Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-14T13:22:12.521Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

CAPITAL DESTRUCTION, JOBLESS RECOVERIES, AND THE DISCIPLINE DEVICE ROLE OF UNEMPLOYMENT

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2017

Marianna Riggi*
Affiliation:
Bank of Italy
*
Address correspondence to: Marianna Riggi, Bank of Italy, via Nazionale 91, 00184 Rome, Italy; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

I consider an economy growing along the balanced growth path that is hit by an adverse shock to its capital accumulation process. The model integrates efficiency wages due to imperfect monitoring of the quality of labor in a search and matching framework with methods of dynamic general equilibrium analysis. I show that, depending on the firms' abilities to assess workers' performance, the discipline device role of unemployment may account for sharp declines in employment and jobless recoveries driven by exceptional increases in the work effort of employees. The model also explains why rigid real wages may prevail in equilibrium: the large movements in unemployment are indeed associated with real wage rigidity, which is generated endogenously by efficiency wages.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I wish to thank an associate editor and two referees for their very helpful suggestions. I am also grateful to Pierpaolo Benigno, Matteo Bugamelli, Julien Champagne, Marco Cosconati, André Kurmann, Tommaso Monacelli, Stefano Neri, Francesco Nucci, Patrizio Pagano, Federico Ravenna, Alfonso Rosolia, Sergio Santoro, Massimo Sbracia, Paolo Sestito, Henry Siu, Stefano Siviero, and participants of the CEPR-CREI conference on “Understanding Jobless Recoveries” Universitat Pompeu Fabra, of the 8th Dynare Conference in Zurich, and of the “Vienna Macroeconomics Workshop 2014” for their helpful suggestions and discussions. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of Italy.

References

REFERENCES

Aiello, John R. and Kolb, Kathryn J. (1995) Electronic performance monitoring and social context: Impact on productivity and stress. Journal of Applied Psychology 80 (3), 339353.10.1037/0021-9010.80.3.339Google Scholar
Aiello, John R. and Kolb, Kathryn J. (1997) Computer-based performance monitoring and productivity in a multiple task environment. Journal of Business and Psychology 12 (2), 189204.Google Scholar
Alexopoulos, Michelle (2004) Unemployment and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 277298.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2002.11.002Google Scholar
Alexopoulos, Michelle (2007) A monetary business cycle model with unemployment Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31 (12), 39043940.10.1016/j.jedc.2007.01.017Google Scholar
Altig, David, Christiano, Lawrence, Eichenbaum, Martin, and Linde, Jasper (2011) Firm-specific capital, nominal rigidities and the business cycle. Review of Economic Dynamics 14, 225247.10.1016/j.red.2010.01.001Google Scholar
Amick, B. C. and Smitht, M. J. (1992) Stress, computer-based work monitoring and measurement systems: A conceptual overview. Applied Ergonomics 23 (1), 616.10.1016/0003-6870(92)90005-GGoogle Scholar
Andolfatto, David and MacDonald, Glenn (2004) Jobless recoveries. EconWPA, Macroeconomics, 0412014.Google Scholar
Atkinson, Anthony and Piketty, Thomas (2006) Top Incomes Over the Twentieth Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bachmann, Rüdiger (2014) Understanding the Jobless Recoveries After 1991 and 2001. Mimeo, University of Michigan.Google Scholar
Baker, George (1992) Incentive contracts and performance measurement. Journal of Political Economy 100, 598614.10.1086/261831Google Scholar
Barnichon, Regis (2012) Vacancy posting, job separation and unemployment fluctuations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36 (3), 315330.10.1016/j.jedc.2011.09.006Google Scholar
Barro, Robert J. (2006) Rare disasters and asset markets in the twenthieth century. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99, 823866.10.1162/qjec.121.3.823Google Scholar
Berger, David (2014) Countercyclical Restructuring and Jobless Recoveries. Mimeo, Northwestern University.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. (2003) The Jobless Recovery. Remarks by Governor at the Global Economic and Investment Outlook Conference. Pittsburgh, PA: Carnegie Mellon University, Accessed on November 6, 2003 from www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2003/200311062/default.htmGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. and Quah, Danny (1989) The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances. American Economic Review 79 (4), 655673Google Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. and Diamond, Peter (1990) The cyclical behavior of the gross flows of US workers. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 160.Google Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. and Gali, Jordi (2010) Labour market frictions and monetary policy: A new Keynesian model with unemployment. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (2), 130.Google Scholar
Chen, Jinzhu, Kannan, Prakash, Loungani, Prakash and Trehan, Bharat (2011) New Evidence on Cyclical and Structural Sources of Unemployment. IMF working paper WP/11/106.Google Scholar
Danthine, Jean Pierre and Donaldson, John B. (1995) Non Walrasian Economies. In Cogley, Thomas F. (ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, pp. 217242. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Elsby, Michael, Hobijn, Bart, and Sahin, Aysegul (2011) The labour market in the great recession: An update to September 2011. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 42 (2), 353384.10.1353/eca.2011.0013Google Scholar
Faia, Ester (2009) Ramsey monetary policy with labor market frictions. Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 570581.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009.03.009Google Scholar
Fischer, Jonas D. M. (2006) The dynamic effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks. Journal of Political Economy 114, 413451.10.1086/505048Google Scholar
Furlanetto, Francesco and Seneca, Martin (2011) New Perspective on Depreciation Shocks as a Source of Business Cycle Fluctuations. Norges Bank working paper 2011/02.Google Scholar
Gali, Jordi, Lopez-Salido, David, and Vallés, Javier (2007) Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 5 (1), 227270.10.1162/JEEA.2007.5.1.227Google Scholar
Gali, Jordi, Smets, Frank, and Wouters, Rafael (2011) Slow Recoveries: A Structural Interpretation. Mimeo, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.Google Scholar
Gali, Jordi and van Rens, Thijs (2014) The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity. Warwick Economic research papers, 1062.Google Scholar
Gertler, Mark, Sala, Luca, and Trigari, Antonella (2008) An estimated monetary DSGE model with unemployment and staggered nominal wage bargaining. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40 (8), 17131764.10.1111/j.1538-4616.2008.00180.xGoogle Scholar
Gertler, Mark and Karadi, Peter (2011) A model of unconventional monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 58, 1734.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.10.004Google Scholar
Gertler, Mark and Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro (2010) Financial intermediation and credit policy in business cycle analysis. In Friedman, Benjamin M. and Woodford, Michael (eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, 1st ed., Vol. 3, Chap. 11, pp. 547599. Elsevier.10.1016/B978-0-444-53238-1.00011-9Google Scholar
Gomme, Paul (1999) Shirking, unemployment and aggregate fluctuations. International Economic Review 40 (1), 321.10.1111/1468-2354.00002Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. (1979) The “end-of-expansion” phenomenon in short-run productivity behavior. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 10 (2), 447462.10.2307/2534391Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. (1993) The jobless recovery: Does it signal a new era of productivity-led growth? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 217306.Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. (2003) Exploding productivity growth: Context, causes, and implications. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 207–79.10.1353/eca.2004.0006Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. (2010) The Demise of Okun's Law and of Procyclical Fluctuations in Conventional and Unconventional Measures of Productivity. Mimeo, Northwestern University.Google Scholar
Groshen, Erica and Potter, Simon (2003) Has structural change contributed to a jobless recovery?. Current Issues in Economics and Finance 9 (8), 17.Google Scholar
Hayashi, F. (1982) Tobin's marginal q and average q: A neoclassical interpretation. Econometrica 50 (1), 213224.10.2307/1912538Google Scholar
Hall, Robert E. (2005) Employment efficiency and sticky wages: Evidence from flows in the labor market. Review of Economics and Statistics 87 (3), 397407.10.1162/0034653054638346Google Scholar
Hall, Robert E. (2010) Why is Unemployment Still so High Two Years after the Financial Crisis. Mimeo, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Hawk, Stephen R. (1994) The effects of computerized performance monitoring: An ethical perspective. Journal of Business Ethics 13 (12), 949957.10.1007/BF00881664Google Scholar
Jaimovich, Nir and Siu, Henry E. (2014) The Trend is the Cycle: Job Polarization and Jobless Recoveries. NBER working paper 18334.Google Scholar
Justiniano, Alejandro and Primiceri, Giorgio E. (2008) The time varying volatility of macroeconomic fluctuations. American Economic Review 98, 604641.10.1257/aer.98.3.604Google Scholar
Justiniano, Alejandro, Primiceri, Giorgio E., and Tambalotti, Andrea (2010) Investment shocks and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 57, 132145.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009.12.008Google Scholar
Justiniano, Alejandro, Primiceri, Giorgio E., and Tambalotti, Andrea (2011) Investment shocks and the relative price of investment. Review of Economic Dynamics 14 (1), 101121.10.1016/j.red.2010.08.004Google Scholar
Kimball, Miles S. (1994) Labour market dynamics when unemployment is a worker discipline device. American Economic Review 84 (4), 10451059.Google Scholar
King, Robert and Watson, Mark (1996) Money, prices, interest rates and the business Cycle. Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 3553.10.2307/2109846Google Scholar
Kurtzberga, Terri R., Naquinb, Charles E., and Belkinc, Liuba Y. (2005) Electronic performance appraisals: The effects of e-mail communication on peer ratings in actual and simulated environments. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 98 (2), 216226.10.1016/j.obhdp.2005.07.001Google Scholar
Kydland, Finn E. and Zarazaga, Carlos E. J. M. (2016) Fiscal sentiment and the weak recovery from the great recession: A quantitative exploration. Journal of Monetary Economics 79, 109125.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2016.03.002Google Scholar
Lemieux, Thomas, MacLeod, W. Bentley, and Parent, Daniel (2009) Performance pay and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (1), 149.10.1162/qjec.2009.124.1.1Google Scholar
Levy, P. E. and Williams, J. R. (2004). The social context of performance appraisal: A review and framework for the future. Journal of Management 30, 881905.10.1016/j.jm.2004.06.005Google Scholar
Lilien, David M. (1982) Sectoral shifts and cyclical unemployment. Journal of Political Economy 90 (4), 777–93.10.1086/261088Google Scholar
Lindé, Jesper (2009) The effects of permanent technology shocks on hours: Can the RBC-model fit the VAR evidence?. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 33, 597613.10.1016/j.jedc.2008.08.011Google Scholar
Liu, Z., Waggoner, D. F., and Zha, T. (2010) Sources of Macroeconomic Fluctuations: A Regime-Switching DSGE Approach. FRB San Francisco working paper 2009-01.Google Scholar
Loungani, Prakash and Trehan, Bharat (1997) Explaining unemployment: Sectoral vs aggregate shocks. Economic ReviewFederal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 315.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. (1967) Adjustment costs and the theory of supply. Journal of Political Economy 75 (4), Part 1, 321334.10.1086/259289Google Scholar
Mitman, Kurt and Rabinovichz, Stanislav (2014) Unemployment Benefit Extensions Caused Jobless Recoveries!?. Penn Institute for Economic Research working paper no. 14-013, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Monacelli, Tommaso, Quadrini, Vincenzo, and Trigari, Antonella (2011) Financial Markets and Unemployment. NBER working paper w17389.Google Scholar
Ohanian, Lee E. (2009) What – or who – started the great depression?. Journal of Economic Theory 144 (6), 23102335.10.1016/j.jet.2009.10.007Google Scholar
Ohanian, Lee E. (2010a) The economic crisis from a neoclassical perspective. Journal of Economic Perspective 24 (4), 4566.10.1257/jep.24.4.45Google Scholar
Ohanian, Lee E. (2010b) Understanding economic crises: The great depression and the 2008 recession. Economic Record 86, 26.10.1111/j.1475-4932.2010.00667.xGoogle Scholar
Oliner, Stephen D., Sichel, Daniel E., and Stiroh, Kevin J. (2007), Explaining a productivity decade. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 81137.10.1353/eca.2007.0014Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas and Saez, Emmanuel (2006) The evolution of top incomes: A historical and international perspective. American Economic Review 96 (2), 200205.10.1257/000282806777212116Google Scholar
Primiceri, Giorgio, Schaumburg, Ernst, and Tambalotti, Andrea (2006). Intertemporal Disturbances. Mimeo, Northwestern University.Google Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio J. (2003) Stochastic technical progress, smooth trends, and nearly distinct business cycles. American Economic Review 93 (5), 15431559.10.1257/000282803322655437Google Scholar
Shapiro, Carl and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1984) Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. American Economic Review 74 (3), 433444.Google Scholar
Shimer, Robert (2005) The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies. American Economic Review 95 (1), 2549.10.1257/0002828053828572Google Scholar
Shimer, Robert (2007) Reassessing the Ins and Outs of Unemployment. NBER working paper 13421.Google Scholar
Shimer, Robert (2012) Wage rigidities and jobless recoveries. Journal of Monetary Economics 59 (15), 657710.1016/j.jmoneco.2012.10.024Google Scholar
Solow, Robert (1979) Another possible source of wage stickiness. Journal of Macroeconomics 1 (1), 7982.10.1016/0164-0704(79)90022-3Google Scholar
The Economist (2009) Big Brother Bosses. September 10, 2009. Available at http://www.economist.com/node/14413380Google Scholar
Uhlig, Harald and Xu, Yexiao (1996) Effort and the Cycle: Cyclical Implications of Efficiency Wages. Tilburg University discussion paper 1996-49.Google Scholar
Van Rens, Thijs (2005) Organizational Capital and Employment Fluctuations. Mimeo, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.Google Scholar
Wang, Pengfei and Wen, Yi (2012) Hayashi meets Kiyotaki and Moore: A theory of capital adjustment costs. Review of Economic Dynamics 15 (2), 207225.10.1016/j.red.2011.09.004Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (1994) Notes on Dynamic Efficiency Wage Models. Mimeo, Columbia University.Google Scholar
Yellen, Janet L. (2010) The Outlook for the Economy and Monetary Policy. President's Speech. San Diego: University of San Diego. Available at http://www.frbsf.org/news/speeches/2010/janet_yellen0222.htmlGoogle Scholar