Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T06:44:54.578Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

ARE HIGHER WAGES GOOD FOR BUSINESS? AN ASSESSMENT UNDER ALTERNATIVE INNOVATION AND INVESTMENT SCENARIOS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 July 2018

Alessandro Caiani*
Affiliation:
University of Pavia
Alberto Russo
Affiliation:
Marche Polytechnic University
Mauro Gallegati
Affiliation:
Marche Polytechnic University
*
Address correspondence to: Alessandro Caiani, University of Pavia, Department of Management, Via San Felice 5, Stanza 5, Pavia, PV, Italy; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

This paper aims at investigating the interplay between inequality, innovation dynamics, and investment behaviors in shaping the long-run patterns of growth of a closed economy. By extending the analysis proposed in Caiani et al. [(2018) Journal of Evolutionary Economics], we explore the effects of alternative wage regimes under different investment and technological change scenarios. Experimental results seem to de-emphasize the role of technological progress as a possible source of greater inequality. Overall, simulation results are consistent with the predominance of a wage-led growth regime in most of the scenarios analyzed: A faster growth of low- and middle-level workers’ wages, relative to managers’, generally exert beneficial effects on the economy and allows to counteract the labor-saving effects of technological progress. Furthermore, a distribution more favorable to workers does not compromise firms’ profitability, but rather strengthen it by creating a more favorable macroeconomic environment, which encourages further innovations, stimulates investment, and sustains economic growth.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abowd, J. M., Kramarz, F., and Margolis, D. N. (1999) High wage workers and high wage firms. Econometrica 67 (2), 251333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (1998) Why do new technologies complement skills: Directed technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 10551089.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2002) Technical change, inequality, and the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature 40, 772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2007) Equilibrium bias of technology. Econometrica 75 (5), 13711409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Robinson, J. A., and Verdier, T. (2012) Can’t We All Be More Like Scandinavians? Asymmetric Growth and Institutions in an Interdependent World. NBER working papers, 18441.Google Scholar
Aghion, P., Akcigit, U., Bergeaud, A., Blundell, R., and Hemous, D. (2015) Innovation and Top Income Inequality. NBER working papers, 21247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1997) Endogeneous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Antonelli, C. and Gehringer, A. (2013) Innovation and Income Inequality. Technical Report, University of Turin, Department of Economics and Statistics Cognetti de Martiis LEI & BRICK, Collegio Carlo Alberto. WP series.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B., Piketty, T., and Saez, E. (2011) Top incomes in the long run of history. Journal of Economic Literature 49 (1), 371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caiani, A., Godin, A., Caverzasi, E., Gallegati, M., Kinsella, S., and Stiglitz, J. E. (2016) Agent Based-Stock Flow Consistent macroeconomics: Towards a benchmark model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 69, 375408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caiani, A., Godin, A., and Lucarelli, S. (2014) A stock flow consistent analysis of a Schumpeterian innovation economy. Metroeconomica 65 (3), 397429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caiani, A., Russo, A., and Gallegati, M. (2018) Does inequality hamper innovation and growth? An AB-SFC analysis. Journal of Evolutionary Economics. doi:10.1007/s00191-018-0554-8.Google Scholar
Carlin, W. and Soskice, D. (1990) Macroeconomics and the Wage Bargain: A Modern Approach to Employment, Inflation, and the Exchange Rate. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Ciarli, T., Lorentz, A., Savona, M., and Valente, M. (2010) The effect of consumption and production structure on growth and distribution. A micro to macro model. Metroeconomica 61 (1), 219246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delli Gatti, D., Gallegati, M., Greenwald, B. C., Russo, A., and Stiglitz, J. E. (2010) The financial accelerator in an evolving credit network. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34, 16271650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domar, E. (1947) Expansion and employment. American Economic Review 37, 3455.Google Scholar
Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., Napoletano, M., and Roventini, A. (2013) Income distribution, credit and fiscal policies in an agent-based Keynesian model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 (8), 15981625.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., and Roventini, A. (2010) Schumpeter meeting Keynes: A policy-friendly model of endogenous growth and business cycles. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (9), 17481767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dosi, G., Pereira, M., Roventini, A., and Virgillito, M. (2017) When more flexibility yields more fragility: The microfoundations of Keynesian aggregate unemployment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 81, 162186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, A. K. (1987) Alternative closures again: A comment on growth, distribution and inflation. Cambridge Journal of Economics 11 (1), 7582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dynan, K. E., Skinner, J., and Zeldes, S. P. (2004) Do the rich save more? Journal of Political Economy 112 (2), 397444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichner, A. S. (1976) The Megacorp and Oligopoly: Micro Foundations of Macro Dynamics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldin, C. and Katz, L. F. (2008) The Race Between Education and Technology. Cambridge, MA and London, UK: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Harrod, H. (1939) An essay in dynamic theory. Economic Journal 49 (193), 1433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hein, E. and Vogel, L. (2008) Distribution and growth reconsidered empirical results for six OECD countries. Cambridge Journal of Economics 32, 479511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopkin, J., Lapuente, V., and Moller, L. (2014) Lower levels of inequality are linked with greater innovation in economies. Technical report, London School of Economics and Political Science. LSE’s USAPP blog.Google Scholar
Jacobs, E. (2016) What do trends in economic inequality imply for innovation and entrepreneurship? A framework for future research and policy. Technical report, Washington Center for Equitable Growth.Google Scholar
Jaumotte, F. and Buitron, C. O. (2015) Inequality and Labor Market Institutions. Staff discussion notes SDN/15/14.Google Scholar
Jones, C. I. and Kim, J. (2014) A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality. NBER working papers, 20637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1957) A model of economic growth. Economic Journal 67 (268), 591624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, L. F. and Murphy, K. M. (1992) Change in relative wages: Supply and demand factors. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 3578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumhof, M., Ranciere, R., and Winant, P. (2015) Inequality, leverage and crises. American Economic Review 105 (3), 12171245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lavoie, M. (1992) Foundations of Post-Keynesian Economic Analysis. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Lavoie, M. (2015) Post-Keynesian Economics: New Foundations. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Lavoie, M. and Stockhammer, E. (2012) Wage-Led Growth: Concept, Theories and Policies. Conditions of Work and Employment Series, 41. Geneva: International Labor Office.Google Scholar
Lydall, H. F. (1959) The distribution of employment incomes. Econometrica 27 (1), 110115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCombie, J. S. L. (2002) Increasing returns and the Verdoon law from a Kaldorian perspective. In McCombie, J. S. L., Pugno, M., and Soro, B. (eds.), Productivity Growth and Economic Performance: Essays on Verdoon’s Law, pp. 64114. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naastepad, C. W. M. and Storm, S. (2006) OECD demand regimes (1960-2000). Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics 29 (2), 213248.Google Scholar
Napoletano, M., Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., and Roventini, A. (2012) Wage formation investment behavior and growth regimes: An agent-based analysis. Revue de l’OFCE 124, 235261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1977) Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition. American Economic Review 67 (1), 271276.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. G. (1982) An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Onaran, O. and Galanis, G. (2012) Is Aggregate Demand Wage-Led or Profit-Led? National and Global Effects, Conditions of Work and Employment Series, 40. Geneva: International Labor Office.Google Scholar
Onaran, O. and Obst, T. (2016) Wage-led growth in the EU15 member states: The effects of income distribution on growth, investment, trade balance, and inflation. Cambridge Journal of Economics 40 (6), 15171551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perugini, C., Holscher, J., and Collie, S. (2016) Inequality, credit and financial crises. Cambridge Journal of Economics 40 (1), 227257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, T. (2014) Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA and London: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Piketty, T., Saez, E., and Stantcheva, S. (2014) Optimal taxation of top labor incomes: A tale of three elasticities. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 6 (1), 230271.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. and Zucman, G. (2014) Capital is back: Wealth-income ratios in rich countries 1700–2010. Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (3), 12551310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prescott, E. S. (2003) Firms, assignments, and earnings. Federal Reserve Bank Richmond Economic Quarterly 89 (4), 6981.Google Scholar
Riccetti, L., Russo, A., and Gallegati, M. (2015) An agent-based decentralized matching macroeconomic model. Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 10 (2), 305332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rowthorn, R. (1981) Demand, real wages and economic growth. Thames Papers in Political Economy Autumn, 1–39.Google Scholar
Russo, A., Riccetti, L., and Gallegati, M. (2016) Increasing inequality, consumer credit and financial fragility in an agent based macroeconomic model. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 26 (1), 2547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salle, I. and Yildizoglu, M. (2014) Efficient sampling and meta-modeling for computational economic models. Computational Economics 44 (4), 507536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934/1912) The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. (1957) The compensation of executives. Sociometry 20, 3235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steindl, J. (1952) Maturity and Stagnation in American Capitalism. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (2012) The Price of Inequality. New York: Norton & Co Inc.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (2015) The Great Divide: Unequal Societies and What We Can Do About Them. New York: Norton & Co Inc.Google Scholar
Stockhammer, E. and Onaran, O. (2013) Wage-led growth: Theory, evidence, policy. Review of Keynesian Economics 1 (1), 6178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stockhammer, E., Onaran, O., and Ederer, S. (2009) Functional income distribution and aggregate demand in the euro area. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33 (1), 139159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Storm, S. and Naastepad, C. W. M. (2012) Macroeconomics Beyond the NAIRU. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, L. (1983) Structuralist Macroeconomics: Applicable Models for the Third World. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Thirlwall, A. (1983) A plain man’s guide to Kaldor’s growth laws. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 5 (3), 345358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vergeer, R. and Kleinknecht, A. (2010) The impact of labor market deregulation on productivity: A panel data analysis of 19 OECD countries (1960–2004). Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 33 (2), 371407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vergeer, R. and Kleinknecht, A. (2014) Do labor market reforms reduce labor productivity growth: A panel data analysis of 20 OECD countries (1960–2004). International Labour Review 153 (3), 365393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldman, M. (1984) Workers allocation, hierarchies and the wage distribution. Review of Economic Studies 51, 95109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weinhold, D. and Nair-Reichert, U. (2009) Innovation, inequality and intellectual property rights. World Development 37 (5), 889901.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winter, S. G. (1984) Schumpeterian competition in alternative technological regimes. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 5, 287320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar