Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T15:49:09.790Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

If Boilerplate Could Talk: The Work of Standard Terms in Sovereign Bond Contracts

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 April 2019

Abstract

Standard contract terms are “sticky”: they rarely change, even if change appears to be in the parties’ interest. Multiple theories to explain stickiness do not reach consensus on its causes. We investigate the role of stickiness in sovereign bond contracts, where it would be especially costly and therefore puzzling. In our interviews with more than a 100 officials responsible for the bond contracts of twenty-eight countries, they linked reluctance to change non-financial contract terms and the imperative of following a “market standard” for such terms. When a term could be described as standard for the government’s debt stock or borrower cohort, its content often came across as secondary. Sovereign debt managers seemed willing to forgo some of the benefits of contract terms for dealing with contingencies and revealing private information to avoid negative signals and maintain the liquidity of primary and secondary debt markets. Interviews with investors suggested a similar focus on standard form and a limited engagement with contract substance.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© 2019 American Bar Foundation 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We owe deep thanks to commentators and participants in conferences and workshops where we presented this research, including Georgetown Law, the University of Glasgow, the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Graduate Institute (Geneva), the University of Texas at Austin School of Law, Washington University School of Law-St. Louis, and Northwestern University, to our home institutions for supporting our travel to far-flung debt offices, to several generations of research assistants, and to the five anonymous reviewers who, along with Willa Sachs, gave us superb comments. Above all, this article would not exist but for the extraordinary generosity of its protagonists, public officials and market participants.

References

REFERENCES

Ben Shahar, Omri, and Pottow, John. “On the Stickiness of Default Rules.” Florida State Law Review 33, no. 3 (2006): 651–81.Google Scholar
Bolton, Patrick, and Jeanne, Olivier. “Structuring and Restructuring Sovereign Debt: The Role of Seniority.” Review of Economic Studies 76, no. 3 (2009): 879902.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borensztein, Eduardo, and Panizza, Ugo. “The Costs of Sovereign Default.” IMF Staff Papers 56, no. 4 (2009): 683741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratton, William.Pari Passu and a Distressed Sovereign’s Rational Choices.” Emory Law Journal 53, no. 1 (2006): 823–67.Google Scholar
Choi, Stephen, Gulati, Mitu, and Posner, Eric. “Evolution of Contractual Terms in Sovereign Bonds.” Journal of Legal Analysis 4, no. 1 (2012): 131–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, Stephen, Gulati, Mitu and Scott, Robert. “Variation in Boilerplate: Rational Design or Random Mutation?American Law & Economics Review 20, no. 1 (2018): 145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dang, Tri Vi, Gorton, Gary, and Holmström, Bengt. “The Information Sensitivity of a Security.” Mimeo. 2015.Google Scholar
Datz, Giselle.Governments as Market Players: State Innovation in the Global Economy.” Journal of International Affairs, 62, no. 1 (2008): 3549.Google Scholar
De Franco, Gus, Vasvari, Florin, Vyas, Dushyantkumar, and Wittenberg-Moerman, Regina. “Sticky Covenants.” Mimeo. 2014.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demiroglu, Cem, and James, Christopher. “The Information Content of Bank Loan Covenants.” The Review of Financial Studies 23, no. 10 (2010): 3700–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dezalay, Yves, and Garth, Bryant. Dealing in Virtue: International Commercial Arbitration and the Construction of a Transnational Legal Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996.Google Scholar
Diaz de Leon Carrillo, Alejandro. “Mexico’s Adoption of New Standards in International Sovereign Debt Contracts.” Capital Markets Law Journal 11, no. 1 (2016): 1224.Google Scholar
Dooley, Michael.International Financial Architecture and Strategic Default.” Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy 53, no. 1 (2000): 361–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, Jonathan, and Gersovitz, Mark. “Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.” Review of Economic Studies 48, no. 2 (1981): 289309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Financial Markets Law Committee. “Pari Passu Clauses.” Issue 79. March, 2005.Google Scholar
Gelpern, Anna. “Italy’s Pari Passu Scrubbing.” CreditSlips.org. April, 2013.Google Scholar
Gelpern, Anna. “The Importance of Being Standard.” In ESCB Legal Conference 2016, 2345. Frankfurt: European Central Bank Publication. 2017.Google Scholar
Gelpern, Anna, and Gulati, Mitu. “Public Symbol in Private Contract: A Case Study.” Washington University Law Review 84, no. 1 (2006): 1627–716.Google Scholar
Gelpern, Anna, and Gulati, Mitu. “The Wonder Clause.” Journal of Comparative Economics 41, no. 2 (2013): 367385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelpern, Anna, Heller, Ben, and Setser, Brad. “Count the Limbs.” In Too Little, Too Late: The Quest to Resolve Sovereign Debt Crises. Edited by Martin, Guzman, Antonio Ocampo, Jose, and Stiglitz, Joseph, 109143. New York: Columbia University Press, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilsinan, Kathy. “65 Words Just Caused Argentina’s $29 Billion Default.” Atlantic, July 31. 2014.Google Scholar
Gulati, Mitu, and Scott, Robert. The Three and a Half Minute Transaction: Boilerplate and the Limits of Contract Design. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Häseler, Sönke. “Collective Action Clauses in International Sovereign Bond Contracts– Whence the Opposition?Journal of Economic Surveys 23, no. 5 (2009): 882923.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Han, Shin-Kap. “Mimetic Isomorphism and Its Effect on the Audit Services Market.” Social Forces 73, no. 2 (1994): 637–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ho, Karen. Liquidated: An Ethnography of Wall Street. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). “Sovereign Debt Restructuring—Recent Developments for the Fund’s Legal and Policy Framework.” April 26. 2013.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). “Revised Guidelines for Debt Management.” April 1. 2014.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). “Progress Report on Inclusion of Contractual Provisions in Sovereign Contracts.” September 1. 2015.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). “Second Progress Report on Inclusion of Contractual Provisions in Sovereign Contracts.” December 27. 2016.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). “Third Progress Report on Inclusion of Contractual Provisions in Sovereign Contracts.” December 15. 2017.Google Scholar
Johnston, Jason.Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules,” Yale Law Journal 100, no. 3 (1990): 615–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Juliet. Priests of Prosperity. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2016.Google Scholar
Kahan, Marcel, and Klausner, Michael. “Standardization and Innovation in Corporate Contracting,” Virginia Law Review 83, no. 4 (1997): 713–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahan, Marcel, and Leshem, Shmuel (2017). “Sovereign Debt and Moral Hazard: The Role of Contractual Ambiguity and Asymmetric Information.” Mimeo. 2017.Google Scholar
Kapstein, Ethan.Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence.” International Organization 46, no. 1 (1992): 265–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macaulay, Stewart.Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study.” American Sociological Review 28, no. 1 (1963): 5567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macneil, Ian.The Many Futures of Contract.” Southern California Law Review, 47, no. 1 (1974): 691721.Google Scholar
Mersch, Yves.Reflections on the Feasibility of a Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism in the Euro Area.” In ESCB Legal Conference 2016, 613. Frankfurt: European Central Bank, 2016.Google Scholar
Myles, Danielle. “Ivory Coast Sets Maturity Benchmark for SSA Eurobonds.” International Financial Law Review. April 2, 2015.Google Scholar
Riles, Annelise. Collateral Knowledge: Legal Reasoning in the Global Financial Markets. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sadeh, Tal, and Porath, Yehuda. “The Politics of Fiscal Policy Signaling in Government Bond Issues.” Mimeo. 2017.Google Scholar
Salmon, Felix.The Buy Side Starts to Bite Back.” Euromoney. April, 2001.Google Scholar
Scigliuzzo, Davide. “Changes to LatAm Bond Clauses Raises Hackles.” Reuters. March 6, 2015.Google Scholar
Shleifer, Andrei.Will the Sovereign Debt Market Survive?American Economic Review 92, no. 2 (2003): 8590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Gordon, and King, Brayden. “Contracts as Organizations.” Arizona Law Review 51, no. 1 (2009): 140.Google Scholar
Spier, Kathryn.Incomplete Contracts and Signalling.” RAND Journal of Economics 23, no. 3 (1992): 432443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobel, Mark.Strengthening Collective Action Clauses.” Capital Markets Law Journal 11, no. 1 (2016): 311.Google Scholar
Suchman, Mark.The Contract as Social Artifact.” Law & Society Review 37, no. 1 (2003): 91142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zuckerman, Ezra.The Categorical Imperative: Securities Analysts and the Illegitimacy Discount.” American Journal of Sociology 104, no. 5 (1999): 13981438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar