Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T08:46:04.589Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

CHARLES RICHARD DE BUTRÉ: PIONEER OF MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 August 2016

Loïc Charles
Affiliation:
University of Paris 8 Saint-Denis (Led/EA 3391) and Ined, [email protected].
Christine Théré
Affiliation:

Abstract

Historians of economics have acknowledged the significant role François Quesnay and the Physiocrats played in the early development of mathematical economics. It is, however, important to note that although the Tableau économique could well be translated into algebra, Quesnay never did it. As part of our research on Charles Richard de Butré, an obscure collaborator of François Quesnay, we have uncovered documents that show that he was one Physiocrat who did use algebra to explain his theoretical conceptions. In two texts written at the end of 1766 and the beginning of 1767, Butré systematically used algebra as an aid for economic reasoning. Our argument is that these texts provide very interesting insights into the development of early mathematical economics.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Badinter, Elisabeth. 1999–2007. Les Passions intellectuelles. Three volumes. Paris: Fayard.Google Scholar
Barna, Tibor. 1975. “Quesnay’s Tableau in Modern Guise.” Economic Journal 85: 485496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barna, Tibor. 1976. “Quesnay’s Model of Economic Development.” European Economic Review 8 (4): 315338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brockliss, Laurence W. B. 1987. French Higher Education in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Butré, Charles Richard de. 1767. Elémens d’oeconomie politique. Tours: Archives Départementales d’Indre-et-Loire, box C 101.Google Scholar
Camus, Charles-Etienne-Louis. 1749–1752. Cours de mathématique. Four volumes. Paris: Ballard fils.Google Scholar
Castel, Louis-Bertrand. 1728. Mathematique universelle, abregee a l’usage et a la portée de tout le monde; Principalement des jeunes Seigneurs, Ingenieurs, Physiciens, Artistes &c. Paris: Pierre Simon.Google Scholar
Charles, Loïc, and Théré, Christine. 2016. “Charles Richard de Butré: An Economist in the Shadow of François Quesnay.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 38 (2): 131152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clairaut, Alexis-Claude. 1746. Elemens d’algèbre. Paris: frères Guerin, David l’aîné, Durand.Google Scholar
D’Alembert, Jean le Rond. 1751. “Analyse.” In Encyclopédie, ou dictionnaire raisonné des sciences et des arts et métiers. Volume 1. Paris: Briasson, pp. 400403.Google Scholar
Duclos, Jean-Baptiste. 1737. Elemens de mathematiques contenant les elemens de Geometrie, d’Arithmetique, d’Algebre & d’Analise. Lyon: Perroti.Google Scholar
Eltis, Walter. 1975. “François Quesnay: A Reinterpretation. 1. The Tableau économique.” Oxford Economic Papers 27 (2): 167200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gherke, Christian, and Kurz, Heinz. 1995. “Karl Marx on Physiocracy.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 2 (1): 5390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hankins, Thomas L. 1985. Science and the Enlightenment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hishiyama, Izumi. 1960. “The Tableau économique of Quesnay.” Kyoto University Economic Review 30 (1): 146.Google Scholar
Isnard, Achille-Nicolas. 1781. Traité des richesses. Two volumes. London, Lausanne: F. Grasset.Google Scholar
Knies, Carl, ed. 1892. Carl Friedrichs von Baden. Brieflicher verkehr mit Mirabeau und Du Pont. Two volumes. Heidelberg: Carl Winter’s Universitätbuchhandlung.Google Scholar
Leontiev, Wassily W. 1936. “Quantitative Input and Output Relations in the Economic System of the United States.” Review of Economics and Statistics 18 (3): 105125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Longhitano, Gino. 2012. “The Library of François Quesnay.” In Longhitano, Gino and Cartelier, Jean, eds., Quesnay and Physiocracy. Studies and Materials. Paris: L’Harmattan, pp. 193240.Google Scholar
Lynn, Michael R. 2006. Popular Science and Public Opinion in Eighteenth-Century France. Manchester, New York: Manchester University Press & Palgrave.Google Scholar
Mazéas, Jean-Mathurin. 1758. Elémens d’arithmétique, d’algèbre et de géométrie, avec une introduction aux sections coniques. Paris: Lemercier.Google Scholar
Meek, Ronald L. [1962] 1993. “Problems of the Tableau économique.” In The Economics of Physiocracy. Fairfield, NJ: Augustus M. Kelley, pp. 265296.Google Scholar
Orain, Arnaud. Forthcoming. “A Science of Ratios. The Analytical Economics of Jean-Joseph-Louis Graslin (1767).” In Kaplan, Steven L. and Reinert, Sophus, eds., The Economic Enlightenment and the Critique of Physiocracy.Google Scholar
Phillips, Almarin. 1955. “The Tableau économique as a Simple Leontief Model.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 69 (1): 134144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popov, Pavel I. [1926] 1964. “Introduction to the Balance of the National Economy.” In Spulber, N., ed., Foundations of Soviet Strategy for Economic Growth. Selected Soviet Essays, 1924–1930. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, pp. 519.Google Scholar
Pressman, Steven. 1994. Quesnay’s Tableau économique. A Critique and Reassessment. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Quesnay, François. 2005. Œuvres économiques complètes de François Quesnay et autres textes. Edited by Théré, Christine, Charles, Loïc, and Perrot, Jean-Claude. Two volumes. Paris: INED.Google Scholar
Rivard, Dominique-François. 1732. Elémens de géométrie, avec un abrégé d’arithmétique et d’algèbre. Paris: Henry.Google Scholar
Robertson, Ross M. 1949. “Mathemathical Economics before Cournot.” Journal of Political Economy 57 (6): 523536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1954] 1987. History of Economic Analysis. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Steenge, Albert E., and Van den Berg, Richard. 2001. “Generalising the Tableau économique; Isnard’s Système des richesses.” International Journal of Applied Economics and Econometrics 9 (2): 121146.Google Scholar
Steenge, Albert E., and Van Den Berg, Richard. 2007. “Transcribing the Tableau Economique: Input-Output Analysis à la Quesnay.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 29 (3): 331358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spiegel, Henry W., ed. 1955. Pierre Samuel Du Pont de Nemours: On Economic Curves. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Taton, René, ed. 1964. Enseignement et diffusion des sciences au XVIIIe siècle. Paris: EPHE.Google Scholar
Theocharis, Reghinos D. 1961. Early Developments in Mathematical Economics. Philadelphia: Porcupine Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Théré, Christine. 1998. “Political Economy and its Authors before 1789.” In Faccarello, Gilbert, ed., From Bodin to Walras. Studies in the History of French Political Economy. London, New York: Routledge, pp. 156.Google Scholar
Turgot, Anne-Robert-Jacques. [1766] 1914. [Letter to Du Pont, 22 December 1766]. In Schelle, G., ed., Œuvres de Turgot et documents le concernant. Volume 2. Paris: F. Alcan, pp. 520521.Google Scholar
Van den Berg, Richard. 2006. At the Origin of Mathematical Economics. The Economics of A. N. Isnard (1748–1803). London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Véron de Forbonnais, François. 1753. “Change.” In Encyclopédie, ou dictionnaire raisonné de sciences et des arts et métiers. Volumes 3. Paris: Briasson, pp. 127131.Google Scholar