Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-14T07:27:13.642Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

DATA REVISIONS IN THE ESTIMATION OF DSGE MODELS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 January 2016

Miguel Casares
Affiliation:
Universidad Pública de Navarra
Jesús Vázquez*
Affiliation:
Universidad del País Vasco (UPV/EHU)
*
Address correspondence to: Jesús Vázquez, Department FAE II, Universidad del País Vasco (UPV/EHU), Avda. Lehendakari Aguirre 83, 48015 Bilbao, Spain; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

Revisions of U.S. macroeconomic data are persistent, correlated with real-time data, and with high variability (around 80% of U.S. real-time data volatility). This paper adapts a DSGE-style model to accommodate both real-time and revised data from the U.S. economy. The results show a lesser role of both habit formation and price indexation than in the standard model. In the simulations, revision shocks to both output and inflation are expansionary because the Fed reacts by cutting interest rates. Consumption revisions, in contrast, are countercyclical, consumption mirrors the observed reduction in real-time consumption. In the variance decomposition, data revisions explain 9.3% of output changes.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Adam, Klaus (2007) Optimal monetary policy with imperfect common knowledge. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 267301.Google Scholar
Aruoba, Borogan S. (2004) Data Uncertainty in General Equilibrium. Mimeo, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Aruoba, Borogan S. (2008) Data revisions are not well-behaved. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40, 319340.Google Scholar
Berardi, Michele and Duffy, John (2015) Real-time, adaptive learning via parameterized expectations. Macroeconomic Dynamics 19 (2), 245269.Google Scholar
Brooks, Stephen P. and Gelman, Andrew (1998) General methods for monitoring converge of iterative simulations. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics 7, 434455.Google Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A. (1983) Staggered pricing in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 383396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casares, Miguel and McCallum, Bennett T. (2006) An optimizing IS–LM framework with endogenous investment. Journal of Macroeconomics 28, 621644.Google Scholar
Christiano, Lawrence J., Eichenbaum, Martin, and Evans, Charles L. (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113, 145.Google Scholar
Coenen, Günter, Levin, Andrew, and Wieland, Volker (2005) Data uncertainty and the role of money as an information variable for monetary policy. European Economic Review 49, 9751006.Google Scholar
Corradi, Valentina, Fernandez, Andres, and Swanson, Norman R. (2009) Information in the revision process of real-time datasets. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 27, 455467.Google Scholar
Croushore, Dean (2011) Frontiers of real-time data analysis. Journal of Economic Literature 49, 72100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croushore, Dean and Stark, Tom (2001) A real-time data set for macroeconomists. Journal of Econometrics 105, 111130.Google Scholar
Diebold, Francis X. and Rudebusch, Glenn D. (1991) Forecasting output with the composite leading index: A real-time analysis. Journal of the American Statistical Association 86, 603610.Google Scholar
Edge, Rochelle M., Kiley, Michael T., and Laforte, Jean-Philippe (2010) A comparison of forecast performance between Federal Reserve staff forecasts, simple reduced-form models, and a DSGE model. Journal of Applied Econometrics 25, 720754.Google Scholar
Erceg, Christopher J., Henderson, Dale W., and Levin, Andrew T. (2000) Optimal monetary policy with staggered wage and price contracts. Journal of Monetary Economics 46, 281313.Google Scholar
Faust, Jon, Rogers, John H., and Wright, Jonathan H. (2005) News and noise in G-7 GDP announcements. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37, 403419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herbst, Edward and Schorfheide, Frank (2011) Evaluating DSGE Model Forecasts of Comovements. Research Department working paper 11-5, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ireland, Peter (2003) Endogenous money or sticky prices? Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 16231648.Google Scholar
Kimball, Miles S. (1995) The quantitative analytics of the basic neomonetarist model. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27, 12411277.Google Scholar
King, Robert G. and Watson, Mark W. (1996) Money, prices, interest rates and the business cycle. Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 3553.Google Scholar
Levine, Paul, Pearlman, Joseph, Perendia, George, and Yang, Bo (2012) Endogenous persistence in an estimated DSGE model under imperfect information. Economic Journal 122, 12871312.Google Scholar
Mackowiak, Bartosz and Wiederholt, Mirko (2009) Optimal sticky prices under rational inattention. American Economic Review 99, 769803.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. Gregory, Runkle, David E., and Shapiro, Matthew D. (1984) Are preliminary announcements of the money stock rational forecasts? Journal of Monetary Economics 14, 1527.Google Scholar
Orphanides, Athanasios (2001) Monetary policy rules based on real-time data. American Economic Review 91, 964985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orphanides, Athanasios (2003) Monetary policy evaluation with noisy information. Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 605631.Google Scholar
Orphanides, Athanasios and van Norden, Simon (2002) The unreliability of output-gap estimates in real time. Review of Economics and Statistics 84, 569583.Google Scholar
Pruitt, Seth (2012) Uncertainty over models and data: The rise and fall of American inflation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44, 341365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reis, Ricardo (2009) A Sticky Information General Equilibrium Model for Policy Analysis. Working paper 14732, NBER.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio J. and Woodford, Michael (1997) An optimizing-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy. In Bernanke, Ben S. and Rotemberg, Julio J. (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 297346. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Sims, Christopher A. (2003) Implications of rational inattention. Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 665690.Google Scholar
Smets, Frank R. and Wouters, Rafael (2007) Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review 97, 586606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stock, James H. and Watson, Mark W. (2002) Has the business cycle changed and why? In Gertler, Mark and Rogoff, Kenneth (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 159218. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Svensson, Lars E.O. and Woodford, Michael (2004) Indicator variables for optimal policy under asymmetric information. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 28, 661690.Google Scholar
Vázquez, Jesús, María-Dolores, Ramón, and Londoño, Juan M. (2012) The effect of data revisions on the basic New Keynesian model. International Review of Economics and Finance 24, 235249.Google Scholar