Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T02:04:55.520Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Adam Smith's Influence on Hegel's Philosophical Writings

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

Historians of economics and philosophy have noted Georg Wilhelm Fredrich Hegel's debt to Adam Smith and have suggested that Hegel's analysis of civil society rests on a Smithian foundation. Laurence Dickey recognized that “Hegel's interest in the Scots coincided with the late eighteenth-century German interest in the relationship between socioeconomic processes in history and the development of civil institutions” (Dickey 1987, p. 194). Georg Lukacs emphasized that “it is highly probable that the study of Adam Smith was a turning-point in Hegel's evolution” (Lukacs 1976, p. 172). In his study of The Formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx, Ernest Mandel maintained that Marx discovered political economy and its importance to philosophy in his reading of Hegel. Says Mandel:

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Avineri, Shlomo. 1972. Hegel's Theory of the Modern State, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellamy, R. P. 1987. “Hegelianism,” in The New Palgrave, 2, 635–36, edited by John, Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman, The Macmillan Press Limited, London.Google Scholar
Bonar, James. 1932. A Catalogue of the Library of Adam Smith, 2nd edition, reprint 1966, Augustus Kelley, New York.Google Scholar
Chamley, Paul. 1963. Economie Politique et Philosophie chez Steuart et Hegel, Dalloz, Paris.Google Scholar
Chamley, Paul. 1965. “Les Origines de la pensee economique de Hegel,Hegel Studien, Band 3, 225–61.Google Scholar
Dickey, Laurence. 1987. Hegel: Religion, Economics, and the Politics of Spirit, 1770–1807, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fay, C. R. 1956. Adam Smith and the Scotland of His Day, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, Peter. 1987. “Division of Labour” in The New Palgrave, 1, 7901, edited by John, Eatwell, Murray, Milgate and Peter, Newman, The Macmillan Press Limited, London.Google Scholar
Hegel, G. W. F. 1956. The Philosophy of History, translated by Sibree, J., Dover Publications, New York.Google Scholar
Hegel, G. W. F.. 1942. The Philosophy of Right, translated by Knox, T. M., Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Hegel, G. W. F.. 1979. “Philosophy of Spirit 1803–04,” System of Ethical Life (1802/3) and First Philosophy of Spirit [Part III of the System of Speculative Philosophy 1803/4], edited and translated by Harris, H. S. and Knox, T. M., State University of New York Press, Albany. [Cited as Jenenser Realphilosophie I].Google Scholar
Hegel, G. W. F.. 1983. “Philosophy of Spirit (1805–06),” Hegel and the Human Spirit, translated by Leo, Rauch. Wayne State University Press, Detroit. (Cited as Jenenser Realphilosophie II).Google Scholar
Khalil, Elias L. 1990. “Beyond Self-Interest and Altruism: A Reconstruction of Adam Smith's Theory of Human Conduct,Economics and Philosophy, 6, 09, 255–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lukacs, Georg. 1976. The Young Hegel, translated by Rodney, Livingstone, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
Mandel, Ernest. 1971. The Formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx, translated by Brian, Pearce, Monthly Review Press, New York.Google Scholar
Marcuse, Herbert. 1941. Reason and Revolution, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1844. The Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844, translated by Martin, Milligan, International Publishers, New York, 1964.Google Scholar
Nicolaus, Martin. 1973. “Foreword” to the Grundrisse, Vantage Books, New York.Google Scholar
Palyi, Melchior. 1928. “The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent,” in Adam Smith, 1776–1926, Lectures to Commemorate the Sesquicentennial of the Publication of “The Wealth of Nations,” 180233, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Pelczynski, Z. A., ed. 1984. The State and Civil Society, Studies in Hegel's Political Philosophy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Plant, Raymond. 1980. “Economic and Social Integration in Hegel's Political Philosophy,” Hegel's Social and Political Thought, 5990, edited by Donald, Phillip Verene, Humanities Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Plant, Raymond. 1983. Hegel, An Introduction, 2d edition, Basil Blackwell Publisher Limited, Oxford.Google Scholar
Rae, John. 1895. Life of Adam Smith, reprint, Augustus Kelley, New York, 1965.Google Scholar
Riedel, Manfred. 1984. Between Tradition and Revolution, The Hegelian Transformation of Political Philosophy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Rosdolsky, Roman. 1977. The Making of Marx's “Capital,” Pluto Press Limited, London.Google Scholar
Rubel, Maximilien and Margaret, Manale. 1975. Marx without Myth, A Chronological Study of his Life and Work, Harper and Row, New York.Google Scholar
Scott, William R. 1937. Adam Smith as Student and Professor, reprint, Augustus Kelley, New York, 1965.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. 1776. The Wealth of Nations, reprint, The Modern Library, New York, 1937.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. 1978. Lectures on Jurisprudence, edited by Meek, R. L., Raphael, D. D., and Stein, P. G., Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Steuart, Sir James. 1966. An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy, edited by Oliver, A. Skinner and Boyd, , London.Google Scholar
Stewart, Dugald. 1793. Biographical Memoir of Adam Smith, reprint, Augustus Kelley, New York, 1966.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1965. Guide to John Rae's “Life of Adam Smith,” Augustus Kelley, New York.Google Scholar