Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T11:04:12.722Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Incentives in religious performance: a stochastic dominance approach

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

Teresa García-Muñoz*
Affiliation:
Departamento de Métodos Cuantitativos para la Economía y la Empresa, Universidad de Granada
*
* Address: Teresa García-Muñoz, Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales, Campus de la Cartuja s/n, 18011 Granada, España. Email: [email protected].
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Using a stochastic dominance approach in an international dataset of about 10,000 Catholic subjects, we show that incentives (based on absolute belief) play a crucial role in religious practice (church attendance and prayer). Furthermore, we find that when both positive (heaven) and negative (hell) incentives are available, the former have a much stronger effect than the latter. The results are confirmed using Kolmogorov-Smirnov tests.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
The authors license this article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 License.
Copyright
Copyright © The Authors [2010] This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

1 Introduction

Many studies have examined the role of incentives and their effect on the behavior of individuals (Tversky & Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1991; Slonim & Roth, Reference Slonim and Roth1998; Andreoni et al., Reference Andreoni, Harbaugh and Vesterlund2003; Nikiforakis, Reference Nikiforakis2008; among others). In this study, the interest falls on the effect of incentives on religious behavior in the sense that they increase (decrease) individual religious performance.

Religious practice can be encouraged by two types of incentives: earthly ones and afterlife ones.

  • Earthly incentives. These incentives are associated with social or professional rewards (Azzi & Ehrenberg, Reference Azzi and Ehrenberg1975). Economic speculations suggest that subsidies for religious schools, favorable tax schemes for the religious sector, or the social recognition of neighbors could encourage religious activity. Furthermore, churches are good places to build social links and increase professional opportunities, therefore encouraging church-attendance.

  • Afterlife incentives. This type of incentive is linked to rewards in the afterlife, that is, rewards that will be obtained after death. Individuals may view their expected afterlife consumption as being related to their current participation in church related activities (attendance, prayer, financial religious contributions and others). Individual beliefs on afterlife probabilities play a crucial role in this earthly investment.

This paper addresses the second group. Previous studies have analyzed the effects of “afterlife incentives” on religious behavior. Azzi and Ehrenberg (Reference Azzi and Ehrenberg1975) were the first to propose and test a theoretical model of afterlife religious capital.Footnote 1 They analyzed the determinants of participation in religious activities using a utility-maximizing model. Among other results, they found afterlife beliefs to be a major determinant of church attendance. Using several surveys carried out in the United States, they provided empirical support for their theory.

Blomberg et al. (Reference Blomberg, DeLeire and Hess2006) developed a model where financial religious contributions are motivated by both current consumption and afterlife considerations. They show that afterlife considerations play an important role in explaining financial religious contributions.

Pyne (Reference Pyne2010) studied the relationship between religiosity and the fear of death. He found that individuals who place a higher probability on the existence of an afterlife invest more in religious capital.

Recently, Brañas-Garza et al. (Reference Brañas-Garza, García-Muñoz and Neuman2010) estimated the role of afterlife beliefs in the production of religious commodities, concretely, church attendance and prayer. Using ordered logit regressions, they found that afterlife beliefs are crucial determinants but, more importantly, that beliefs in heaven are much more relevant than beliefs in hell: positive incentives are stronger than negative ones. However, this regression approach does not allow us to study the joint effect of positive and negative incentives. When the logit model contains interactions (among variables) two problems appear: i) the computation of partial effects becomes problematic; ii) the interpretation of these estimate effects is not straightforward. As showed in Norton et al. (Reference Norton, Wang and Ai2004) the estimated coefficients of the interaction terms do not reflect the interaction effect; moreover their statistical significance cannot be tested through a simple t-test. Even more problematic is the interpretation given that the estimated interaction effect is also conditional on the current value of the other independent variables. Hence, we cannot properly study the meaning of different interactions in a logit regression model.

This paper presents a different statistical tool — the stochastic dominance approach (Levy, Reference Levy1998) — that allows the use and the straightforward interpretation of the joint effect of positive and negative incentives. Our analyses confirm the main results showed in Brañas-Garza et al. (Reference Brañas-Garza, García-Muñoz and Neuman2010) and revises the interactive effects among positive and negative incentives. In an easy and graphical way we show that afterlife incentives play a crucial role in religious performance, comparing not only and positive or negative incentives but combination of both are compared.

The study was carried out on Catholic people. In the Catholic religion, church attendance and prayer are strategies that lead to heaven and prevent hell. Church attendance and prayer are two dimensions of religiosity that reflect public religious activities versus private/intimate prayer activities. While church attendance also has non-religious motives such as networking and the building of social ties, private prayer activity has more pure religious motives.

Using a stochastic dominance approach, we ask whether absolute beliefs in eternal bliss (heaven) and in eternal damnation (hell) increase individual’s religious investment as reflected in church attendance and prayer, and whether absolute belief in eternal damnation (hell) is a more or less powerful incentive than eternal bliss (heaven) for intensified religious effort.

2 Sample and variables used in the study

The data were drawn from the module on National Identity of the 1998 International Social Survey Program (ISSP): Religion II. The survey contains questions about attitude and beliefs, specifically:

  • “How often do you attend religious services at a church?” This question has six options: (1) never; (2) once a year; (3) two or three times a year; (4) once a month; (5) two or three times a month; and (6) at least once a week.

  • “How often do you pray?” This question has eleven alternative categories: (1) never; (2) once a year; (3) twice a year; (4) a few times a year; (5) about once a month; (6) two or three times a month; (7) almost every week; (8) every week; (9) several times a week; (10) once a day; and (11) several times a day.

  • “Do you believe in life after death?”

  • “Do you believe in heaven?”

  • “Do you believe in hell?”

The last three questions have the same four options: (1) yes, definitely; (2) yes, probably; (3) no, probably not; and (4) no, definitely not.

The promise of an afterlife serves as an incentive for believers to engage in religious behavior. Those who definitely believe in heaven are confident that they will be highly rewarded, thus belief in heaven can be considered a positive incentive (with p=1). On the opposite side, those who definitely believe in hell are confident that they will be highly punished after death. Therefore, belief in hell can be considered a negative incentive (with p=1).

After excluding respondents who did not answer some of the questions, the final dataset was comprised of about 10,840 Catholic subjects. Table 1 shows their distribution of beliefs:

Table 1: Distributions of beliefs for Catholics (%)

Table 1 reveals that afterlife incentives are important (the largest category is shown in bold). As can be seen, individuals are concerned with what happens after death, although the people that believe in a reward (heaven) are much more numerous than those who believe in a punishment (hell). On average, subjects are optimistic regarding afterlife outcomes.

Concerning beliefs about heaven and hell, Table 2 shows the contingency table of the responses by 10,840 subjects.

Table 2: Contingency table of responses of 10,840 subjects

Since we focus only on people who definitely believe or definitely do not believe (that is, the subjects appearing in bold in Table 2), the sample is reduced to 5,013 subjects.

Hence, we define a 2x2 factors design according to the type of incentives affecting subjects. As shown in Table 2 (in bold), we have:

  • Respondents affected by both types of incentives: positive and negative. They definitely believe in heaven (positive) and hell (negative). [n=2,726]

  • Respondents with positive incentives only. They definitely believe in heaven, but do not believe in hell at all. [n=377]

  • Respondents with no incentives. They do not believe in heaven or hell at all. [n=1,899]

  • Respondents with negative incentives only. They definitely believe in hell, but do not believe in heaven at all. Due to the small size of this group, it has been dropped. [n=11]

Using a stochastic dominance approach and the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test, we compare individual religious performance (church attendance and prayer) according to the type of incentive affecting each person. Basically, we compare the respondents with both types of incentives versus respondents with only positive incentives versus respondents with no incentives.

3 Stochastic dominance

Stochastic dominance is an abbreviated term for first-order stochastic dominance, which refers to a set of relations that may hold between a pair of distributions (Levy, Reference Levy1998). Stochastic dominance is usually applied to the analysis of income distribution and income inequality (for example, Davidson, Reference Davidson, Durlauf and Blume2006, and Davidson & Duclos, Reference Davidson and Duclos2000). The concept can, however, be applied in many other domains. Concretely, we can study the effectiveness of several incentives on church attendance and prayer using the stochastic dominance relation between the distributions of these two variables generated by these incentives.

In order to determine whether a relation of stochastic dominance holds between two distributions, the distributions are first characterized by their Cumulative Distribution Functions (CDF). For instance, in the previous section we saw that the question about church attendance has 6 response levels ranging from “never (1)” to “at least once a week (6)”. For a given sample, the value of the CDF at level a is the proportion of subjects in the sample that do not go to church more than a.

Suppose we find the following “radical” situation. We have two different samples of subjects. The people in the first sample are not so religious (in terms of church attendance), while in the second sample, subjects attend church very frequently. The relative frequencies and CDFs for each level of church attendance for both samples are presented in Table 3.

Table 3: Relative frequencies and CDFs for each level of church attendance for both samples

Clearly, the second sample contains subjects who engage in religious practices with greater frequency. Figure 1 shows the cumulative distribution functions of these two samples.

Figure 1: Cumulative distribution functions of religious frequency for two samples.

Let us now introduce the concept of stochastic dominance.

Definition 1

Suppose that we consider two distributions A and B, characterized respectively by the cumulative distribution functions F A and F B. Then distribution B dominates distribution A stochastically (at the first order) if, for any argument a, F B(a)≤ F A(a).

In our example, inequality is F 2 (a)F 1 (a), for all a, that is, the distribution of church attendance in the second sample stochastically dominates (is always below) the distribution in sample 1. This means that the proportion of subjects in each level in F 2 is always less than or equal to the proportion of subjects in each level in F 1.

In other words, Sample 2 is formed by more religious people (in terms of church attendance) than Sample 1. For this reason we say that the second sample “dominates” the first one since Sample 2 has more subjects in the upper categories of the ordinal variable we are studying (church attendance)Footnote 2.

With this type of data, where the distribution functions do not cross in any point, the criterion of first order dominance allow to compare the behavior of several sub-samples in an easy and graphical way. In addition, this method does not demand any hypothesis about the distribution shape, and it uses all the points of the distribution.

In the next section we use this approach to explore the effect of incentives on religious performance.

4 Incentives on religious performance

In Section 2 we selected 5,002 Catholic subjects who definitely believe or definitely do not believe in heaven and hell. The subjects have been divided into three samples according to what types of incentives (beliefs) affect them: people affected by both incentives (heaven and hell), people affected by the positive incentive only (heaven) and people with no incentives. In Tables 4 and 5, the CDFs of church attendance and prayer are given for the three samples:

Table 4: CDFs of attendance

Table 5: CDFs of prayer

Figures 2 and 3 show the cumulative distribution functions. In both figures, the “both incentives” distribution was found to stochastically dominate the “no incentives” and “positive incentives” distributions. Moreover, the “positive incentives” distribution stochastically dominates the “no incentives” distribution. At all attendance and prayer levels, the CDF values of “both incentives” are smaller than the CDF values of the other two samples. As we explained in Section 3, this means that there is a higher proportion of practicing subjects (church attendance and prayer) among people who are affected by negative and positive incentives than in the other groups.

Figure 2: CDFs for attendance

Figure 3: CDFs for prayer

The differences between distributions can be statistically corroborated using the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test.Footnote 3 In Table 6 we present the statistics and significance of this test to compare the distributions of church attendance and prayer among the three samples:

In sum, we find that:

  1. 1. The effects of “both (positive and negative) incentives” are different from “positive incentives only”;

  2. 2. The effects of “positive incentives only” are different from “no incentives”.

Furthermore, the positive incentives effect is large, whereas the negative incentives effect is smaller. We obtain this result by comparing the net effects of “both incentives” versus the net effect of “positive incentives only”. When we remove the “negative incentives” effect, that is, when we jump from the “both incentives” sample to the “positive incentives” sample, attendance and prayer distributions are closer than when we remove the “both incentives” effect, that is, when we jump from the “positive incentives” sample to the “no incentives” sample. This can be viewed graphically in Figures 2 and 3 and by numerically calculating the mean differences between the CDF values.

For attendance distribution, the Mean Differences (MD) are:Footnote 4

We observe that the distance between the “positive incentives” distribution and the “no incentives” distribution is larger than the distance between the “positive incentives” and “both incentives” distributions.

For prayer distribution, the mean differences are:

The “positive incentives” effect is stronger for prayer than for attendance distribution. When we only remove the “negative incentives” effect (jumping from the “both incentives” sample to the “positive incentives” sample), the behavior of the prayer distribution is similar in both samples (the MD between both CDFs is 7.93).

Table 6: Kolmogorov-Smirnov tests (p-values in parentheses). Positive incentives only

5 Conclusions

Using a stochastic dominance approach and a dataset of 10,840 Catholic subjects, we have illustrated that incentives have a major effect on religious behavior and that positive incentives have a much stronger effect than negative ones when both types of incentives are available. This result is similar to the one proposed in the cooperation experiments described in Andreoni et al. (Reference Andreoni, Harbaugh and Vesterlund2003) and contributes to the robustness of the estimated effects of positive/negative religious incentives in Brañas-Garza et al. (Reference Brañas-Garza, García-Muñoz and Neuman2010).

Therefore we may conclude that:

  1. 1. Positive and negative incentives have a crucial effect on decisions.

  2. 2. The size of positive incentives is much larger than the size of negative incentives.

  3. 3. The size of the joint effect of positive and negative incentives is much larger than both effects separately.

In sum, our study supports the pronounced effectiveness of positive rewards, but finds no large effects for punishment. Hence we may conclude that the Catholic Church could be much more successful in their performance (aggregate behavior) if it were to promote heavensward activities rather than the fear of God.

Footnotes

*

Financial support was from the MCI (SEJ2007–62081/ECON), Junta de Andalucía-Excelencia (P07.SEJ.02547) and Instituto de la Mujer (2007 I+D+I/031). I wish to thank the editor J. Baron and P. Brañas for helpful suggestions.

1 Of course, Pascal’s wager (Pascal, Reference Pascal1670, note 233) was a theoretical model, indeed perhaps the first statement of expected-utility theory, but stated as an argument for living the Christian life and not as an empirical claim about religious belief.

2 Note, however, that the graph of Sample 1 overlaps the graph of Sample 2 in Figure 1.

3 The Kolmogorov-Smirnov test is a nonparametric test to compare two samples. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov statistic quantifies a distance between the distribution functions of two samples. The null distribution of this statistic is calculated under the null hypothesis that the samples are drawn from the same distribution.

4 Observe that the CDF value in the last category is always 100.

References

Andreoni, J., Harbaugh, W., & Vesterlund, L. (2003). The carrot or the stick: rewards, punishments, and cooperation. American Economic Review, 93, 893902.10.1257/000282803322157142CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azzi, C. & Ehrenberg, R. (1975). Household allocation of time and church attendance. The Journal of Political Economy, 83, 2756.10.1086/260305CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brañas-Garza, P., García-Muñoz, T. & Neuman, S. (2010, forthcoming). The big carrot: high-stake incentives revisited. Journal of Behavioural Decision Making. 10.1002/bdm.657CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomberg, S., DeLeire, T. & Hess, G. D. (2006). The afterlife-cycle theory of religious contributions. CESinfo Working Paper no. 1854.Google Scholar
Davidson, R. (2006). Stochastic dominance. The new Palgrave dictionary of Economics. Second Edition. Eds. Durlauf, Steven N. and Blume, Lawrence E.. Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Davidson, R., & Duclos, J. Y. (2000). Statistical inference for stochastic dominance and for the measurement of poverty and inequality. Econometrica, 68, 14351464.10.1111/1468-0262.00167CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, H. (1998). Stochastic dominance. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Norwell, MA.10.1007/978-1-4757-2840-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nikiforakis, N. (2008). Punishment and counter-punishment in public good games: can we really govern ourselves? Journal of Public Economics, 92, 91112.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.04.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton, E. C., Wang, H. & Ai, C. (2004). Computing interaction effects and standard errors in logit and probit models. The Stata Journal, 4, 154167.10.1177/1536867X0400400206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pascal, B. (1670). Pensées de M. Pascal sur la religion, et sur quelques autres sujets.Google Scholar
Pyne, D. (2010). A model of religion and death. Journal of Socio-Economics, 39, 4654.Google Scholar
Slonim, R., & Roth, A. E. (1998). Learning in high-stakes ultimatum games: an experiment in the Slovak Republic. Econometrica, 66, 569596.10.2307/2998575CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: a reference dependent model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 10391061.10.2307/2937956CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1: Distributions of beliefs for Catholics (%)

Figure 1

Table 2: Contingency table of responses of 10,840 subjects

Figure 2

Table 3: Relative frequencies and CDFs for each level of church attendance for both samples

Figure 3

Figure 1: Cumulative distribution functions of religious frequency for two samples.

Figure 4

Table 4: CDFs of attendance

Figure 5

Table 5: CDFs of prayer

Figure 6

Figure 2: CDFs for attendance

Figure 7

Figure 3: CDFs for prayer

Figure 8

Table 6: Kolmogorov-Smirnov tests (p-values in parentheses). Positive incentives only