Ahmed S. (2013) The road not taken: What is the “appropriate” path to development when growth is unbalanced? Macroeconomic Dynamics 17, 747778.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, Debraj (1998) Development Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Vollrath, Dietrich (2009) The dual economy in long-run development. Journal of Economic Growth 14, 287312.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wang, Ping and Xie, Danyang (2004) Activation of a modern industry. Journal of Development Economics 73, 393410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weil, David (2013) Economic Growth, 3rd ed.Harlow, UK: Pearson Education.Google Scholar
Wood, Adrian (1994) North–South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Yuki, Kazuhiro (2007) Urbanization, informal sector, and development. Journal of Development Economics 84, 76103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yuki, Kazuhiro (2008) Sectoral shift, wealth distribution, and development. Macroeconomic Dynamics 12, 527559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar