Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T04:04:11.790Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

How can the History of Economic thought Contribute to an Understanding of Institutional Change?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

Since Moses Abramovitz's “classic” paper on “Catching-Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind” (1986) economists have become increasingly aware again of the significance of “social capability” for processes of economic change. During the past twenty years much research has been done on “soft” determinants of development and growth. Especially some of the so-called new institutionalists and evolutionary economists have now returned to the roots of the institutional research program by acknowledging that “ideas matter” in the process of institutional change. However, it is still often overlooked in the literature that the cognition of social reality is deeply intertwined with the general world-view prevailing in a given society. Certainly, such general world-views are partly determined by the level of economic and technological development, but they are also a reflection of deeply rooted cultural traditions. In particular, the highly divergent outcomes of economic and political transition in the formerly socialist countries of Central and Eastern Europe have brought the connection between culture, ideas, and institutions to the fore again (see, for example, Winiecki 2004). Therefore it is all but an accident that it is one of the leading transition experts who has recently called on economists to “seek a better understanding of the role of values and norms in shaping both ideas and institutions” (Roland 2004, p. 128).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Abramovitz, Moses (1986) Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind, The Journal of Economic History, 46 (2), pp. 385406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexander, Jeffrey C. (Ed) (1990) Differentiation Theory and Social Change: Comparative and Historical Perspectives (New York: Columbia University Press).Google Scholar
Arnason, Johann P. (2000) Communism and Modernity, Deadalus, 129 (Winter), pp. 6190.Google Scholar
Backhaus, Juergen (Ed) (1993) Gustav Schmoller und die Probleme von heute (Berlin: Duncker & Humblot).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Badie, Bertrand (1992) The Imported State: The Westernization of the Political Order (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2000).Google Scholar
Balabkins, Nicholas W. (1988) Not by Theory Alone: The Economics of Gustav Schmoller and its Legacy to America (Berlin: Duncker & Humblot).Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark (1998). Economic Theory in Retrospect, 5th edition (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Blyth, Mark (2002) Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brette, Olivier (2003) Thorstein Veblen's Theory of Institutional Change: Beyond Technological Determinism, The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 10 (Autumn), pp. 455–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brubaker, Rogers (1984) The Limits of Rationality: An Essay on the Social and Moral Thought of Max Weber (London: Routledge, 1991).Google Scholar
Bulgakov, Sergei N. (1911) Srednevekovyi ideal i noveyshaya kul'tura, in Bulgakov, Sergey N., Dva Grada: Issledovaniya o prirode obshchestvennych idealov (St. Petersburg: Izdatel'svto Christiyanskogo Gumanitarnogo Instituta, 1997), pp. 95110.Google Scholar
Caravale, Giovanni A. (1997) Equilibrium and Economic Theory (London: Routledge).Google Scholar
Chistyakov, Oleg I. (Ed) (1998) Reformy Aleksandra II (Moscow: Yuridicheskaya literatura).Google Scholar
Choi, Young-back (1993) Paradigms and Conventions: Uncertainty, Decision Making and Entrepreneurship (Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Jong, Martin et al. (Eds) (2002) The Theory and Practice of Institutional Transplantation. Experiences with the Transfer of Policy Institutions (Dorderecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T. and North, Douglass C. (1994) Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions, Kyklos, 47 (1), pp. 331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dequech, David (2002) The Demarcation Between the “Old” and the “New” Institutional Economics: Recent Complications, Journal of Economic Issues, 36 (2), pp. 565–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
di Zerega, Gus (1989) Democracy as a Spontaneous Order, Critical Review, 3 (2), pp. 206–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Djankov, Simeon et al. (2003) The New Comparative Economics, Journal of Comparative Economics, 31 (4), pp. 595619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egidi, Massimo and Rizello, Salvatore (Eds) (2004) Cognitive Economics, 2 vols. (Cheltenham: Elgar).Google Scholar
Gadzhiyev, Komaludin (1996) Totalitarismus als Phänomen des 20. Jahrhunderts, in: Maier, Hans (Ed) “Totalitarismus” und “politische Religionen”: Konzepte des Diktaturvergleichs (Paderborn: Schoningh), pp. 335–56.Google Scholar
Garrouste, Pierre (Ed) (2001) Evolution and Path Dependence in Economic Ideas: Past and Present (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschenkron, Alexander (1969) History of Economic Doctrines and Economic History, Papers and Proceedings of the American Economic Association, 59 (2), pp. 117.Google Scholar
Goldstein, Judith S. and Keohane, Robert O. (Eds) (1993) Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change (Ithaca: Cornell University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harada, Tetsushi (2004) Adam Müllers Staats- und Wirtschaftslehre (Marburg: Metropolis).Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1944) The Road to Serfdom (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994).Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1988) The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press; London: Routledge).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2001) How Economics Forgot History (London: Routledge).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2004) The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure and Darwinism in American Institutionalism (London: Routledge).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubatsch, Walther (1977) Die Stein-Hardenbergschen Reformen, 2nd edition (Darmstadt: Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft, 1989).Google Scholar
Janssen, Hauke (2000) Nationalökonomie und Nationalsozialismus: Die deutsche Volkswirtschaftslehre in den dreiβiger Jahren, 2nd edition (Marburg: Metropolis).Google Scholar
Janssen, Hauke (2004). Russische Ökonomen in Deutschland (1910–1933) (Marburg: Metropolis).Google Scholar
Kalberg, Stephen (1994) Max Weber's Comparative-Historical Sociology (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1936) The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money (London: Macmillan, 1960).Google Scholar
Kitschelt, Herbert (2003) Accounting for Post-communist Regime Diversity: What Counts as a Good Cause? in: Ekiert, Grzegorz and Hanson, Stephen E. (Eds), Capitalism and Democracy in Central and Eastern Europe: Assessing the Legacy of Communist Rule (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), pp. 4986.Google Scholar
Koshelyov, Alexander I. (1857) O zamene obyazannoi raboty nayomnoyu i o pozemel'noi obshchinnoi sobstvennosti, Russkaya beseda, No. 4,’ pervaya, pp. 109–71.Google Scholar
Louçã, Francisco and Perlman, Mark (Eds) (2000) Is Economics an Evolutionary Science? The Legacy of Thorstein Veblen (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martens, Bertin (2004) The Cognitive Mechanics of Economic Development and Institutional Change (London: Routledge).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mironov, Boris N. (2000) The Social History of Imperial Russia 1700–1917 (Boulder, CO: Westview Press).Google Scholar
Müller, Adam (1809) Die Elemente der Staatskunst, 2 vols. (Jena: Fischer, 1922).Google Scholar
Mun, Thomas (1664) England's Treasure by Forraign Trade: Or, The Ballance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of our Treasure (Düsseldorf: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen, 1989).Google Scholar
Nau, Heino H. (2000) Gustav Schmoller's historico-ethical Political Economy: Ethics, Politics and Economics in the Younger German Historical School, The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 7 (12), pp. 507–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nau, Heino H. and Schefold, Bertram (Eds) (2002) The Historicity of Economics. Continuities and Discontinuities of Historical Thought in 19th and 20th Century Economics (Berlin: Springer).Google Scholar
Nienhaus, Volker (1999) Kultur und Wirtschaftsstil—Erklärungsansätze für die Systemdynamik und Systemeffizienz in Entwicklungsländern?, in: Cassel, Dieter (Ed) Perspektiven der Systemforschung (Berlin: Duncker & Humblot), pp. 89118.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1997) The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics to an Understanding of the Transition Problem (Helsinki: WIDER Annual Lectures, No 1).Google Scholar
O'Hara, Phillip A. (2000) Marx, Veblen, and Contemporary Institutional Political Economy: Principles and Unstable Dynamics of Capitalism (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oleinik, Anton (2005) Transfer of Institutions: Actors and Constraints— the Russian Case in a Global Context (Hamburg: HWWA Discussion Paper No. 320).Google Scholar
Pelikan, Pavel and Wegner, Gerhard (Eds) (2003) The Evolutionary Analysis of Economic Policy (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perlman, Mark and McCann, Charles R. Jr. (1998) The Pillars of Economic Understanding: Ideas and Traditions (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peukert, Helge (2001) The Schmoller Renaissance, History of Political Economy, 33 (Spring), pp. 71116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pipes, Richard (1991) The Russian Revolution (New York: Vintage Books).Google Scholar
Polterovich, Viktor M. (2001) Transplantatsiyañekonomicheskikh institutov, Ekonomicheskaya nauka sovremennoi Rossii, (2001/3), pp. 2450.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl (1960) The Poverty of Historicism, 2nd edition (London: Routledge).Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl (1944) The Great Transformation (New York: Octagon Books, 1975).Google Scholar
Pribram, Karl (1917/1918) Die Weltanschauungen der Völker und ihre Politik, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, 44, pp. 161–97.Google Scholar
Pribram, Karl (1949) Conflicting Patterns of Thought (Washington D.C.: Public Affairs Press).Google Scholar
Pribram, Karl (1951) Prolegomena to a History of Economic Reasoning, in Karl Pribram, A History of Economic Reasoning (Baltimore and London: John Hopkins University Press, 1983), pp. 585609.Google Scholar
Pribram, Karl (1983) A History of Economic Reasoning (Baltimore and London: John Hopkins University Press).Google Scholar
Priddat, Birger P. (1995) Die andere Ökonomie. Eine neue Einschätzung von Gustav Schmollers Versuch einer “ethisch-historischen” Nationalökonomie im 19. Jahrhundert (Marburg: Metropolis).Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel (1963) On the Relations between Politics and Economics, in: Lionel Robbins, Papers in Political Economy (London: Macmillan), pp. 326.Google Scholar
Robinson, Joan (1962), Economic Philosophy (London: Watts).Google Scholar
Roland, Gérard (2004) Understanding Institutional Change: Fast-Moving and Slow-Moving Institutions, Studies in Comparative International Development, 38 (Winter), pp. 109–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, Emma (2001) Economic Sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet, and the Enlightenment (Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcom (1994) Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salin, Edgar (1932) Wirtschaft und Staat: Drei Schriften zur deutschen Weltlage (Berlin: Hobbing).Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. (1974) The History of Economic Thought as Intellectual History, in: Blaug, Mark (Ed) The Historiography of Economics (Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 1991), pp. 106–24.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. (1977) Ideology in Economics, in: Weintraub, Sidney (Ed) Modern Economic Thought (Philadelphia: University of Philadelphia Press), pp. 467–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. (Ed) (1998). The Founding of Institutional Economics: The Leisure Class and Sovereignty (London: Routledge).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schimank, Uwe (2000) Theorien gesellschaftlicher Differenzierung (Opladen: Leske & Budrich).Google Scholar
Schluchter, Wolfgang (1976) Die Paradoxie der Rationalisierung. Zum Verhältnis von “Ethik” und “Welt” bei Max Weber, Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 5 (3), pp. 256–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmoller, Gustav (1881) über Zwecke und Ziele des Jahrbuchs, in: Nau, Heino H. (Ed), Gustav Schmoller: Historisch-ethische Nationalökonomie als Kulturwissenschaft. Ausgewählte methodologische Schriften (Marburg: Metropolis, 1998), pp. 97114.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1954) History of Economic Analysis (London: George Allan & Unwin, 1967).Google Scholar
Seabright, Paul (2004) The Company of Strangers: A Natural History of Economic Life (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Shionoya, Yūichi (1997) Schumpeter and the Idea of Social Science: A Metatheoretical Study (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shionoya, Yūichi (2005) The Soul of the German Historical School: Methodological Essays on Schmoller, Weber and Schumpeter (New York: Springer).Google Scholar
Sikking, Kathryn (1991) Ideas and Institutions: Developmentalism in Argentina and Brazil (Ithaca: Cornell University Press).Google Scholar
Simmel, Georg (1900) The Philosophy of Money, 2nd edition (London: Routledge, 2001).Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1790) The Theory of Moral Sentiments, 6th edition, edited by Raphael, David D. and Macfie, Alec L. (Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Press, 1982).Google Scholar
Sombart, Werner (1932) Die Zukunft des Kapitalismus (Berlin: Buchholz & Weisswange).Google Scholar
Spengler, Joseph J. (1960) The Problem of Order in Economic Affairs, in: Spengler, Joseph J. and Allen, William A. (Eds) Essays in Economic Thought: Aristotle to Marshall (Chicago: Rand McNally), pp. 633.Google Scholar
Stolper, Gustav (1940) The German Economy 1870–1940: Issues and Trends (London: Allen & Unwin).Google Scholar
Streit, Manfred et al. (Eds) (2000) Cognition, Rationality, and Institutions (Berlin: Springer).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tenbruck, Friedrich (1959a) Die Genesis der Methodologie Max Webers, in: Friedrich Tenbruck, Das Werk Max Webers: Gesammelte Aufsätze zu Max Weber (Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck, 1999), pp. 158.Google Scholar
Tenbruck, Friedrich (1959b) Das Werk Max Webers, in: Friedrich Tenbruck, Das Werk Max Webers: Gesammelte Aufsätze zu Max Weber (Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck, 1999), pp. 5998.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1958) From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, Gerth, Hans Heinrich and Mills, C. Wright (Eds) (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Winiecki, Jan (2004) Determinants of Catching Up or Falling Behind: Interaction of Formal and Informal Institutions, Post-Communist Economies, 16 (2), pp. 137–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woods, Ngaire (1996) Economic Ideas and International Relations: Beyond Rational Neglect, International Studies Quarterly, 39 (06), pp. 161–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wohlgemuth, Michael (2002) Evolutionary Approaches to Politics, Kyklos, 55 (2), pp. 223–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhukhov, Nikolai S. (1996) Matematicheskaya ekonomiya v Rossii (1865–1995) (Moscow: Nauka).Google Scholar
Zweynert, Joachim (2002a) Eine Geschichte des ökonomischen Denkens in Ruβland: 1805–1905 (Marburg: Metropolis).Google Scholar
Zweynert, Joachim (2002b) Eine systemtheoretische Neuformulierung des Wirtschaftsstilkonzepts. Geldwirtschaft und Machtwirtschaft als stiltheoretische Idealtypen, Schmollers Jahrbuch, 122 (3), pp. 415–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zweynert, Joachim (2006) Shared Mental Models, Catch-up Development and Economic Policy-Making: The Cases of Germany after World War II and its significance Contemporary Russia, Eastern Economic Journal, 32 (3), pp. 457478.Google Scholar
Zweynert, Joachim and Goldschmidt, Nils (2006) The two transitions in central and eastern europe as process of institutional transplantation, Journal of Economic Issues, XL (4), pp. 895918.CrossRefGoogle Scholar